Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lectures 2 and 3: Introduction to Dynamic Voting and Constitutions

Similar documents
Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lectures 2 and 3: Introduction to Dynamic Voting and Constitutions

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lectures 2 and 3: Introduction to Dynamic Voting and Constitutions

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lectures 3-5: Introduction to Dynamic Voting and Constitutions

Dynamics and Stability of Constitutions, Coalitions, and Clubs

Political Economy of Institutions and Development: Problem Set 1. Due Date: Thursday, February 23, in class.

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 8. Institutional Change and Democratization

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 8. Institutional Change and Democratization

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lectures 2 and 3: Static Voting Models

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 24: Decisions in Groups

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 1 and 2: Collective Choice and Voting

Social Mobility and Stability of Democracy: Re-evaluating De Tocqueville

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Social Mobility and Stability of Democracy: Re-evaluating De Tocqueville

Re-evaluating de Tocqueville: Social Mobility and Stability of Democracy

Blocking Development

Social Mobility and Stability of Democracy: Re-evaluating De Tocqueville

Coalition Formation in Non-Democracies

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 4. Economic Institutions under Elite Domination

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 10. Information, Beliefs and Politics

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Costless Delay in Negotiations

Online Appendix: The Role of Theory in Instrument-Variables Strategies

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 13 and 14: Economic Policy under Nondemocratic Institutions

SUPPLEMENT TO POLITICAL ECONOMY OF REDISTRIBUTION (Econometrica, Vol. 85, No. 3, May 2017, )

Coalitional Structure of the Muller-Satterthwaite Theorem

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 13: Culture, Values and Cooperation

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 11: Introduction to Game Theory 3

Repeated Downsian Electoral Competition

Inducing stability in hedonic games

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES COALITION FORMATION IN POLITICAL GAMES. Daron Acemoglu Georgy Egorov Konstantin Sonin

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

NOTES ON COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY AND THE CORE. 1. Introduction

SPATIAL VOTING (MULTIPLE DIMENSIONS)

Multiple Equilibria in the Citizen-Candidate Model of Representative Democracy.

Robust Mechanism Design and Robust Implementation

Online Appendixes for \A Theory of Military Dictatorships"

Weak Robust (Virtual) Implementation

13 Social choice B = 2 X X. is the collection of all binary relations on X. R = { X X : is complete and transitive}

Bayesian Learning in Social Networks

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 8: Supermodular and Potential Games

Rationalization of Collective Choice Functions by Games with Perfect Information. Yongsheng Xu

A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations *

Introduction to Game Theory

Learning from Others Outcomes

We set up the basic model of two-sided, one-to-one matching

Patience and Ultimatum in Bargaining

SPATIAL VOTING (MULTIPLE DIMENSIONS)

Fairness and Redistribution: Response

Entropic Selection of Nash Equilibrium

Wars of Attrition with Budget Constraints

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 16: Cooperation and Trust in Networks

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND Department of Economics Economics 754 Topics in Political Economy Fall 2005 Allan Drazen. Exercise Set I

Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning. Jason R. Marden

Non-deteriorating Choice Without Full Transitivity

Impatience vs. Incentives

Endre Boros b Vladimir Gurvich d ;

CORE AND NO-TREAT EQUILIBRIUM IN TOURNAMENT GAMES WITH EXTERNALITIES

Second Welfare Theorem

On the Chacteristic Numbers of Voting Games

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information

Farsighted stability with heterogeneous expectations

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case

Economic Core, Fair Allocations, and Social Choice Theory

Sequential implementation without commitment

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 10 Apr 2018

Coalitionally strategyproof functions depend only on the most-preferred alternatives.

Farsightedness and Cautiousness in Coalition Formation

The core of voting games: a partition approach

The Axiomatic Method in Social Choice Theory:

Pledge-and-Review Bargaining

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations

Extreme Agenda Setting Power in Dynamic Bargaining Games

Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1

Recap Social Choice Fun Game Voting Paradoxes Properties. Social Choice. Lecture 11. Social Choice Lecture 11, Slide 1

The Relation Between Implementability and the Core

CS 781 Lecture 9 March 10, 2011 Topics: Local Search and Optimization Metropolis Algorithm Greedy Optimization Hopfield Networks Max Cut Problem Nash

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 13: Extensive Form Games

Definitions and Proofs

Rate of Convergence of Learning in Social Networks

Game Theory. Bargaining Theory. ordi Massó. International Doctorate in Economic Analysis (IDEA) Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (UAB)

1 Lattices and Tarski s Theorem

Dynamic Coalitions. July 22, Abstract

László Á. Kóczy RM/08/028

SF2972 Game Theory Exam with Solutions March 15, 2013

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

First Prev Next Last Go Back Full Screen Close Quit. Game Theory. Giorgio Fagiolo

