A Note on Profitable Mergers. in a Hierarchical Stackelberg Model

Similar documents
Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Advanced Microeconomics

Quantity-setting games with a dominant

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Free Entry and Social Inefficiency under Vertical Oligopoly: Revisited

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Quantity-setting games with a dominant firm

Durable goods monopolist

Mixed duopolies with advance production

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Basics of Game Theory

Sequential mergers with differing differentiation levels

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

EconS Sequential Competition

Static Models of Oligopoly

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games

1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E.

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS PROFITABILITY OF HORIZONTAL MERGERS IN TRIGGER STRATEGY GAME. Berardino Cesiy University of Rome Tor Vergata

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

Profitability of price and quantity strategies in a duopoly with vertical product differentiation

Oligopoly. Firm s Profit Maximization Firm i s profit maximization problem: Static oligopoly model with n firms producing homogenous product.

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot

OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís**

Backwards Induction. Extensive-Form Representation. Backwards Induction (cont ) The player 2 s optimization problem in the second stage

Supermodular Games. Ichiro Obara. February 6, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Supermodular Games February 6, / 21

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Cartel Stability in a Dynamic Oligopoly with Sticky Prices

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana

Some Simple Graphical Interpretations of the. Herfindahl-Hirshman Index and their Implications

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition

On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

On Hotelling s Stability in Competition

Welfare Reducing Mergers in Differentiated Oligopolies with Free Entry

Convexity of Bertrand oligopoly TU-games with differentiated products

ECO 2901 EMPIRICAL INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Industrial Organization

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 11: Introduction to Game Theory 3

Price setting on a network

Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information

4: Dynamic games. Concordia February 6, 2017

Free Entry Bertrand Competition

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network

Online Appendix for Dynamic Ex Post Equilibrium, Welfare, and Optimal Trading Frequency in Double Auctions

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE)

Solving Extensive Form Games

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) -

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters

Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration with Downstream Oligopsony and Oligopoly

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Overview. Producer Theory. Consumer Theory. Exchange

Answer Key: Problem Set 1

Bilateral Trading in Divisible Double Auctions

Stochastic Equilibrium Problems arising in the energy industry

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 29 Mar 2012

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1

Own price influences in a Stackelberg leadership with demand uncertainty

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION. Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar

On the Coalitional Stability of Monopoly Power in Differentiated

Mixed oligopoly in a two-dimensional city y

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Ranking Bertrand, Cournot and Supply Function Equilibria in Oligopoly

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game

Price and Capacity Competition

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

The Impact of Organizer Market Structure on Participant Entry Behavior in a Multi-Tournament Environment

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model

Product Variety, Price Elasticity of Demand and Fixed Cost in Spatial Models

Introduction to Game Theory

A Note on Bank Behavior and Monetary Policies in an Oligopolistic Market

Transcription:

Working Paper Series No.80, Faculty of Economics, Niigata University A Note on Profitable Mergers in a Hierarchical Stackelberg Model Kojun Hamada Series No.80 Address: 8050 Ikarashi 2-no-cho, Niigata City, 950-2181 Japan Tel. and fax: +81-25-262-6538 E-mail address: khamada@econ.niigata-u.ac.jp

A Note on Profitable Mergers in a Hierarchical Stackelberg Model Kojun Hamada Faculty of Economics, Niigata University Abstract In this paper, we attempt to examine whether or not mergers are profitable in a hierarchical Stackelberg model under quantity competition. Unfortunately, a significant result cannot be obtained under general demand function, with regard to whether or not mergers are profitable, although we would expect this result to be satisfied. Instead, we show that mergers are always profitable, regardless of any curvature of demand under a specified demand structure. This result supports the intuition that mergers are always profitable in a hierarchical Stackelberg model, although the result is accompanied with some loss of generality on the functional form. Keywords: hierarchical Stackelberg model; profitable merger JEL classification: D43; L13 Address: 8050 Ikarashi 2-no-cho, Niigata City, 950-2181 Japan Tel. and fax: +81-25-262-6538 E-mail address: khamada@econ.niigata-u.ac.jp 1

1 Introduction This paper attempts to examine whether or not mergers are profitable in a hierarchical Stackelberg model under quantity competition. Under the hierarchical Stackelberg model (henceforth HSM), multiple firms choose outputs sequentially under Stackelberg quantity competition. In a representative paper on the analysis of the HSM, Boyer and Moreaux (1986) showed that competitive equilibrium can be seen as the limit of some hierarchical game in which the rights (or information) of the players can be strictly ordered. Vives (1988) reexamined the relationship between potential competition, industry structure, and welfare in a market, subject to a sequential entry threat where firms can make quantity commitments and have access to a constant returns technology. It is shown that, provided the entry is not blocked, the incumbent(s) will either prevent entry or allow all the potential entrants in. Anderson and Engers (1992) compared an n-firm Cournot model with an n-hierarchical Stackelberg model and they showed that the Stackelberg equilibrium price is lower, total surplus is higher, and total profits are lower. The existing literature has paid scant attention to the profitability of mergers in a HSM. In this paper, we investigate in more details the profitability of mergers in the HSM. As a well-known result, Salant, Switzer, and Reynolds (1983) showed that mergers are not profitable if the market share of the merged firm does not exceed over 80% under Cournot quantity competition. Daugherty (1990) and Huck, Konlad, and Müller (2001) independently presented the similar extensive results under the two-stage Stackelberg quantity competition. They showed that any merger between a leader and a follower is profitable. We extend the existing analyses on profitable mergers to an n-hierarchical Stackelberg model and examine the 2

profit of mergers under the HSM. We focus on the analysis of an n-hierarchical Stackelberg equilibrium, applying the same setting as in the HSM in Anderson and Engers (1992) and attempt to examine whether or not mergers are profitable. It is a well-known fact that when the demand curve is linear, any merger is profitable in a HSM. Likewise, it is a well-known folk theorem that any merger is profitable in a HSM, even if demand structure is in a more general form. So far, however, it has not yet been clarified that any merger is profitable in a HSM. Thus, we attempt to examine whether or not any merger is profitable in a HSM. Unfortunately, a significant result cannot be obtained under general demand function, with regard to whether or not any merger is profitable, although we would expect this result to be satisfied as a folk theorem. Instead, we focus on analyzing a specified form of demand function, which takes the curvature of the more general demand function into consideration, including that the functions are linear, concave and convex. We show that any merger is profitable, regardless of any curvature of the demand curve under this specified demand function. This result supports the intuition that any merger is profitable in a hierarchical Stackelberg model, although the result is accompanied with some loss of generality on the functional form of demand. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the model and derives firms outputs and profits in the equilibrium. Section 3 examines whether or not mergers are profitable under general demand structure. Section 4 specifies the form of demand function and presents the main results. Section 5 presents a discussion on the results in this paper. 3

