Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

Similar documents
Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

A Dynamic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

New Keynesian Macroeconomics

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

The New Keynesian Model

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

The Zero Lower Bound

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Y t = log (employment t )

Discussion Global Dynamics at the Zero Lower Bound

Problem 1 (30 points)

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Nonlinearity. Exploring this idea and what to do about it requires solving a non linear model.

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Queen s University Department of Economics Instructor: Kevin Andrew

A Discussion of Arouba, Cuba-Borda and Schorfheide: Macroeconomic Dynamics Near the ZLB: A Tale of Two Countries"

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

Macroeconomics Theory II

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Gali (2008), Chapter 3

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Bayesian Estimation of DSGE Models: Lessons from Second-order Approximations

The Return of the Wage Phillips Curve

THE ZERO LOWER BOUND: FREQUENCY, DURATION,

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Assessing the Fed s Performance through the Effect of Technology Shocks: New Evidence

Two Models of Macroeconomic Equilibrium

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy. Jordi Galí and Tommaso Monacelli. March 2005

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics Notes

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

The Analytics of New Keynesian Phillips Curves. Alfred Maußner

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Aspects of Stickiness in Understanding Inflation

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Forward Guidance without Common Knowledge

Monetary Policy Design in the Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. October 2015

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes.

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound?

Deep Habits, Nominal Rigidities and Interest Rate Rules

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Seoul National University Mini-Course: Monetary & Fiscal Policy Interactions II

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

The Smets-Wouters Model

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Eco 200, part 3, Fall 2004 Lars Svensson 12/6/04. Liquidity traps, the zero lower bound for interest rates, and deflation

Optimal Monetary Policy

Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Taylor-Rule Exit Policies for the Zero Lower Bound

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Wage and price setting. Slides for 26. August 2003 lecture

Lecture 9: Stabilization policy with rational expecations; Limits to stabilization policy; closed economy case.

Fiscal Multipliers with Time-inconsistent Preferences

Lecture 6, January 7 and 15: Sticky Wages and Prices (Galí, Chapter 6)

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

Inflation Stabilization and Welfare: The Case of a Distorted Steady State

New Keynesian DSGE Models: Building Blocks

Learning and Global Dynamics

Aggregate Supply. A Nonvertical AS Curve. implications for unemployment, rms pricing behavior, the real wage and the markup

The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy

Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment. Abstract

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Open Market Operations and Money Supply. at Zero Nominal Interest Rates

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Incorporating a Simple DMP Version of the Labor Market and Rediscovering the Shimer Puzzle

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Analysis of the Government Expenditure Multiplier under Zero Lower Bound: the Role of Public Investment 1

Stabilization policy with rational expectations. IAM ch 21.

Transcription:

Monetary Economics Problem Set #4 Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions This problem set is marked out of 100 points. The weight given to each part is indicated below. Please contact me asap if you have any questions. 1. Government purchases in the new Keynesian model. Consider a basic new Keynesian model with the following (log-linearised) equilibrium conditions: for consumption, a dynamic Euler equation for labor supply the production function for firms c t = 1 σ (i t E t [π t+1 ] ρ) + E t [c t+1 ] w t p t = σc t + ϕn t y t = n t If prices were fully flexible, firms would set a constant markup over marginal cost. With sticky prices, there is a new Keynesian Phillips curve in terms of the output gap π t = βe t [π t+1 ] + ỹ t The government purchases a fraction τ t of output each period with τ t varying exogenously. (a) Derive a log-linear version of the goods market clearing equation of the form y t = c t + g t where g t log(1 τ t ). (5 points) (b) Show that natural output is proportional to government purchases, yt n = Γg t, and give an explicit formula for the coefficient Γ. Does a fiscal expansion increase or decrease natural output when prices are fully flexible? By how much? Explain. (10 points) Now assume that monetary policy is set according to the simple interest rate rule i t = ρ + φ π π t + φ y ỹ t and that government purchases g t follow an AR(1) process with persistence 0 ρ g < 1. (c) Show that the output gap ỹ t satisfies a dynamic IS curve of the form ỹ t = 1 σ (i t E t [π t+1 ] r n t ) + E t [ỹ t+1 ] and derive a formula for the natural real rate rt n in terms of g t. (5 points) (d) Use the method of undetermined coefficients to solve for the response of the key endogenous variables output, natural output, employment, inflation, interest rates to an exogenous increase in government purchases g t. Give economic intuition for your answers. (20 points)

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 2 (e) Explain how the response of output to government purchases depends on the monetary policy coefficient φ π. Does a higher φ π increase or decrease the impact effect of government purchases on output? Similarly, explain how the response of output to government purchases depends on the AR(1) persistence ρ g. Does a more persistent process increase or decrease the impact effect of government purchases on output? Give economic intuition for your answers. (10 points) Solutions: (a) Since the government purchases a fraction τ t of output, we have government purchases G t = τ t Y t and the goods market clearing condition in raw levels is so Taking logs of both sides Y t = C t + G t (1 τ t )Y t = C t y t = c t + g t where, as suggested, g t log(1 τ t ) and as usual y t log Y t, c t log C t. (b) With fully flexible prices each period, a firm sets its price as a constant markup over nominal marginal cost P t = ε ε 1 W t or in logs p t = µ + w t where µ log(ε/(ε 1)) > 0 is the log markup. So the natural real wage (for want of a better term) is a constant w t p t = µ and so using the household s labor supply condition and the production function for firms, natural output yt n satisfies Solving for y n t then gives µ = w t p t = σc t + ϕn t = σ(y n t g t ) + ϕy n t = (σ + ϕ)y n t σg t When prices are fully flexible, the multiplier is yt n = 1 σ + ϕ µ + σ σ + ϕ g t (1) Γ yn t g t = σ σ + ϕ