Lecture Notes: Self-enforcing agreements

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Static Information Design

The core of voting games with externalities

Solving Extensive Form Games

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

NEGOTIATION-PROOF CORRELATED EQUILIBRIUM

Mixed Refinements of Shapley s Saddles and Weak Tournaments

Finite Dictatorships and Infinite Democracies

Stochastic convexity in dynamic programming

Transcription:

14.773 Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lectures 2 and 3: Introduction to Dynamic Voting and Constitutions Daron Acemoglu MIT February 8 and 13, 2018. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 1 / 63

Dynamic Voting Models and Constitutions Introduction Introduction Political losers: Anticipation of future political changes creates incentives for distorting policies/institutions/actions now. More generally related to: How does the anticipation of changes in political power effects political equilibria and economic effi ciency? We now investigate this question focusing on Markov Perfect Equilibria of dynamic political games. These issues are more salient and important when current political decisions affect the distribution of political power in the future. The set of issues that arise here are very similar to those that will be central when we think about endogenous institutions. Thus useful to start considering more general dynamic voting models. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 2 / 63

Examples Constitutional Choice Example Dynamic Voting autocracy limited franchise full democracy Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 3 / 63

Examples Dynamic Voting Constitutional Choice (continued) Three states: absolutism a, constitutional monarchy c, full democracy d Two agents: elite E, middle class M E rules in a, M rules in c and d. w E (d) < w E (a) < w E (c) w M (a) < w M (c) < w M (d) Myopic elite: starting from a, move to c Farsighted elite (high discount factor): stay in a as moving to c will lead to M moving to d But very different insights when there are stochastic elements and intermediate discount factors. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 4 / 63

Examples A Baseline Model States and Utilities Society starts period in state (e.g., size of club, constitution, policy) s t 1 and decides on (feasible) s t A finite set of individuals/players, and a finite set of states, S All players maximize discounted utility, with discount factor β < 1 Player i in period t gets instantaneous utility (in general, this is derived from the within-state game) w i (s t ) Strict increasing differences: For any agents i, j N such that i > j, w i (s) w j (s) is increasing in s This could be weakened to weak increasing differences for some results. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 5 / 63

Transition Mapping Examples A Baseline Model Let us consider Markov transition rules for analyzing how the state changes over time. A Markov transition rule is denoted by φ such that φ : S S. A transition rule is useful because it defines the path of the state s recursively such that for all t, i.e., s t+1 = φ(s t ). Why Markov? If there is an s such that s = φ(s ), then s is a steady state of the system (and we also use φ (s) to denote limiting value starting with s). We will consider both deterministic and stochastic transition rules φ( ). But for now, useful to think of it as non-stochastic. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 6 / 63

Recursive Representation Examples A Baseline Model Value function (conditioned on transition mapping φ): V φ i (s) = w i (s) + k=1 ) β k w i (φ k (s). Recursively V φ i (s) = w i (s) + βv φ i (φ(s)). Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 7 / 63

Examples A Baseline Model Recursive Representation (continued) In the stochastic case: V φ E,i (s) = w E,i (s) + β E E q ( E, E ) V φ E,i (φ E (s)). where E denotes different environments with different payoffs, transition costs or political processes, and q (E, E ) denotes transition probabilities. Key observation: If w satisfies (strict) increasing differences, then so does V. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 8 / 63

Roadmap Examples A Baseline Model We now study some special cases, then returning to the general framework so far outlined. A (finite) game of political eliminations. Characterization for the general model without stochastic elements and with β close to 1. Applications. Characterization for the general model with stochastic elements and arbitrary discount factor β. Applications. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 9 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Voting over Coalitions Voting Over Coalitions Another obvious example of dynamic voting with changing constituencies/coalitions. Model based on Acemoglu, Egorov and Sonin (2008). A coalition, which will determine the distribution of a pie (more generally payoffs), both over its own membership. Possibility of future votes shaping the stability of current clubs illustrated more clearly. Motivation: 1 the three-player divide the dollar game. 2 eliminations in the Soviet Politburo. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 10 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Voting over Coalitions Political Game Let I denote the collection of all individuals, which is assumed to be finite. The non-empty subsets of I are coalitions and the set of coalitions is denoted by C. For any X I, C X denotes the set of coalitions that are subsets of X and X is the number of members in X. In each period there is a designated ruling coalition, which can change over time. The game starts with ruling coalition N, and eventually the ultimate ruling coalition (URC) forms. When the URC is X, then player i obtains baseline utility w i (X ) R. w ( ) {w i ( )} i I. Important assumption: game of non-transferable utility. Why? Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 11 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Voting over Coalitions Political Power So far, our focus has been on democratic situations. One person one vote. Now allow differential powers across individuals. Power mapping to: γ : I R ++, γ i γ (i): political power of individual i I and γ X i X γ i political power of coalition X. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 12 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Voting over Coalitions Winning Coalitions Coalition Y X is winning within coalition X if and only if γ Y > αγ X, where α [1/2, 1) is a (weighted) supermajority rule (α = 1/2 corresponds to majority rule). Let us write: Y W X for Y X winning within X. Since α 1/2, if Y, Z W X, then Y Z =. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 13 / 63