2 The model In Section 2, we describe a situation where n firms choose output sequentially in a HSM. The Stackelberg equilibrium is the subgame perfect outcome that arises when firms choose their outputs sequentially according to some exogenously determined order of moves. We shall assume that firms that supply perfect substitutes are identical, except for the order of moves. The output level of firm i =1, 2,,n is denoted by q i. The total output and the price of homogeneous goods are denoted by Q n i=1 q i and P, respectively. The market demand function is denoted by Q = Q(P ). The demand function is always monotonically decreasing, Q (P ) < 0. Thus, the inverse demand function exists and it is given by P = P (Q),P (Q) < 0. It is assumed to be more than twice differentiable for all Q>0. The demand specification that we consider in Section 2 is a general one. Later on, in Section 4, we specify the demand function. Therefore, the inverse demand function is allowed to be convex, P (Q) > 0, or concave, P (Q) < 0, and it is linear when P (Q) =0. It is assumed that the second-order conditions for profit maximization for all firms are satisfied. In particular, 2P + P q i < 0, q i is assumed. It is presumed that the output levels for all firms in the equilibrium are the interior solution. Furthermore, in order to satisfy the condition that the reaction functions of all firms are strictly downward-sloping and as a result, the equilibrium is unique and stable, it is assumed that the usual downward-sloping marginal revenue condition is satisfied: MR i Q i = P + P q i < 0; Q i j i q j as MR i (q i ) P + P q i < 0, q i. For simplification of analysis, it is assumed that the marginal cost is constant and it is denoted by c. Firm i s profit is denoted by π i (q i ) [P (q i + Q i ) c]q i ; Q i j i q i. The solution concept under the HSM is the subgame perfect equilibrium, which can be 4

obtained by backward induction. In the following subsection, we derive outputs and profits of firms in the equilibrium by solving the profit maximization problems from firm n to firm 1 in backward sequence. 2.1 The final firm First, we solve the profit maximization problem of the final firm (firm n) in a HSM. Firm n s profit is denoted by π n (q n ; Q n ) [P (q n + Q n ) c]q n ; Q n n 1 i=1 q i = q 1 + + q n 1. The f.o.c. is as follows: π n (q n ; Q n ) q n = P (Q)+P (Q)q n c =0. (1) By assumption, the s.o.c. is satisfied. From (1), the reaction function of firm n is obtained. It is denoted by q n r n (Q n ). Substituting q n = r n (Q n ) into (1), the following identity is satisfied: P (r n (Q n )+Q n )+P (r n (Q n )+Q n )r n (Q n ) c 0 r n (Q n ) P (r n(q n )+Q n ) c P. (2) (r n (Q n )+Q n ) Totally differentiating (2) with regard to Q n, we can obtain the slope of the reaction function of firm n as follows: P (1 + r n)+p r n + P (1 + r n)r n =0 r n = P + P q n 2P + P q n < 0 (3) q n = P (1 + 2r n) P (1 + r n > 0. (4) ) By assumption, the reaction function of firm n is strictly downward-sloping (r n < 0). It is shown that 1 + r n = P 2P +P q n > 0 by readily calculating. Note that 1 <r n(q n ) < 0, which 5

guarantees the uniqueness and the stability of the equilibrium. From (4), r n 1 2 if and only if P 0. From (3), if P = 0, then r n = 1 2. (3) is precisely rewritten as r n (Q n) = P (r n(q n )+Q n )+P (r n(q n )+Q n )r n(q n ) 2P (r n(q n )+Q n )+P (r n(q n )+Q n )r n(q n ). Totally differentiating (3) with regard to Q n once again and substituting (3) and (4) into r n, we can obtain the second derivative of the reaction function of firm n as follows: r n = (P P (P ) 2 )(1 + r n )r n + P P r n (2P + P q n ) 2 = P {P P + (2(P ) 2 P P )q n } (2P + P q n ) 3 (5) = (1 + r n )2 {(P P (P ) 2 )+(2P P 3(P ) 2 )r n } P P. (6) The sign of r n is indeterminate until the value of q n is solved by backward induction in the subgame perfect equilibrium. 1 2.2 The penultimate firm Next, we solve the profit maximization problem of the penultimate firm (firm n 1) in a HSM. This problem is described as follows: max π n 1 (q n 1 ; q n,q (n 1) )=[P(q n 1 + q n + Q (n 1) ) c]q n 1, (7) q n 1 subject to q n = r n (Q n ), 1 When P < 0, if a necessary condition, (P ) 2 P P > 0 ( P > (P ) 2 ; (P ) 2 P P < 0) is satisfied, 2(P ) 2 P P > 0 is satisfied and the bracket in the numerator in (5) is positive. The numerator and denominator in (5) are negative and r n > 0 is satisfied as a result. The necessary condition, (P ) 2 P P > 0, includes P > 0 as a special case. By the way, this condition implies that the absolute risk aversion of the demand function (in other words, the first-derivative of the utility function U(Q) of the representative consumer) is increasing, because the Arrow-Pratt measure of absolute risk-aversion (ARA), which is defined by R f (x) f (x) f (x) is monotonically increasing, that is, (R P (x)) =( P P ) = (P ) 2 P P (P ) 2 > 0. However, the implication of the increasing ARA about the demand function which is derived as the first-derivative of the utility function is not clear. On the other hand, when P > 0, we cannot determine the sign of r n before solving the equation for q n. 6

