The Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Similar documents
Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

Lecture 3: Dynamics of small open economies

Dynamic Problem Set 1 Solutions

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 3

Dynamic Optimization Using Lagrange Multipliers

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Optimization Over Time

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. February 6, 2018

Economics 101 Spring 2001 Section 4 - Hallam Problem Set #5

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Slides II - Dynamic Programming

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

The Real Business Cycle Model

Topic 6: Consumption, Income, and Saving

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Econ 504, Lecture 1: Transversality and Stochastic Lagrange Multipliers

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

Practice Problems 2 (Ozan Eksi) ( 1 + r )i E t y t+i + (1 + r)a t

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Dynamic Optimization Problem. April 2, Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo. Math Camp Day 4. Daiki Kishishita.

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

Topic 8: Optimal Investment

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Traditional vs. Correct Transversality Conditions, plus answers to problem set due 1/28/99

Problem Set # 2 Dynamic Part - Math Camp

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 21: Stochastic Dynamic Programming and Applications

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

This process was named creative destruction by Joseph Schumpeter.

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Macroeconomics Theory II

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 2

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Consumption / Savings Decisions

Problem 1 (30 points)

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 2 - Solution

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

Economics 210B Due: September 16, Problem Set 10. s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0 given, lim. and

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

Notes on Winnie Choi s Paper (Draft: November 4, 2004; Revised: November 9, 2004)

Mankiw Chapter 11. Aggregate Demand I. Building the IS-LM Model

Advanced Macroeconomics

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

The Necessity of the Transversality Condition at Infinity: A (Very) Special Case

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Suggested Solutions to Homework #6 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

Lecture 8: Consumption-Savings Decisions

Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

The Hansen Singleton analysis

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Cointegration and the Ramsey Model

Asset Pricing. Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model. June 20, 2006

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, Partial Answer Key

Second Welfare Theorem

Organizational Equilibrium with Capital

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Homework 3 - Partial Answers

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Lecture 1: Introduction

Transcription:

The Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko 1 / 15

A 2-period formulation 2-period problem, periods 0 and 1. Within-period (instantaneous) utility function is quadratic: u(c t ) = 1 2 (c t c) 2. Freely borrow/lend at the constant real interest rate r. Endowments y 0 and y 1 are known at time 0. c is the bliss consumption level. If c t = c, a consumer attains the maximum utility possible, equal to 0. c c t so that the marginal utility is positive: c c t > 0. β (0, 1) is the time discount factor. β(1 + r) = 1. 2 / 15

Optimization problem max U(c 0, c 1 ) = 1 c 0 0,c 1 0 2 (c 0 c) 2 β 1 2 (c 1 c) 2 s.t. c 0 + c 1 1 + r = y 0 + y 1 1 + r, where β (0, 1) is the time discount factor. For this utility function, MU 0 = c c 0 MU 1 = β( c c 1 ). 3 / 15

Optimum At the optimum, the following two equations should be satisfied: (c c 0) = β(1 + r)(c c 1) c 0 + c 1 1 + r = y 0 + y 1 1 + r. Since we assumed that β = 1 1+r, we can write the first of those equations as c c 0 = c c 1, or c 0 = c 1. Plugging this equilibrium condition into the second equation, we obtain c 0 + c 0 1+r = y 0 + y 1 1+r, or c 0 = c 1 = 1 + r ( y 0 + y ) 1. 2 + r 1 + r Consumer, for these preferences, will prefer to smooth consumption across periods perfectly. 4 / 15

Infinite horizon 1 Assume instead that a consumer s horizon is infinite, and s/he chooses consumption for periods t = 0, 1, 2,... In this case, max U(c 0, c 1, c 2,...) = 1 c 0 0,c 1 0,c 2 0,... 2 (c 0 c) 2 +β 1 }{{} 2 (c 1 c) 2 }{{} =u(c 0 ) =u(c 1 ) + β 2 1 2 (c 2 c) 2 + β3 1 }{{} 2 (c 3 c) 2 +... }{{} =u(c 2 ) =u(c 3 ) s.t. c 0 + c 1 1 + r + c 2 (1 + r) 2 + c 3 (1 + r) 3 +... = y 0 + y 1 1 + r + y 2 (1 + r) 2 + y 3 + (1 + r) 3 +... 5 / 15