Payoffs Voting over Coalitions Voting over Coalitions Assumption: Let i I and X, Y C. Then: (1) If i X and i / Y, then w i (X ) > w i (Y ) [i.e., each player prefers to be part of the URC]. (2) For i X and i Y, w i (X ) > w i (Y ) γ i /γ X > γ i /γ Y ( γ X < γ Y ) [i.e., for any two URCs that he is part of, each player prefers the one where his relative power is greater]. (3) If i / X and i / Y, then w i (X ) = w i (Y ) w i [i.e., a player is indifferent between URCs he is not part of]. Interpretation. Example: w i (X ) = γ { X {i} γi /γ = X if i X γ X 0 if i / X. (1) Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 14 / 63

Extensive-Form Game Voting over Coalitions Voting over Coalitions Choose ε > 0 arbitrarily small. Then, the extensive form of the game Γ = (N, γ N, w ( ), α) is as follows. Each stage j of the game starts with some ruling coalition N j (at the beginning of the game N 0 = N). Then: 1. Nature randomly picks agenda setter a j,q N j for q = 1. 2. [Agenda-setting step] Agenda setter a j,q makes proposal P j,q C Nj, which is a subcoalition of N j such that a j,q P j,q (for simplicity, we assume that a player cannot propose to eliminate himself). 3. [Voting step] Players in P j,q vote sequentially over the proposal. More specifically, Nature randomly chooses the first voter, v j,q,1, who then casts his vote vote ṽ (v j,q,1 ) {ỹ, ñ} (Yes or No), then Nature chooses the second voter v j,q,2 = v j,q,1 etc. After all P j,q players have voted, the game proceeds to step 4 if players who supported the proposal form a winning coalition within N j (i.e., if {i P j,q : ṽ (i) = ỹ} W Nj ), and otherwise it proceeds to step 5. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 15 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Extensive-Form Game (continued) Voting over Coalitions 4. If P j,q = N j, then the game proceeds to step 6. Otherwise, players from N j \ P j,q are eliminated and the game proceeds to step 1 with N j+1 = P j,q (and j increases by 1 as a new transition has taken place). 5. If q < N j, then next agenda setter a j,q+1 N j is randomly picked by Nature among members of N j who have not yet proposed at this stage (so a j,q+1 = a j,r for 1 r q), and the game proceeds to step 2 (with q increased by 1). If q = N j, the game proceeds to step 6. 6. N j becomes the ultimate ruling coalition. Each player i N receives total payoff U i = w i (N j ) ε 1 k j I {i Nk }, (2) where I { } is the indicator function taking the value of 0 or 1. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 16 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Voting over Coalitions Discussion Natural game of sequential choice of coalitions. ε introduced for technical reasons (otherwise, indifferences lead to uninteresting transitions). Important assumption: players eliminated have no say in the future. Stark representation of changing constituencies, but not a good approximation to democratic decision-making. More reminiscent to dealmaking in autocracies or coalition formation in nondemocracies. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 17 / 63

Main Result Voting over Coalitions Voting over Coalitions Theorem Fix I, γ, w ( ) and α [1/2, 1). Then there exists a set φ (N) such that: 1. For any K φ (N), there exists a pure strategy profile σ K that is an SPE and leads to URC K in at most one transition. In this equilibrium player i N receives payoff U i = w i (K ) εi {i K } I {N =K }. This equilibrium payoff does not depend on the random moves by Nature. 2. Suppose that γ is generic (in the sense that no two coalitions have the same power), then φ (N) is a singleton (and φ ( ) is single-valued). Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 18 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Voting over Coalitions Main Result (continued) Theorem (continued) 3. This mapping φ may be obtained by the following inductive procedure. For any k N, let C k = {X C : X = k}. Clearly, C = k N C k. If X C 1, then let φ (X ) = {X }. If φ (Z ) has been defined for all Z C n for all n < k, then define φ (X ) for X C k as φ (X ) = argmin γ A, and A M(X ) {X } M (X ) = {Z C X \ {X } : Z W X and Z φ (Z )}. Proceeding inductively φ (X ) is defined for all X C. Intuitively, M (X ) is the set of proper subcoalitions which are both winning and self-enforcing. When there are no proper winning and self-enforcing subcoalitions, M (X ) is empty and φ (X ) = X. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 19 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Voting over Coalitions Discussion and Implication Implication: Essential uniqueness when there are no ties. Application: coalition formation among three players with approximately equal powers. Corollary What happens among k players with approximately equal powers? Coalition N is self-enforcing, that is, N φ (N), if and only if there exists no coalition X N, X = N, that is winning within N and self-enforcing. Moreover, if N is self-enforcing, then φ (N) = {N}. Main implication: a coalition that includes a winning and self-enforcing subcoalition cannot be self-enforcing. This captures the notion that the stability of smaller coalitions undermines stability of larger ones. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 20 / 63