where Q (n 1) = n 2 i=1 q i = q 1 + + q n 2. The f.o.c. is as follows: π n 1 (q n 1 ; r n (Q n ),Q (n 1) ) q n 1 = P + P (1 + r n)q n 1 c =0. (8) By assumption, the s.o.c. of this problem is satisfied and the marginal revenue of firm n 1is downward-sloping. Like subsection 2.1, the reaction function of firm n 1 can be obtained by (8). It is denoted by q n 1 = r n 1 (Q (n 1) ). Substituting q n 1 = r n 1 (Q (n 1) ) into (8), the following identity is satisfied: P (r n 1 (Q (n 1) )+q n + Q (n 1) )+P (r n 1 (Q (n 1) )+q n + Q (n 1) )(1 + r n )r n 1(Q (n 1) ) c 0 r n 1 (Q (n 1) ) P (r n 1(Q (n 1) )+q n + Q (n 1) ) c P (r n 1 (Q (n 1) )+q n + Q (n 1) )(1 + r n), (9) where q n = r n (Q n ) = r n (q n 1 + Q (n 1) ) = r n (r n 1 (Q (n 1) )+Q (n 1) ). Note that q n Q (n 1) = r n (1 + r n 1 ). Totally differentiating (9) with regard to Q (n 1), we obtain the following equation: (P + P (1 + r n )r n 1)(1 + r n 1 )(1 + r n )+P (1 + r n )r n 1 + P r n (1 + r n 1 )r n 1 =0 r n 1 = (P + P (1 + r n )r n 1)(1 + r n )+P r n r n 1 (2P + P (1 + r n )r n 1)(1 + r n )+P r n r. (10) n 1 By (3) and (6), substituting r n and r n into (10), we obtain the slope of the reaction function of firm n 1 as follows: r n 1 = (2P + P q n ) 2 +[3P P + (3(P ) 2 P P )q n ]q n 1 2(2P + P q n ) 2 +[3P P + (3(P ) 2 P P )q n ]q n 1. (11) Comparing (1) with (8), we obtain the following equation: q n =(1+r n)q n 1 = P 2P + P q n q n 1. (12) By (3) and (12), it is satisfied that q n =(1+r n )q n 1 <q n 1. Arranging (12), the following quadratic equation with regard to q n is derived: P (q n ) 2 +2P q n P q n 1 =0. (13) 7

When P 0, solving the quadratic equation (13) with regard to q n, we obtain the solutions, q n = P ± (P ) 2 +P P q n 1 P = P ± (P )(P +P q n 1 ) P. No matter what the sign of P is, q n = P (P )(P +P q n 1 ) P > 0 is the unique proper solution. 2 Although, because of calculating complexity, we do not substitute q n = P (P )(P +P q n 1 ) P > 0 into the slope of the reaction function in (11), r n 1 can be represented as a function of q n 1. Like the sign of r n is indeterminate until q n is solved in the subgame perfect equilibrium in subsection 2.1, the sign of r n 1 is indeterminate until q n and q n 1 are derived. However, in advance, we assume that the slope of the reaction function of firm n 1, r n 1, is negative, the same as that of firm n. 3 By assumption, r n 1 < 0 is satisfied. In this case, it is shown that both numerator and denominator in (11) are positive and the denominator exceeds the numerator. As a result, 1+r n 1 = (2P +P q n) 2 2(2P +P q n) 2 +[3P P +(3(P ) 2 P P )q n]q n 1 > 0. 4 The uniqueness and the stability of the equilibrium is guaranteed under the condition, 1 <r n 1 (Q (n 1)) < 0. Totally differentiating (11) with regard to Q (n 1) once again and arranging it, we can obtain the second derivative of the reaction function of firm n 1 as follows: r n 1 = A(2A B AB ) (2A 2 + B) 2 ; A 2P + P q n < 0, B (3P P + (3(P ) 2 P P )q n )q n 1. (14) 2 The reason why this solution is proper and the other is not is as follows: P 7 0 P 7 p (P )(P + P q n 1) = p ( P ) 2 + P P q n 1 is satisfied. When P > 0, the other solution exceeds P P, P + (P ) 2 +P P q n 1 P > P P. Under this solution, the assumption, P + P q n < 0( q n < P P ), is not satisfied. When P < 0, the numerator of q n must be negative, although the numerator of the other solution is positive, P + p (P )(P + P q n 1) > 0. 3 Similar to the explanation of footnote 1, when P < 0, if (P ) 2 P P > 0 (increasing ARA of demand function), both numerator and denominator in (11) are positive and r n 1 < 0 is satisfied. At least, if 3P P + (3(P ) 2 P P )q n > 0, then r n 1 < 0 is necessarily satisfied. 4 By (11), r n 1 7 1 2 3P P + (3(P ) 2 P P )q n? 0. P =0 r n 1 = 1 2. 8

The sign of r n 1 determined. 5 is indeterminate until the outputs in the subgame perfect equilibrium are 2.3 The antepenultimate firm We proceed to solve the profit maximization problem of the antepenultimate firm (firm n 2). This problem is described as follows: max π n 2 (q n 2 ; {q n,q n 1 },Q (n 2) )=[P(q n 2 + q n 1 + q n + Q (n 2) ) c]q n 2, (15) q n 2 s.t. q n = r n (Q n ) and q n 1 = r n 1 (Q (n 1) ). The f.o.c. is as follows: π n 2 (q n 2 ; {q n,q n 1 },Q (n 2) ) q n 2 = P + P (1 + r n)(1 + r n 1)q n 2 c =0. (16) By assumption, the s.o.c. of this problem is satisfied and the marginal revenue of firm n 2is downward-sloping. Like subsection 2.2, the reaction function of firm n 2, q n 2 = r n 2 (Q (n 2) ), can be obtained from (16), and the slope is assumed to be downward-sloping, r n 2 < 0. Substituting q n 2 = r n 2 (Q (n 2) ) into (16), the following identity is satisfied: P (r n 2 (Q (n 2) )+q n + q n 1 + Q (n 2) ) c r n 2 (Q (n 2) ) P (r n 2 (Q (n 2) )+q n + q n 1 + Q (n 2) )(1 + r n )(1 + (17) r n 1 ), where q n = r n (r n 2 (Q (n 2) )+r n 1 (r n 2 (Q (n 2) )+Q (n 2) )+Q (n 2) ) and q n 1 = r n 1 (r n 2 (Q (n 2) )+Q (n 2) )+Q (n 2) ). Note that and q n 1 Q (n 2) = r n 1 (1 + r n 2 ). q n Q (n 2) = r n(1 + r n 1 )(1 + r n 2 ) 5 A = ((2P + P q n)+(3p + P q n)r n)(1 + r n 1) and B =[3P P + (3(P ) 2 P P )q n]r n 1 + [((3(P ) 2 + 3P P )+(5P P P P (4) )q n)(1 + r n) + (3(P ) 2 P P )r n](1 + r n 1)q n 1. It is very difficult to derive (2A B AB ) explicitly, owing to calculating complexity. 9