Infinite horizon 2 More compactly, max U(c 0, c 1, c 2,...) = c 0 0,c 1 0,c 2 0,... s.t. [ 12 ] βt (c t c) 2 c t (1 + r) t = y t (1 + r) t. Now, instead of finding just c 0 and c 1, we will need to find the whole (infinite) sequence {c 0, c 1, c 2,...}. Not so hard! Just need the (optimality) Euler equations and the lifetime budget constraint. 6 / 15

The equations to be satisfied at the optimum MU 1 = (1 + r)mu 2 MU 2 = (1 + r)mu 3 MU 3 = (1 + r)mu 4 MU 4 = (1 + r)mu 5. c t (1 + r) t = y t (1 + r) t. 7 / 15

In terms of our utility function, the following equations should be satisfied at the optimum: c c 0 = (1 + r) β(c c }{{}}{{ 1) } MU 0 MU 1 β(c c }{{ 1) = (1 + r) β 2 (c c }}{{ 2) } MU 1 MU 2 β 2 (c c }{{ 2) = (1 + r) β 3 (c c }}{{ 3) } MU 2. MU 3 c t (1 + r) t = y t (1 + r) t. Since we assume that β = 1 1+r, the sequence of Euler equations implies c 0 = c 1, c 1 = c 2, c 2 = c 3... c 0 = c 1 = c 2 = c 3 =... = c. 8 / 15

Plugging the result into the lifetime budget constraint, Note that c 1 (1 + r) t = y t (1 + r) t. 1 (1 + r) t = 1 + 1 1 + r + 1 (1 + r) 2 + 1 (1 + r) 3 +..., and 1 1+r < 1. We want to find S = 1 + x + x2 + x 3 +..., where x 1 1 1+r. This sum will be equal to 1 x = 1 = 1+r 1 1 r. 1+r [ c = c 0 = c 1 = c 2 =... = r ] y t 1 + r (1 + r) t. }{{} y p Milton Friedman: individual consumption in each period should be related to an estimate of the permanent income. 9 / 15

Aside It is easy to show that S = 1 + x + x 2 + x 3 + x 4 +... = 1, for x < 1. 1 x Multiply the LHS and RHS of the equation by x, xs = x + x 2 + x 3 + x 4 + x 5 +..., and subtract the result from S, to obtain S xs = (1+x+x 2 +x 3 +x 4 +...) (x+x 2 +x 3 +x 4 +...) = 1. Thus, S = 1 1 x. 10 / 15

Example: constant flow of endowments If y 0 = y 1 = y 2 =... = y, c will be equal to [ r 1 + r y 1 + 1 ] 1 + r + 1 (1 + r) 2 + 1 (1 + r) 3 +... r = y 1 + r 1 + r r = y 11 / 15

Stochastic incomes In reality, future incomes are uncertain (that is, stochastic). At time t, when making consumption decision for time t, we do not know for sure {y t+1, y t+2, y t+3, y t+4,...}. In this case, it does not make sense to set consumptions for periods c t+1, c t+2,... once and for all, since new information about future incomes and permanent income will arrive in periods following t. The optimality (Euler) condition that links optimal consumptions in periods t and t + 1, for the utility function we adopted, will read as: c t = E t (c t+1), where E t ( ) is expectation conditional on information (about future endowments) available at time t. 12 / 15

Stochastic Euler equation Subtracting c t from both sides, E t ( c t+1 c t ) = Et c t+1 = 0. It means that the expected future change in consumption, given all the available information at time t, is equal to zero, that is consumption does not change between periods t and t + 1 if there is no additional information arriving between periods t and t + 1 about consumer s incomes. In statistics, a variable that has this property is called a martingale. An implication of the martingale property of consumption is that consumption in period t + 1 will differ from consumption in period t only if a consumer receives unexpected news about his permanent income. 13 / 15

Optimal consumption with stochastic incomes In terms of the levels of consumption, we may derive the following relationship: c t = y p t = E t [ ( r y t + y t+1 1 + r 1 + r + y t+2 (1 + r) 2 + y )] t+3 (1 + r) 3 +.... 14 / 15

Important implications Consumption will change between adjacent periods if (a consumer s estimate of) the permanent income changes Consumption will adjust by a larger margin if an unexpected change in income is permanent (e.g., compare disability vs. short spell of unemployment). If the government contemplates about some policy affecting individual incomes (say, a tax cut) and wants to boost the economy via an increase in the aggregate consumption, it will only succeed if the policy affects permanent incomes a lot (say, a permanent reduction in income taxes). Otherwise, the reaction of consumers will be weak, if any. 15 / 15