Voting over Coalitions The Structure of Ruling Coalitions Characterization Equilibrium characterize simply by a set of recursive equations. What are the implications of equilibrium coalition formation Let us impose one more assumption Assumption: For no X, Y C such that X Y the equality γ Y = αγ X is satisfied. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 21 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Continuity of Ruling Coalitions The Structure of Ruling Coalitions Proposition Consider Γ = (N, γ, w ( ), α) with α [1/2, 1). Then: 1. There exists δ > 0 such that if γ : N R ++ lies within δ-neighborhood of γ, then Φ (N, γ, w, α) = Φ (N, γ, w, α). 2. There exists δ > 0 such that if α [1/2, 1) satisfies α α < δ, then Φ (N, γ, w, α) = Φ (N, γ, w, α ). 3. Let N = N 1 N 2 with N 1 and N 2 disjoint. Then, there exists δ > 0 such that for all N 2 such that γ N2 < δ, φ (N 1 ) = φ (N 1 N 2 ). Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 22 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Fragility of Self-Enforcing Coalitions The Structure of Ruling Coalitions Proposition Suppose α = 1/2 and fix a power mapping γ : I R ++. Then: 1. If coalitions X and Y such that X Y = are both self-enforcing, then coalition X Y is not self-enforcing. 2. If X is a self-enforcing coalition, then X {i} for i / X and X \ {i} for i X are not self-enforcing. Implication: under majority rule α = 1/2, the addition or the elimination of a single agent from a self-enforcing coalitions makes this coalition no longer self-enforcing. Why? Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 23 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Size of Ruling Coalitions I The Structure of Ruling Coalitions Proposition Consider Γ = (N, γ, w ( ), α) with α [1/2, 1). Suppose that there exists δ > 0 such that max i,j N { γi /γ j } < 1 + δ. Then: 1. When α = 1/2, any ruling coalition must have size k m = 2 m 1 for some m Z, and moreover, φ (N) = N if and only if N = k m for k m = 2 m 1. 2. When α [1/2, 1), φ (N) = N if and only if N = k m,α where k 1,α = 1 and k m,α = k m 1,α /α + 1 for m > 1, where z denotes the integer part of z. When powers are approximately equal, the size of the URC is determined tightly. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 24 / 63

Rules and Coalitions Voting over Coalitions The Structure of Ruling Coalitions Should an increase in α raise the size of the URC? Should an individual always gain from an increase in his power? Intuitive, but the answers are no and no. Proposition 1. An increase in α may reduce the size of the ruling coalition. That is, there exists a society N, a power mapping γ and α, α [1/2, 1), such that α > α but for all X Φ (N, γ, w, α) and X Φ (N, γ, w, α ), X > X and γ X > γ X. 2. There exist a society N, α [1/2, 1), two mappings γ, γ : N R ++ satisfying γ i = γ i for all i = j, γ j < γ j such that j Φ (N, γ, w, α), but j / Φ (N, γ, w, α). Moreover, this result applies even when j is the most powerful player in both cases, i.e. γ i = γ i < γ j < γ j for all i = j. Why? Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 25 / 63

Voting over Coalitions Conclusions Preliminary Conclusions Once dynamic voting also affects the distribution of political power, richer set of issues arise. Endogeneity of constituencies is both practically relevant and related to endogenous institutions. Ensuring equilibria in situations of dynamic voting harder, but often we can put economically interesting structure to ensure equilibria (once we know what we are trying to model). Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 26 / 63

Constitutions Introduction Introduction Why do constitutions matter? What is written in constitutions seems to matter, but constitutions can be disobeyed and rewritten. How do we think about the role of constitutions? Different approaches. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 27 / 63