Totally differentiating (17) with regard to Q (n 2), we obtain the following equation: r n 2 = (P + P (1 + r n)(1 + r n 1)r n 2)(1 + r n)(1 + r n 1)+P ((1 + r n 1) 2 r n +(1+r n)r n 1)r n 2 (2P + P (1 + r n)(1 + r n 1 )rn 2)(1 + r n)(1 + r n 1 )+P. (18) ((1 + r n 1 )2 r n +(1+r n)r n 1 )rn 2 By substituting r n, r n, r n 1, and r n 1 into (18), r n 2 can be represented by the reduced form that is expressed by only q n, q n 1, and q n 2 in principle, although we cannot calculate it due to a very complicated calculating work. By assumption, the reaction function of firm n 2 in (18) is downward-sloping, that is, r n 2 < 0. In this case, it is shown that both numerator and denominator in (18) are negative and the absolute vale of the denominator exceeds that of the numerator. As a result, 1 + r n 2 > 0 is satisfied.6 The uniqueness and the stability of the equilibrium is guaranteed under the condition, 1 <r n 2 < 0. Comparing (8) with (16), we obtain the following equation: q n 1 =(1+r n 1 )q n 2. (19) By (19) and r n 1 < 0, q n 1 =(1+r n 1 )q n 2 <q n 2 is satisfied. Totally differentiating (18) with regard to Q (n 2) once again and arranging it, we can obtain the second derivative of the reaction function of firm n 2, r n 2 in principle, although in practice, it is too difficult to derive it owing to calculating complexity. 7 2P (1+r n )(1+r n 1 ) (2P +P (1+r n )(1+r n 1 )r n 2)(1+r n )(1+r n 1 )+P ((1+r n 1 )2 r n +(1+r n )r 6 1+r n 2 = > 0. n 1 )r n 2 7 By replacing it as 1 + r n 1 = C ; C 2P (1 + r C+D n)(1 + r n 1),D {P (1 + r n) 2 (1 + r n 1) 2 + P ((1 + r n 1) 2 r n +(1+r n)r n 1)}r n 2, r n 2 = C D CD (C+D) 2. It is very difficult to derive (C D CD ) explicitly, owing to calculating complexity. The sign of r n 2 is indeterminate until the outputs in the subgame perfect equilibrium are determined. 10

2.4 The intermediate firm By inducing backward in turn, we can deal with the profit maximization problem of the intermediate firm (firm i). This problem is as follows: max q i π i (q i ; {q n,q n 1,,q i+1 },Q i )=[P (q i + n j=i+1 q j + Q i ) c]q i, (20) s.t. q n = r n (Q n ),q n 1 = r n 1 (Q (n 1) ),, q i+1 = r i+1 (Q (i+1) ). The f.o.c. is as follows: P + P n j=i+1 (1 + r j )q i c =0. (21) When i = n, the f.o.c. can be calculated as the product term in (21) is unity, n j=i+1 (1+r j )=1. By assumption, the s.o.c. is satisfied and the marginal revenue of firm i is downward-sloping. The reaction function of firm i, q i = r i (Q i ), can be obtained from (21), and the slope is assumed to be downward-sloping, r i < 0. Substituting q i = r i (Q i ) into (21), the following identity is satisfied: P c r i (Q i ) P n j=i+1 (1 + (22) r j ). Note that q i+m Q i = r i+m n j=i+m+1 (1 + r j ). Totally differentiating (22) with regard to Q i, we obtain the following equation: Q r i = P +(P +P Q Q )q i P ; Y ny j=i+1 (1 + r j) Q Q P r i = (P + P n j=i+1 (1 + r n j)r i) j=i+1 (1 + r j)+p n Q Q { P (2P + P n j=i+1 (1 + r j )ri) n j=i+1 (1 + r j )+P n { k=i+1 (r k k=i+1 (r k Q Q n l=k+1 (1 + r k 1 l) j=i+1 (1 + r j) 2 )}q i Q n l=k+1 (1 + r )Q k 1 l j=i+1 (1 +. (23) r j )2 )}q i r i cannot be represented by the reduced form in practice, owing to calculation complexity. By assumption, the reaction function of firm i in (23) is downward-sloping, that is, r i < 0. In this case, it is shown that both numerator and denominator in (23) are negative and the absolute 11

value of the denominator exceeds that of the numerator. As a result, 1+r i > 0 is satisfied.8 The uniqueness and the stability of the equilibrium is guaranteed under the condition, 1 <r i < 0. It is too difficult to derive the second derivative of the reaction function of firm i, r i sign of r i in practice. The is indeterminate until the outputs in the subgame perfect equilibrium are determined. 2.5 Comparison of outputs and profits in the equilibrium We compare the output levels and firms profits in the equilibrium under the HSM. As we assume 1 <r i < 0 i, the interior solution for all firms is guaranteed in the subgame perfect equilibrium. The assumption, 1 + r i > 0, implies that the self-effect of the output on the profit function exceeds over the cross-effect and guarantees the uniqueness and the stability of equilibrium. First, the following proposition can be derived with regard to the firms outputs in the HSM. Proposition 1. The output of the firm whose order of move is fast is always greater than that of later firms, under general demand function. That is, q 1 >q 2 > >q i >q i+1 > >q n 1 >q n. (24) 8 1+r i = 2P Q nj=i+1 (1+r j ) (2P +P Q nj=i+1 (1+r j )r i) Q n j=i+1 (1+r j )+P { P n k=i+1 (r k The bracket in the denominator of the above equation is as follows: P n k=i+1 (r k Q n l=k+1 (1 + r l) Q k 1 j=i+1 (1 + r j) 2 ) = r n(1 + r n 1) 2 (1 + r n 2) 2 (1 + r i+1) 2 + (1+r n)r n 1(1 + r n 2) 2 (1 + r i+1) 2 + (1+r n)(1 + r n 1)r n 2(1 + r n 3) 2 (1 + r i+1) 2 + + (1+r n)(1 + r n 1) (1 + r i+3)r i+2(1 + r i+1) 2 Q nl=k+1 (1+r l )Q k 1 j=i+1 (1+r j )2 )}q i > 0. + (1+r n)(1 + r n 1) (1 + r i+3)(1 + r i+2)r i+1. 12

