Similar documents
Competitive Equilibrium

The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

Introduction to General Equilibrium

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Advanced Microeconomics Problem Set 1

Lecture #3. General equilibrium

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Market Equilibrium Price: Existence, Properties and Consequences

First Welfare Theorem

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

Adding Production to the Theory

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

TECHNICAL APPENDIX. 7. Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

Uniqueness, Stability, and Gross Substitutes

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Lecture 7: General Equilibrium - Existence, Uniqueness, Stability

Advanced Microeconomics

Scarf Instability and Production: A Simulation

Notes on General Equilibrium

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

Sometimes the domains X and Z will be the same, so this might be written:

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005

Microeconomic Theory I Midterm October 2017

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations

CONSUMER DEMAND. Consumer Demand

Microeconomic Theory I Midterm

Problem Set Suggested Answers

Existence, Computation, and Applications of Equilibrium

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Midterm Exam

Properties of Walrasian Demand

1 Second Welfare Theorem

Proportional Response as Iterated Cobb-Douglas

PhD Qualifier Examination

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM: EXCESS DEMAND AND THE RÔLE OF PRICES

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Consumer Theory. Ichiro Obara. October 8, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Consumer Theory October 8, / 51

1 General Equilibrium

Economics th April 2011

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Introductory Microeconomics

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Revealed Preferences and Utility Functions

On the Maximal Domain Theorem

PS4-Solution. Mehrdad Esfahani. Fall Arizona State University. Question 1 Question 2 Question 3 Question 4 Question 5

Fixed Point Theorems

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Partial Differentiation

Core. Ichiro Obara. December 3, 2008 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Core December 3, / 22

ECMB02F -- Problem Set 2

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Alp Simsek (MIT) Recitation Notes: 1. Gorman s Aggregation Th eorem2. Normative Representative November 9, Household Theorem / 16

Economic Core, Fair Allocations, and Social Choice Theory

Tangent Plane. Nobuyuki TOSE. October 02, Nobuyuki TOSE. Tangent Plane

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

A MATHEMATICAL MODEL OF EXCHANGE

Convergence of Non-Normalized Iterative

Economics 604: Microeconomics Deborah Minehart & Rachel Kranton

1 + x 1/2. b) For what values of k is g a quasi-concave function? For what values of k is g a concave function? Explain your answers.

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

The Utility Frontier

Microeconomic Analysis

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

Comparative Statics. Autumn 2018

Answers to Spring 2014 Microeconomics Prelim

Econ Slides from Lecture 10

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

ANSWERS TO ODD NUMBERED EXERCISES IN CHAPTER 3

Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 29 September 2004.

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

Public Goods and Private Goods

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

Lecture 5: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model

Transcription:

The Definition of Market Equilibrium The concept of market equilibrium, like the notion of equilibrium in just about every other context, is supposed to capture the idea of a state of the system in which there are no forces tending to cause the state to change to a different state. For a market system, we think some prices are likely to change if there is excess demand or supply for any of the goods; and conversely that if all markets clear i.e., if no good is in excess demand or supply then the prices will not change. And since the quantities that are transacted depend on the prices, the quantities should not change, either. So the natural definition of a general equilibrium of all markets is that all the markets clear i.e., that the price-list p R l + satisfies the equilibrium condition X (p) = 0 i.e., Xk (p) = 0, k = 1,..., l. ( ) Provisional Definition: Let E = ((u i, x i )) n i=1 be an economy consisting of n consumers (ui, x i ). Let x i ( ) : R l + R l denote the demand function of consumer (u i, x i ), and let X ( ) : R l + R l denote the market net demand function X (p) := n i=1 (xi (p) x i ). A market equilibrium of E is a price-list p R l + that satisfies the equilibrium condition ( ). There are many situations where this definition works just fine, but there are also many situations where it s not satisfactory. For example, (1) If a price p k is zero and there is excess supply of good k i.e., Xk (p) < 0 it seems unlikely that this would lead to a change in any of the prices. (2) What if the demand function x i ( ) is not well-defined at some price-lists p for one or more consumers (u i, x i )? For example, if p k = 0, the CMP for some consumers may not have a solution. (3) What if some consumer s demand function x i ( ) is not single-valued at some price-lists? For example, a utility function u i might have an indifference curve with a flat spot an extreme example is a linear utility function u(x, y) = ax + by. The following definition explicitly avoids issues (2) and (3) by including only situations in which all demand functions are well-defined and single-valued for every price-list p R l +. The definition takes account of issue (1) by allowing that excess supply of some goods is consistent with equilibrium if those goods have a price of zero.

Definition: Let E = ((u i, x i )) n i=1 be an economy consisting of n consumers, all of whose demand functions x i ( ) : R l + R l are well-defined and single-valued on R l +, and let X ( ) : R l + R l denote the corresponding market net demand function. A market equilibrium of E is a price-list p R l + that satisfies the equilibrium condition k = 1,..., l : Xk (p) 0 and Xk (p) = 0 if p k > 0. (Clr) We ll also refer to a price-list that satisfies (Clr) as an equilibrium of the net demand function X ( ). We ll use this equilibrium condition throughout the course, so we give it a name that we ll use to refer to it: (Clr), which is an abbreviation for Clear, since the condition says that all markets clear. A market equilibrium is also called a Walrasian equilibrium. An essential feature of this equilibrium concept is the assumption implicit in the definition that all consumers are price takers. Each consumer, in solving his consumer maximization problem, treats the prices as parameters that will be unaffected by his decision about which consumption bundle he will choose.

Some Remarks (1) Note the analogy with optimization: Here the equilibrium conditions are equations that determine the values of the variables, and in optimization the first-order conditions are equations that determine the values of the variables. (2) With l goods we will have l 1 independent equilibrium conditions (equations), with Walras s Law accounting for the remaining market, so only l 1 relative prices are determined by equilibrium. (We could, for example, use one of the prices as numeraire. ) Because the demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero, they also depend only on the relative prices. (3) What if, unlike in our Cobb-Douglas examples, we can t get a closed-form solution (i.e., an explicit expression) for the state variables in terms of the parameters? How do we do comparative statics in that case? We can apply the Implicit Function Theorem to the equilibrium equations, just as we apply the IFT to the first-order equations to do comparative statics for optimization. (4) The approach in (3) is often not good enough: for example, we often need to determine the actual equilibrium prices and/or quantities, not just the comparative statics derivatives. If we can t get closed-form solutions (which is the typical situation), we can try to compute the equilibrium values. How do we do that? (5) What if there is no equilibrium? Under what conditions will there be an equilibrium? (6) What if there are multiple equilibria? Under what conditions will there be a unique equilibrium? (7) What if the system is not in equilibrium? What are the stability properties of the equilibrium? (8) Is the equilibrium outcome a good outcome? (9) What if markets and prices aren t used? Under what conditions will they be used? (10) What if not everyone is a price-taker? We will address all of these questions in the course, some in depth, and others only in passing.