Philosophical Constitutions Introduction What is written on paper should not matter: because whatever is written down could have been expected even when it was not written down a constitution is as good as the force behind it But this perspective may not be too useful in studying how constitutions are written in practice, why they persist and why and when they matter. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 28 / 63

Constitutions General Approach Dynamics and Stability: A More General Approach A more general approach towards stability and change in social arrangements (political regimes, constitutions, coalitions, clubs, firms) based on Acemoglu, Egorov and Sonin (2012). Main trade-off between current economic payoffs and future political power. Recap: Consider the same simple extension of franchise story Three states: absolutism a, constitutional monarchy c, full democracy d Two agents: elite E, middle class M w E (d) < w E (a) < w E (c) w M (a) < w M (c) < w M (d) E rules in a, M rules in c and d. Myopic elite: starting from a, move to c Farsighted elite: stay in a: move to c will lead to M moving to d. Same example to illustrate resistance against socially beneficial reform. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 29 / 63

Constitutions General Approach Naïve and Dynamic Insights Naïve insight: a social arrangement will emerge and persist if a suffi ciently powerful group prefers it to alternatives. Simple example illustrates: power to change towards a more preferred outcome is not enough to implement change because of further dynamics Social arrangements might be stable even if there are powerful groups that prefer change in the short run. Key: social arrangements change the distribution of political power (decision-making capacity). Dynamic decision-making: future changes also matter (especially if discounting is limited) Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 30 / 63

Simple Implications Constitutions General Approach A particular social arrangement is made stable by the instability of alternative arrangements that are preferred by suffi ciently many members of the society. stability of a constitution does not require absence of powerful groups opposing it, but the absence of an alternative stable constitution favored by powerful groups. Effi ciency-enhancing changes are often resisted because of further social changes that they will engender. Pareto ineffi cient social arrangements often emerge as stable outcomes. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 31 / 63

Constitutions Model Model: Basics Finite set of individuals I ( I total) Set of coalitions C (non-empty subsets X I) Each individual maximizes discounted sum of playoffs with discount factor β [0, 1). Finite set of states S ( S total) Discrete time t 1 State s t is determined in period t; s 0 is given Each state s S is characterized by Payoff w i (s) of individual i I (normalize w i (s) > 0) Set of winning coalitions W s C capable of implementing a change Protocol π s (k), 1 k K s : sequence of agenda-setters or proposals (π s (k) I S) Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 32 / 63

Constitutions Model Winning Coalitions Assumption (Winning Coalitions) For any state s S, W s C satisfies two properties: (a) If X, Y C, X Y, and X W s then Y W s. (b) If X, Y W s, then X Y =. (a) says that a superset of a winning coalition is winning in each state (b) says that there are no two disjoint winning coalitions in any state W s = is allowed (exogenously stable state) Example: Three players 1, 2, 3 W s = {{1}, {1, 2}, {1, 3}, {1, 2, 3}} is valid (1 is dictator) W s = {{1, 2}, {1, 3}, {2, 3}, {1, 2, 3}} is valid (majority voting) W s = {{1}, {2, 3}} is not valid (both properties are violated) Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 33 / 63

Dynamic Game Constitutions Model 1 Period t begins with state s t 1 from the previous period. 2 For k = 1,..., K st 1, the kth proposal P k,t is determined as follows. If π st 1 (k) S, then P k,t = π st 1 (k). If π st 1 (k) I, then player π st 1 (k) chooses P k,t S. 3 If P k,t = s t 1, each player votes (sequentially) yes (for P k,t ) or no (for s t 1 ). Let Y k,t denote the set of players who voted yes. If Y k,t W t 1, then P k,t is accepted, otherwise it is rejected. 4 If P k,t is accepted, then s t = P k,t. If P k,t is rejected, then the game moves to step 2 with k k + 1 if k < K st 1. If k = K st 1, s t = s t 1. 5 At the end of each period (once s t is determined), each player receives instantaneous utility u i (t): { wi (s) if s u i (t) = t = s t 1 = s 0 if s t = s t 1 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 34 / 63

Recursive Representation Constitutions Model Take a transition mapping φ Value function conditioned on transition mapping φ: Recursively V φ i (s) = w i (s) + V φ i k=1 ) β k w i (φ k (s). (s) = w i (s) + βv φ i (φ(s)). Key observation: If w satisfies (strict) increasing differences, then so does V. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 35 / 63

Constitutions Markov Voting Equilibrium Model Let W x denote the set of winning coalitions i.e., the set of agents politically powerful enough to change the state starting in state x. The structure of these sets will be explained in detail below. φ : S S is a Markov Voting Equilibrium (MVE) if for any x, y S, { } i N : V φ i (y) > V φ E,i (φ (x)) { } / W x i N : V φ i (φ (x)) V φ i (x) W x The first is ensures that there isn t another state transition to which would gather suffi cient support. Analogy to core. The second one ensures that there is a winning coalition supporting the transition relative to the status quo. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 36 / 63