Proof. The result is immediately derived by comparing the two adjoining first-order conditions between firm i and i + 1. The margins of firm i and i + 1 are by f.o.c. as follows: P c = P By (25), the following equation is satisfied: n n (1 + r j)q i = P (1 + r j)q i+1. (25) j=i+1 j=i+2 (1 + r i+1 )q i = q i+1 i. (26) By (26) and r i+1 < 0, q i > (1 + r i+1 )q i = q i+1 is satisfied. HSM. Second, the following proposition can be obtained with regard to the firms profits in the Proposition 2. The profit of the firm whose order of move is fast is always greater than that of later firms, under general demand function. That is, π 1 >π 2 > >π i >π i+1 > >π n 1 >π n. (27) Proof. The result is immediately derived from Proposition 1. By the first-order conditions of firms i and i + 1, (25), the profits of firm i and i + 1 are rewritten as follows: π i = (P c)q i = P n j=i+1 π i+1 = (P c)q i+1 = P n j=i+2 (1 + r j)q 2 i, (28) (1 + r j )q2 i+1. (29) By (28) and (29), π i >π i+1 if and only if (1 + r i+1 )q2 i >q2 i+1. This inequality holds because if (1 + r i+1 )q i = q i+1, then (1 + r i+1 )q2 i > (1 + r i+1 )2 q 2 i = q2 i+1 is satisfied by (25). By Propositions 1 and 2, it is shown that the faster the order of move of the firm is, the greater the output and the profit of the firm are, regardless of demand structure. As a corollary 13

to confirm a well-known fact, when the demand function is linear, P =0,r i = 1 2 holds by (3), (11), (18), and (23). Therefore, q i+1 = 1 2 q i and π i+1 = 1 2 π i hold. 3 Examination on whether or not a merger is profitable In this section, we examine whether or not a merger is profitable under the HSM. We denote the output of firm i and the total output under the n-hsm by q i (n) and Q(n) = n i=1 q i(n), respectively. Comparing the total output of the n-hierarchy with that of the n 1-hierarchy, the following proposition can be derived. Proposition 3. (i) The monopoly output is always less than the total output of any n-hierarchy and it is always greater than a final firm s output of any n-hierarchy. That is, Q(1) <Q(n) and q 1 (1) >q n (n) n 2. (ii) If and only if the total output of the n-hierarchy is always greater than that of the (n 1)- hierarchy, the output of the final firm is always greater under the n-hierarchy than under the (n +1)-hierarchy. That is, Q(n) <Q(n +1) q n (n) >q n+1 (n +1). Proof. Rewriting the f.o.c. of firm i, (25), with regard to the numbers of hierarchies, n, the following equation is obtained: n P (Q(n)) + P (Q(n)) (1 + r j (n))q i(n) c =0. (30) j=i+1 (i) Q(1) and Q(n) n 2 satisfy the following equations. Note that when n =1,Q(1) q 1 (1) is the monopoly output. P (Q(1)) + P (Q(1))Q(1) c =0, (31) 14

P (Q(n)) + P (Q(n))q n (n) c =0. (32) By (32), it is satisfied that P (Q(n)) + P (Q(n))Q(n) c<0; Q(n) n i=1 q i(n) =q 1 (n) + + q n (n) >q n (n). As 2P + P q i < 0 q i is satisfied by the s.o.c., Q(1) <Q(n) n 2 is immediately satisfied. By the assumption that the marginal revenue is downward-sloping, MR(q i ) Q i P(Q)+P (Q)q i Q i = P (Q) +P (Q)q i < 0 q i, P (q 1 (1)) + P (q 1 (1))q 1 (1) c =0> P (Q(n)) + P (Q(n))q 1 (1) c is satisfied by (31). In order to satisfy (32), q 1 (1) >q n (n) must be satisfied. (ii) From (30), the outputs of the final firm n in a n-hierarchy and that of firm n + 1 in a (n + 1)-hierarchy satisfy the following equations respectively. P (Q(n)) + P (Q(n))q n (n) c =0, (33) P (Q(n + 1)) + P (Q(n + 1))q n+1 (n +1) c =0. (34) First, we show that if Q(n) <Q(n + 1), then q n (n) >q n+1 (n + 1). Under the downward-sloping marginal revenue, P (Q)+P (Q)q i < 0 q i,ifq(n) <Q(n + 1), P (Q(n))+P (Q(n))q n (n) c = 0 >P(Q(n + 1)) + P (Q(n + 1))q n (n) c is satisfied from (33) by the assumption, P (Q) + P (Q)q i < 0 q i. In order to satisfy (34), q n (n) >q n+1 (n + 1) must be satisfied by the same logic as part (i). Second, we show that if q n (n) >q n+1 (n + 1), then Q(n) <Q(n + 1). By (33) and P < 0, P (Q(n)) + P (Q(n))q n (n) c =0<P(Q(n)) + P (Q(n))q n+1 (n +1) c is satisfied, if q n (n) >q n+1 (n + 1). In order to satisfy (34), Q(n) <Q(n + 1) must be satisfied under the assumption, P (Q)+P (Q)q i < 0 q i. Thus, Q(n) <Q(n +1) q n (n) >q n+1 (n + 1). 9 9 As another procedure of proof, consider the comparative statics with regard to n. Totally differentiating (33) with regard to n (or more exactly, solving the difference equation with regard to n), we obtain the following equation: (P + P q n(n)) dq(n) dn + P dqn(n) dn = 0 dqn(n) dn = P +P q n(n) dq(n) P dn (or more ex- 15