Constitutions Some Terminology Single Crossing and Single Peakedness Definition Take set of individuals I R, set of states S R, and payoff functions w ( ). Then, single crossing condition holds if whenever for any i, j I and x, y S such that i < j and x < y, w i (y) > w i (x) implies w j (y) > w j (x) and w j (y) < w j (x) implies w i (y) < w i (x). Definition Take set of individuals I R, set of states S R, and payoff functions w ( ). Then, single-peaked preferences assumption holds if for any i I there exists state x such that for any y, z S, if y < z x or x z > y, then w i (y) w i (z). Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 37 / 63

Constitutions Some Terminology Generalizations of Majority Rule and Median Voter Definition Take set of individuals I R, state s S. Player i I is a quasi-median voter (in state s) if i X for any X W s such that X = {j I : a j b} for some a, b R. That is, quasi-median voter is a player who belongs to any connected winning coalition. Quasi-median voters: simple majority 5/6 supermajority Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 38 / 63

Constitutions Some Terminology Generalizations of Majority Rule and Median Voter (continued) Denote the set of quasi-median voters in state s by M s (it will be nonempty) Definition Take set of individuals I R, set of states S R. The sets of winning coalitions {W s } s S has monotonic quasi-median voter property if for each x, y S satisfying x < y there exist i M x, j M y such that i j. 1 2 3 4 Robert s model; ok also ok not ok Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 39 / 63

Some More Notation Constitutions Some Terminology Define binary relations: states x and y are payoff-equivalent x y i I : w i (x) = w i (y) y is weakly preferred to x in z y z x {i I : w i (y) w i (x)} W z y is strictly preferred to x in z y z x {i I : w i (y) > w i (x)} W z Notice that these binary relations are not simply preference relations they encode information about preferences and political power. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 40 / 63

Constitutions Main Result Theorem on Single Crossing and Single Peakedness Theorem If preferences are generic (extending our previous definition) and satisfy single crossing and the monotonic quasi-median voter property holds, or if preferences are generic and single peaked and all winning coalitions intersect (i.e., X W x and Y W y imply X Y = ), then sj is acyclic. That is: 1. For any sequence of states s 1,..., s k in S, s j+1 sj s j for all 1 j k 1 = s 1 sk s k, and 2. For any sequence of states s, s 1,..., s k in S such that s j s l and s j s s, s j+1 s s j for all 1 j < k 1 = s 1 s s k. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 41 / 63

Constitutions Noncooperative Characterization Main Result Theorem There exists β 0 [0, 1) such that for all β β 0, the following results hold. 1. Any MVE can be characterized by } a mapping φ constructed as follows: reorder states as {µ 1,..., µ S such that if for any l (j, S ], µ l µj µ j. Let µ 1 S be such that φ (µ 1 ) = µ 1. For k = 2,..., S, let M k = { s { µ 1,..., µ k 1 } : s µk µ k and φ (s) = s }. Define, for k = 2,..., S, { φ µ (µ k ) = k if M k = z M k : x M k with x µk z if M k =. (If there exist more than one s M k : z M k with z µk of these). s, pick any Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 42 / 63

Constitutions Main Result Noncooperative Characterization (continued) Theorem (continued) 2. There is a protocol {π s } s S and a MPE σ such that s t = φ (s 0 ) for any t 1; that is, the game reaches and stays in φ (s 0 ) after one. 3. For any protocol {π s } s S there exists a MPE in pure strategies. Any such MPE σ has the property that for any initial state s 0 S, it reaches some state, s by t = 1 and thus for t 1, s t = s. Moreover, there exists mapping φ : S S is constructed above such that s = φ (s 0 ). 4. If, in addition, the following property holds: For x, y, z S such that x z z, y z z, and x y, either y z x or x z y, then the MVE is unique, and also, the MPE is essentially unique in the sense that for any protocol {π s } s S, any MPE strategy profile in pure strategies σ induces s t φ (s 0 ) for all t 1. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 43 / 63

Constitutions Main Result Effi ciency A state s is myopically stable if s = φ (s) because there does not exist s s s Corollary Clearly a myopically stable state is stable, but not vice versa. If a state s is myopically stable, then it is Pareto effi cient. If it is stable but not myopically stable, then it can be Pareto ineffi cient. Previously, no issue of Pareto ineffi ciency, because you are focusing on a game of pure redistribution (like divide the dollar game). This is no longer the case. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 44 / 63