Part (i) in Proposition 3 implies that the monopoly output is less than the total output under multi-stage Stackelberg quantity competition and it is greater than that of the Stackelberg follower. Part (ii) implies that if and only if the total output of n-hierarchical Stackelberg model exceeds that of (n + 1)-HSM, the final firm of n-hsm is less than that of (n + 1)-HSM. Note that Proposition 3 does not imply that Q(n) <Q(n + 1) is satisfied. Whether or not Q(n) <Q(n + 1) is satisfied depends on the details of demand structure and it is indeterminate under general demand structure. Therefore, we cannot compare Q(n) with Q(n + 1) without further presumption. 10 From now on, assuming Q(n) <Q(n +1) n, we proceed to examine the total profits of firms. If Q(n) <Q(n +1) n, the price in the equilibrium is always higher under n-hsm than that under (n + 1)-HSM by P < 0, that is, P (Q(n)) >P(Q(n + 1)) n. We denote firm i s profit and the total profits under the n-hsm by π i (n) and Π(n) n i=1 π i(n), respectively. actly, (P + P q n(n)) ΔQ(n) Δn + P Δqn(n) Δn = 0 Δqn(n) Δn = P +P q n(n) P ΔQ(n) ). Because of P +P q n(n) < 0, Δn P ΔQ(n) Δn > 0 Δqn(n). When Δn =1,ΔQ(n) =Q(n +1) Q(n) > 0 Δqn(n) =qn+1(n +1) qn(n) < 0is Δn satisfied. 10 The proof by which Q(n) <Q(n + 1) is satisfied cannot be made by applying the mathematical induction: It must prove that (i) Q(1) <Q(2) and q 1(1) >q 2(2) when n = 1; (ii) if Q(k) <Q(k + 1) and q k (k) >q k+1 (k +1) when n = k, it is satisfied that Q(k +1)<Q(k + 2) and q k+1 (k +1)>q k+2 (k + 2) when n = k +1. The reason why we cannot apply the mathematical induction is as follows: The equation of the first-order conditions, (30), which includes (33) and (34) are not recurrence formulae with regard to the number of hierarchies, n. Therefore, there is no recursive equation necessary to use the mathematical induction. In order to complete the proof, we must compare two different simultaneous equation systems whose number of equations are differently n and n + 1 under n-hsm and (n + 1)-HSM. However, the comparison between two different simultaneous equation systems is too difficult. We guess that this is the reason because Q(n) < Q(n + 1) cannot be shown. Moreover, we could not prove Q(n) <Q(n + 1) by using reduction to absurdity. 16

Comparing the total profits under the n-hsm with those under the (n + 1)-HSM, the following proposition can be derived. Proposition 4. Suppose that Q(n) < Q(n +1) n. (i) The total profit of the n-hierarchy is always greater than that of the (n +1)-hierarchy. That is, Π(n) > Π(n +1) n. (ii) The profit of the final firm of the n-hierarchy is always greater than that of the (n +1)- hierarchy. That is, π n (n) >π n+1 (n +1) n. Proof. (i) Since Π(n) n i=1 π i(n) =(P (Q(n)) c)q(n), arg max n Π(n) =(P (Q(n)) c)q(n) = 1, because Q(1) is the monopoly output. That is, the f.o.c., P (Q(1)) + P (Q(1))Q(1) c =0, is satisfied. Since the s.o.c. 2P + P Q<0, is satisfied by assumption, the larger the total output Q grows, the smaller the total profit Π decreases. Therefore, if Q(n) < Q(n + 1), then Π(Q(n)) > Π(Q(n + 1)) is satisfied. (ii) if Q(n) <Q(n + 1), then P (Q(n)) >P(Q(n + 1)). From part (ii) in Proposition 3, q n (n) > q n+1 (n + 1) is also satisfied. Since the output of the final firm is π n (n) (P (Q(n)) c)q n (n), π n (n) >π n+1 (n + 1) immediately follows. Part (i) in Proposition 4 implies that if the total output is larger under n-hsm than that under (n + 1)-HSM, the total profits is also larger under n-hsm than that under (n + 1)-HSM, even if the equilibrium price decreases, P (Q(n)) > P(Q(n + 1)). The reason is because the increase of total output means more intensified competition under the HSM and ends in the decline in the whole industrial profit. See Figure 1 and Figure 2. By rewriting Π(Q(n)) > Π(Q(n + 1)), the following equation is obtained: If Q(n) <Q(n +1) n, then 17

P P(Q) MR i P(Q(1)) P(Q(2)) P(Q(3)) c Π(1) > Π(2) > Π(3)... c 0 Q Q(1) Q(2) Q(3)... Figure 1: total outputs and total profits under the demand curve If Q(n) <Q(n + 1), then P (Q(n)) >P(Q(n + 1)) and Π(n) > Π(n + 1). 0 Π Π(1) Π(2) Π(3) π 1 (1){ { π 2 (2) π { 3 (3){ π 1 (2) π 2 (3){ { π 1 (3) Q(1) < Q(2) < Q(3)... Π(n) Q Figure 2: total profit function with regard to total output If Q(n) <Q(n + 1), then Π(n) > Π(n + 1) and π n(n) >π n+1(n + 1). 18

π 1 (1) >π 1 (2) + π 2 (2) >π 1 (3) + π 2 (3) + π 3 (3) >π 1 (4) + π 2 (4) + π 3 (4) + π 4 (4) >. (35) Furthermore, part (ii) in Proposition 4 implies that the final firm acquires less profit, as the number of hierarchies is larger. The reason is that as total output increases, the price becomes reduced and the residual demand of the final firm under HSM also becomes smaller. By rewriting π n (n) >π n+1 (n + 1), the following equation is obtained: If Q(n) <Q(n +1) n, then π 1 (1) >π 2 (2) >π 3 (3) >π 4 (4) >. (36) However, it is worth noting that Proposition 4 does not mention any other relationships among firms profits. For example, we cannot say that π i (n) >π i (n+1) i <n,evenifq(n) <Q(n+1) from Proposition 4. Now we proceed to examine whether or not a merger is profitable. Suppose that a merged firm produces in firm i s order of move after the merger. If the profit of the merged firm is greater than the sum of profits of the two adjoining firms before the merger, it is better for two firms to choose to merge each other. In other words, if the inequality, π i (n 1) >π i (n)+π i+1 (n), is satisfied, mergers by adjoining firms are always profitable regardless of the form of demand function. See Figure 3. In order to compare π i (n 1) with π i (n) +π i+1 (n), applying (25) and (26), we obtain the following equations: π i (n)+π i+1 (n) = P (Q(n)){ = P (Q(n)) n j=i+1 n j=i+1 π i (n 1) = P (Q(n 1)) (1 + r j (n))q2 i (n)+ n j=i+2 (1 + r j (n))q2 i+1 (n)} (1 + r j (n))(2 + r i+1 (n))q2 i (n). (37) n 1 j=i+1 19 (1 + r j(n 1))q 2 i (n 1). (38)

before merger i = 1 π 1 (n) i = 2 π 2 (n) after merger i = 1 π 1 (n 1) i = 2 π 2 (n 1) i i + 1 i = n n-hierarchy } π i+1 (n) π i (n) + π n (n) i π i (n 1) i = n 1 π n 1 (n 1) (n 1)-hierarchy Figure 3: firm s profit before and after merger If π i(n 1) >π i(n)+π i+1(n), the adjoining merger is profitable. By using the above two equations, (37) and (38), and adapting the result of Proposition 4, can we compare π i (n 1) with π i (n)+π i+1 (n)? Unfortunately, we cannot make any comparison between the sum of profits of two adjoining firms before merger and firm s profit after merger under general demand structure, without further detailed assumptions. The reason why this comparison cannot be made is because the sizes of slopes of reaction functions, r i (n), and also the output sizes of firm i in the n-hierarchy, q i (n), cannot be determined explicitly under the general demand function. As a result, any explicit result on whether or not a merger is profitable cannot be obtained. At a first glance, this comparison seems to be easy to calculate and such result that mergers are profitable seems to be satisfied. However, it is necessary to solve a very complicated calculation and it is too hard to present the calculating result in practice. If Q(n) <Q(n +1) n, it seems to be satisfied that π i (n 1) >π i (n)+π i+1 (n) with regard to any firms profits, such that 20

that is concluded in Proposition 4. In reality, although only π 1 (1) >π 1 (2) + π 2 (2) is necessarily satisfied, any other relationships, for example, π 1 (2) >π 1 (3) + π 2 (3) and π 2 (2) >π 2 (3) + π 3 (3), are not necessarily satisfied such that that is shown in Figure 2. As a result, whether or not a merger is profitable, π i (n 1) >π i (n) +π i+1 (n), cannot be shown under general demand structure. In this section, we could not make a comparison and present a fruitful result on whether or not a merger is profitable in a HSM in the end, despite our best endeavors. Therefore, we specify the functional form of demand in the following section. By this specification, we attempt to answer the question on whether or not any merger is certainly profitable regardless of the curvature of demand function explicitly. 4 Specification of the demand function In the former section, we could not present any explicit results with regard to whether or not a merger is profitable under general demand structure. In this section, we specify the functional form of demand, although this specification of function is accompanied with some loss of generality, and present the main result that any merger is profitable in a HSM. Suppose that the demand function is given by Q(P )=1 P α,α>0. 11 The inverse demand function is denoted by P (Q) =(1 Q) 1 α. The demand curve is always downward-sloping and includes to be convex (0 <α<1) or concave (α >1). If α = 1, the demand function is linear, P =1 Q. It is assumed that the constant marginal cost is normalized as zero, c = 0, for analytical simplification. See Figure 4 with regard to the form of the demand functions. 11 By a change of units, we can always reduce a demand function of the form Q = a bp α,a > 0,b > 0 to the form of Q =1 P α, so that our demand specification is a generalization of linear demand. 21

P 1 0.8 α = 2 0.6 P(Q) = (1 Q) 1/α 0.4 α = 1 0.2 0 α = 1/2 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Q Figure 4: demand function, P (Q) =(1 Q) 1 α When α = 1, 1, and 2, the demand curve is convex, linear, and concave respectively. 2 Firm i s output in the equilibrium can be determined as the solution to max qi P (q i + Q i )q i ; Q i i 1 j=1 q j,i=1, 2,,n. When i = n, q n = r n (Q n )= α(1 Q n) 1+α is obtained by solving the f.o.c. of the final firm, (1). Inducing backward, when i = n 1, q n 1 = r n 1 (Q (n 1) )= α(1 Q (n 1)) 1+α is obtained by solving the f.o.c. of the penultimate firm, (8). 12 Further, when i = n 2, q n 2 = r n 2 (Q (n 2) )= α(1 Q (n 2) ) 1+α is obtained by solving the f.o.c. of the antepenultimate firm, (16). 13 12 Substituting 1+r n = 1 1+α into (8) and arranging it, P +P (1+r n)q n 1 =(1 Q) 1 α 1 α (1 Q) 1 α 1 (1+r n)q n 1 = 0 1 α (1 Q) 1 1 1+α qn 1 = 1 is obtained. Since 1 Q =1 qn qn 1 Q (n 1) = 1 q n 1 Q (n 1) 1+α is obtained by substituting q n = α(1 Q n) 1+α, substituting (1 Q) 1 into the above equation, we obtain q n 1 = r n 1(Q (n 1) )= α(1 Q (n 1) ) 1+α. 13 Substituting 1 + r n =1+r n 1 = 1 1+α into (16) and arranging it, P + P (1 + r n)(1 + r n 1)q n 2 =(1 Q) 1 α 1 α (1 Q) 1 α 1 (1 + r n)(1 + r n 1)q n 2 =0 1 α (1 Q) 1 ( 1 1+α )2 q n 2 = 1 is obtained. Since 1 Q = 1 q n q n 1 q n 2 Q (n 2) =1 α(1 Q n) 1+α α(1 Q (n 1) ) 1+α q n 2 Q (n 2) = 1 q n 2 Q (n 2) (1+α) 2 is obtained 22

Likewise, by calculating the f.o.c. of firm i, (21), the reaction function of firm i is obtained as follows: q i = r i (Q i )= α(1 Q i) i 1 ; Q i q j. (39) 1+α j=1 Q i is the output produced by all preceding firms. Solving (39) yields q i = α, i =1,,n. (40) (1 + α) i so that Q = n i=1 q i =1 (1+α) n by the sum of finite geometric progression. The Stackelberg equilibrium price is P (Q) = (1 + α) n α. (41) Combining (41) with (40) yields firm i s profit as π i (n) =P (Q) q i = α(1 + α) n α i, i =1,,n. (42) For the linear demand case α = 1, the equilibrium price is 2 n and output combination, (q 1 (n),q 2 (n),,q i (n),,q n (n)), are (1/2, 1/4,, 2 i,, 2 n ). Note that q i+1 (n) = 1 2 q i(n). Thus, under linear demand, each firm earns half the profit of its immediate predecessor, that is, π i+1 (n) = 1 2 π i(n). 4.1 Any merger is profitable We examine whether or not mergers between firms are profitable under the above specification of demand curve in the HSM. Suppose that when firm i and j, i < j merge in the n-hierarchy, the merged firm produces in firm i s order of move after merger in the (n 1)-hierarchy. by substituting q n = α(1 Q n) 1+α and q n 1 = α(1 Q (n 1) ) 1+α, substituting (1 Q) 1 into the above equation, we obtain q n 2 = r n 2(Q (n 2) )= α(1 Q (n 2) ) 1+α. 23