Constitutions Example Extension of Franchise Example Three states: absolutism a, constitutional monarchy c, full democracy d Two agents: elite E, middle class M w E (d) < w E (a) < w E (c) w M (a) < w M (c) < w M (d) W a = {{E }, {E, M}}, W c = {{M}, {E, M}}, W d = {{M}, {E, M}} Choose d as µ 1 and thus φ (d) = d and φ (d) = d. Next choose c as µ 2 and we have φ (c) = d and φ (c) = d Therefore, φ (a) = a (and φ (a) = a). Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 45 / 63

Constitutions Applications Voting in Clubs N individuals, I = {1,..., N} N states (clubs), s k = {1,..., k} Assume single-crossing condition for all l > k and j > i, w j (s l ) w j (s k ) > w i (s l ) w i (s k ) Assume genericity : for all l > k, w j (s l ) = w j (s k ) Then, the theorem for ordered spaces applies and shows existence of MPE in pure strategies for any majority or supermajority rule. It also provides a full characterization of these equilibria. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 46 / 63

Constitutions Applications Voting in Clubs If in addition only odd-sized clubs are allowed, unique dynamically stable state. Equilibria can easily be Pareto ineffi cient. If genericity is relaxed, so that w j (s l ) = w j (s k ), then the theorem for ordered spaces no longer applies, but both the axiomatic characterization and the noncooperative theorems can still be applied from first principles. Also can be extended to more general pickle structures (e.g., weighted voting or supermajority) and general structure of clubs (e.g., clubs on the form {k n,..., k,..., k + n} I for a fixed n and different values of k). Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 47 / 63

Constitutions Applications An Example of Elite Clubs Specific example: suppose that preferences are such that w j (s n ) > w j (s n ) > w j (s k ) = w j (s k ) for all n > n j and k, k < j individuals always prefer to be part of the club individuals always prefer smaller clubs. Winning coalitions need to have a strict majority (e.g., two out of three, three out of four etc.). Then, {1} is a stable club (no wish to expand) {1, 2} is a stable club (no wish to expand and no majority to contract) {1, 2, 3} is not a stable club (3 can be eliminated) {1, 2, 3, 4} is a stable club More generally, clubs of size 2 k for k = 0, 1,... are stable. Starting with the club of size n, the equilibrium involves the largest club of size 2 k n. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 48 / 63

Constitutions Applications Stable Constitutions N individuals, I = {1,..., N} In period 2, they decide whether to implement a reform (a votes are needed) a is determined in period 1 Two cases: Voting rule a: stable if in period 1 no other rule is supported by a voters Constitution (a, b): stable if in period 1 no other constitution is supported by b voters Preferences over reforms translate into preferences over a Barbera and Jackson assume a structure where these preferences are single-crossing and single-peaked Motivated by this, let us assume that they are strictly single-crossing Stable voting rules correspond to myopically (and dynamically) stable states Stable constitutions correspond to dynamically stable states Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 49 / 63

Political Eliminations Constitutions Applications The characterization results apply even when states do not form an ordered set. Set of states S coincides with set of coalitions C Each agent i I is endowed with political influence γ i Payoffs are given by proportional rule { γi /γ w i (X ) = X if i X 0 if i / X where γ X = γ j j X and X is the ruling coalition. this payoff function can be generalized to any function where payoffs are increasing in relative power of the individual in the ruling coalition Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 50 / 63

Constitutions Applications Political Eliminations (continued) Winning coalitions are determined by weighted (super)majority rule α [1/2, 1) W X = Genericity: γ X = γ Y only if X = Y {Y : j Y X γ j > α j X γ j } Assumption on Payoffs is satisfied and the axiomatic characterization applies exactly. If players who are not part of the ruling coalition have a slight preference for larger ruling coalitions, then Stronger Acyclicity Assumption is also satisfied. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 51 / 63

Constitutions Applications Other Examples Ineffi cient inertia The role of the middle class in democratization Coalition formation in democratic systems Commitment, (civil or international) conflict and peace Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 52 / 63

General Model General Model Based on Acemoglu, Egorov and Sonin (forthcoming). We now return to the general model with stochastic elements and discount factor < 1 Key challenge: when the game is finite or there is little discounting (and no stochastic shocks), different paths can be evaluated in terms of the utility from the limit state they will lead to. This is no longer true in the general model. Nevertheless, increasing differences in preferences and the monotonic quasi-median voter property enable us to provide a characterization of MVE. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 53 / 63