We compare the sum of firms profits before merger with the profit of the merged firm after merger. As the profits of firm i and j before merger are respectively π i (n) =α(1 + α) n α i and π j (n) =α(1+α) n α j, the joint profit of the pre-merged firms is π i (n)+π j (n) =α(1+α) n α i + α(1 + α) n α j = α(1 + α) n α ((1 + α) i +(1+α) j )=α(1 + α) n α (1 + α) j ((1 + α) i+j + 1). As the number of firms decreases by mergers, the post-merged firm corresponds to firm i in the (n 1)-hierarchy. The profit of the post-merged firm is π i (n 1) = α(1 + α) n 1 α i. We obtain the following proposition by tedious calculation. Proposition 5. Any merger in a HSM is profitable, independent of the curvature of the demand curve. That is, π i (n 1) >π i (n)+π j (n). (43) Proof. π i (n)+π j (n) <π i (n 1) α(1 + α) n α ((1 + α) i +(1+α) j ) <α(1 + α) n 1 α i (1 + α) i +(1+α) j < (1 + α) 1 α i 1 < (1 + α) 1 α (1 + α) i j. We prove that 1 < (1 + α) 1 α (1 + α) i j. When j = i +1,(1+α) i j,i<jis the maximum. Thus, it is sufficient to prove that 1 < (1 + α) 1 α (1 + α) 1, because (1 + α) 1 > (1 + α) i j,i<j i +1. The following equivalence is satisfied: 1 < (1+α) 1 α (1+α) 1 2+α 1+α < (1+α) 1 α 2+α< (1 + α) 1 α +1 ln(2 + α) < 1+α α ln(1 + α). Let us define β 1 α > 0(1 β = α). We aim to prove that the inequality, ln(2+α) < 1+α α ln(1+ α) ln(2+ 1 β ) < (1+β)ln(1+1 β ), is satisfied. It is defined that f(β) (1+β) ln(1+ 1 β ) ln(2+ 1 β ). If f(β) > 0 is satisfied, then 1 < (1 + α) 1 α (1 + α) 1 is satisfied. Since f(β) =ln (1+β)1+β =(1+β) ln(1 + β) β ln β ln(1 + 2β), the limit as β approaches 0 β β (1+2β) is lim β 0 f(β) =1 0 lim β 0 (β ln β) 0 = 0, because lim β 0 (β ln β) = lim β 0 (ln β β ) = ln 0 0 = ln 1 = 0. Note that β approaches 0 if and only if α approaches +. The limit as β approaches 24

+ is lim β + f(β) = lim β + ln( 1+β β )β ( 1+β 1+2β ) = lim β + ln(1 + 1 β )β lim β + ln 1+β 1+2β = ln(exp) ln 2 = 1 ln 2 = 0.30685 > 0. Note that β approaches + if and only if α approaches 0. By tedious calculation, f (β) = ln(1 + β) ln β 2 1+2β and f (β) = 1 β(1+β)(1+2β) 2 < 0 are satisfied. As lim β 0 f (β) =+ and lim β + f (β) = 0, when β>0, it is always satisfied that f (β) > 0. See Figure 5. Therefore, f(β) > 0 and 1 < (1 + α) 1 α (1 + α) 1 are satisfied. As a result, π i (n 1) >π i (n)+π j (n). f (β) 0.3 0.28 0.26 0.24 0.22 0.2 0.18 0.16 β 0 2 4 6 8 10 Figure 5: f(β) ln (1+β)1+β β β (1+2β) Proposition 5 implies that any merger in a HSM is profitable, regardless of the curvature of the demand curve. Although the demand function is specified, the result is applied to broad classes of demand functions including linear demand. Thus, we show that although the intuition that mergers are profitable in the HSM requires some conditions with loss of generality, this intuition is true under broad classes of demand functions. 25

5 Discussion This paper attempted to show that mergers always yield profits in a HSM, regardless of forms of demand function. Under the general demand function, general results on whether or not mergers are profitable has not been obtained, although such result that any merger is profitable has been commonly recognized under the linear demand function. The reason why mergers are profitable under the linear demand in the HSM is as follows: In the linear Stackelberg model, each firm behaves as the monopolist that takes over the residual demand from the firms whose orders of move are faster. Therefore, the output of each firm is independent of the number of successor firms in the HSM. As merger decreases the number of firms and increases the price, the profit of a merged firm necessarily exceeds the sum of the profits of the pre-merged firms. Unfortunately, a significant result could not be obtained under general demand function, with regard to whether or not any merger is profitable, although we would expect this result to be satisfied. Instead, we showed that any merger is profitable, regardless of any curvature of demand under a specified demand structure. This result supports the intuition that any merger is profitable in a HSM, although the result is accompanied with some loss of generality on the functional form. Moreover, our result contrasts with that of Cournot competition that is primarily shown by Salant, Switzer, and Reynolds (1983), where merger is often not profitable. In the HSM, merger always yields profits. 26

Acknowledgements I am grateful to Yasuhiro Takarada for helpful comments and suggestions. This study was partially supported by Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research (No.16730095) from JSPS and MEXT of the Japanese Government. The usual disclaimer applies. References [1] Anderson, S.P., Engers, M. 1992. Stackelberg versus Cournot oligopoly equilibrium. International Journal of Industrial Organization 10, 127-135. [2] Boyer, M., Moreaux, M. 1986. Perfect competition as the limit of a hierarchical market structure. Economics Letters 22, 115-118. [3] Daughety, A.F. 1990. Beneficial concentration. American Economic Review 80, 1231-1237. [4] Deneckere, R., Davidson, C. 1985. Incentives to form coalitions with Bertrand competition. Rand Journal of Economics 16, 473-486. [5] Farrell, J., Shapiro, C. 1990. Horizontal mergers: an equilibrium analysis. American Economic Review 80, 107-126. [6] Huck, S., Konrad, K.A., Müller, W. 2001. Big fish eat small fish: on merger in Stackelberg markets. Economics Letters 73, 213-217. [7] Kwoka, J.E. 1989. The private profitability of horizontal mergers with non-cournot and maverick behavior. International Journal of Industrial Organization 7, 403-411. [8] Perry, M.K., Porter, R.H. 1985. Oligopoly and the investment for horizontal merger. American Economic Review 75, 219-227. 27

[9] Salant, S.W., Switzer, S., Reynolds, R.J. 1983. Losses from horizontal merger: the effects of an exogenous change in industry structure on Cournot-Nash equilibrium. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98, 185-199. [10] Vives, X. 1988. Sequential entry, industrial structure, and welfare. European Economic Review 32, 1671-1687. [11] Vives, X. 1999. Oligopoly Pricing, MIT Press: Massachusetts. 28