General Model Equilibria Approach Introduce different environments with different payoffs and power distributions. Now any MPE in pure strategies can be represented by a set of transition mappings {φ E } such that if s t 1 = s, and environment E t = E, then s t = φ E (s) along the equilibrium path. Transition mapping φ = {φ E : S S} is monotone if for any s 1, s 2 S with s 1 s 2, φ E (s 1 ) φ E (s 2 ). natural, given monotonic median voter property. Definition of MVE and recursive representation the same as before: V φ E,i (s) = w E,i (s) + β E E q ( E, E ) V φ E,i (φ E (s)) where E denotes different environments with different payoffs, transition costs or political processes, and q (E, E ) denotes transition probabilities. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 54 / 63

General Model Equilibria General Results Theorem 1. There exists an MVE φ = {φ E } E E. Furthermore, there exists a limit state s τ = s τ+1 = = s (with probability 1) but this limit state depends on the timing and realization of stochastic shocks and the path to a limit state need not be monotone. 2. The MVE is (generically) unique if at least one of the following conditions holds: (i) for every environment E E and any state s S, M E,s is a singleton; (ii) in each environment, only one-step transitions are possible; each player s preferences are single-peaked; and moreover, for each state s there is a player i such that i M E,s for all E E and the peaks (for all E E) of i s preferences do not lie on different sides of s. Thus monotone transition mappings arise naturally. though equilibria without such monotonicity may exist. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 55 / 63

General Model Equilibria MPE vs. Markov Voting Equilibria Theorem There is again a close connection between MPE and MVE. For any MVE φ (monotone or not) there exists a set of protocols such that there exists a Markov Perfect equilibrium of the game above which implements φ. Conversely, if for some set of protocols and some MPE σ, the corresponding transition mapping φ = {φ E } E E is monotone, then it is MVE. In addition, if the set of quasi-median voters in two different states have either none or one individual in common, and only one-step transitions are possible, every MPE corresponds to a monotone MVE (under any protocol). For each MVE, there exists a protocol π such that the resulting (pure-strategy) MPE induces transitions that coincide with the MVE. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 56 / 63

Effi ciency General Model Effi ciency Theorem If each β E is suffi ciently small, then the limiting state is Pareto effi cient. Otherwise the limiting state may be Pareto ineffi cient. Recall in the above example that Pareto ineffi ciency arises when the discount factor is large. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 57 / 63

General Model Effi ciency Monotone Comparative Statics Theorem Suppose that environments E 1 and E 2 coincide on S = [1, s] S and β E 1 = β E 2, φ 1 and φ 2 are MVE in these environments. Suppose x S is such that φ 1 (x) = x. Then φ 2 (x) x. Implication, suppose that φ 1 (x) = x is reached before there is a switch to E 2. Then for all subsequent t, s t x. Intuition: if some part of the state space is unaffected by shocks, it is either reached without shocks or not reached at all. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 58 / 63

General Model Application: Conflict between Status Quo and Extremist Groups Application: Implication of Radical Politics There is a fixed set of n players (groups) N = { l,..., r} (so n = l + r + 1). We interpret the order of groups as representing some economic interests (poor vs. rich) or political views. Stage payoff with policy p (and repression of groups j / H s ): u i (p) = (p b i ) 2 cost of repression. Repression excludes certain groups from political participation. group 0, ruling in state 0). Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 59 / 63

General Model Application: Conflict between Status Quo and Extremist Groups Application (continued) The weight of each group i N is denoted by γ i and represents the number of people within the group, and thus the group s political power. in state s, coalition X is winning if and only if i Hs X γ i > 1 2 i H s γ i. Incorporating repression, payoffs given by: u i (p) = (p b i ) 2 j / Hs γ j C j. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 60 / 63

General Model Application: Conflict between Status Quo and Extremist Groups MVE First choose the policy within the period, and then dynamics. The key issue is the likelihood of radicals coming to power. Shocks: radicals (extremists) can come to power in the future even if they look weak today. If they come to power, they will use repression against non-radical, traditional groups Implication: repression against radicals before they come to power. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 61 / 63

General Model Strategic Complementarities in Repression Application: Conflict between Status Quo and Extremist Groups Proposition (Strategic Complementarity) Suppose the costs of repressing other groups declines for the radicals. Then it becomes more likely that φ (s) > s for at least one s 0. The history of repression in places such as Russia may not be due to the culture of repression but to small differences in costs of repression (resulting from political institutions and economic structure). Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 62 / 63

General Model Application: Conflict between Status Quo and Extremist Groups Conclusion A general approach to modeling dynamics of change in power and its economic and effi ciency implications. Some general lessons and rich applications, but many interesting applications will also require new theory to be developed (e.g., with more heterogeneity or idiosyncratic shocks for problems such as social mobility). Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 2-3 February 8 and 13, 2018. 63 / 63