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 3 A fiscal expansion (an increase in g t ) increases the natural level of output. Why? Not for Keynesian demand-side reasons, that s for sure! The channel here is purely supply-side: an increase in g t causes consumption c t to fall which is a negative wealth effect on labor supply, i.e., households feel poorer (have higher marginal utility of consumption) and so work more at any given wage (an outward shift in the labor supply curve). That higher labor supply translates into higher natural output. (c) The output gap is defined by ỹ t y t y n t and so using the resource constraint from part (a) and the expression for natural output from part (b) we have ỹ t = c t + g t yt n = c t + g t + 1 σ + ϕ µ σ σ + ϕ g t Rearrange this to express consumption in terms of the output gap and government purchases c t = ỹ t 1 ( ) σ σ + ϕ µ + σ + ϕ 1 g t = ỹ t 1 σ + ϕ µ ϕ σ + ϕ g t We now want to plug this into the dynamic Euler equation given in the problem c t = 1 σ (i t E t [π t+1 ] ρ) + E t [c t+1 ] Note that E t [c t+1 ] = E t [ ỹ t+1 1 σ + ϕ µ = E t [ỹ t+1 ] 1 σ + ϕ µ ϕ ] σ + ϕ g t+1 ϕ σ + ϕ E t[g t+1 ] and since g t follows and AR(1) with persistence ρ g we have so that E t [g t+1 ] = ρ g g t E t [c t+1 ] = E t [ỹ t+1 ] 1 σ + ϕ µ ϕ σ + ϕ ρ gg t Plugging in for c t and E t [c t+1 ] in the Euler equation then gives ỹ t 1 σ + ϕ µ ϕ σ + ϕ g t = 1 σ (i t E t [π t+1 ] ρ) + E t [ỹ t+1 ] 1 σ + ϕ µ Cancelling common terms and collecting things together ỹ t = 1 σ (i t E t [π t+1 ] ρ) + E t [ỹ t+1 ] + ϕ σ + ϕ ρ gg t ϕ σ + ϕ (1 ρ g)g t (2) We can render this expression consistent with the dynamic IS curve given in the problem if we define the natural real rate rt n appropriately. In particular, define r n t = ρ + σ ϕ σ + ϕ (1 ρ g)g t ρ + ϕ g g t (3)

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 4 so that the natural real rate is increasing in government purchases g t. Then with this definition of the natural real rate, from equation (2) we have or ỹ t = 1 σ (i t E t [π t+1 ] ρ) + E t [ỹ t+1 ] + rn t ρ σ ỹ t = 1 σ (i t E t [π t+1 ] r n t ) + E t [ỹ t+1 ] as required. (d) Given the policy rule i t = ρ + φ π π t + φ y ỹ t the nominal rate less the natural rate is i t r n t = φ π π t + φ y ỹ t ϕ g g t where ϕ g > 0 is the slope coefficient defined in (3) above. Plugging this into the dynamic IS curve we have the reduced system of equations that needs to be solved Now guess the linear functions so that ỹ t = 1 σ (φ ππ t + φ y ỹ t ϕ g g t E t [π t+1 ]) + E t [ỹ t+1 ] (4) π t = βe t [π t+1 ] + ỹ t (5) π t = ϕ πg g t ỹ t = ϕ yg g t E t [π t+1 ] = ϕ πg ρ g g t E t [ỹ t+1 ] = ϕ yg ρ g g t for some as-yet unknown coefficients that we need to solve for. Plugging these into the equations (4)-(5) and collecting terms gives [σ(1 ρ g ) + φ y ]ϕ yg + (φ π ρ g )ϕ πg = ϕ g (6) (1 βρ g )ϕ πg = ϕ yg (7) These are two equations to be solved for the two unknowns ϕ yg, ϕ πg. Solving, we get ϕ πg = ϕ yg = (1 βρ g )[σ(1 ρ g ) + φ y ] + (φ π ρ g ) ϕ g (8) (1 βρ g ) (1 βρ g )[σ(1 ρ g ) + φ y ] + (φ π ρ g ) ϕ g (9) If we impose the Taylor Principle φ π > 1 (i.e., the standard sufficient condition for a unique equilibrium, as discussed in class), then both of these coefficients are positive. Under this parameter assumption, then, an increase in government purchases g t increases both inflation π t and the output gap ỹ t. Since from equation (1) natural output yt n is

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 5 increasing in g t, output y t = ỹ t + yt n is also increasing in government purchases. Since from the production function y t = n t, labor n t is also increasing in g t. From the policy rule i t = ρ + φ π π t + φ y ỹ t and since both inflation and the output gap increase, so too does the nominal interest rate. (e) Since the denominators of (8) and (9) are both increasing in φ π, the response coefficients ϕ πg and ϕ yg are both decreasing in φ π. Moreover, since natural output does not depend on φ π, the response of output itself is the same as the response of the output gap. So the response of output is also decreasing in φ π. Intuitively, the more reactive the monetary authority is to inflation, the smaller is the effect of an increase in g t on the output gap and hence the smaller is the rise in actual inflation. In this sense, the effectiveness of fiscal policy depends crucially on the monetary reaction. The effects of ρ g are a little more complicated. In particular, ρ g also enters through the coefficient ϕ g on the natural real rate, as defined in (3). Plugging this is and tidying the expression up gives ϕ yg = σ(1 βρ g )(1 ρ g ) (1 Γ) (10) σ(1 βρ g )(1 ρ g ) + (1 βρ g )φ y + (φ π ρ g ) To see the main effects of ρ g intuitively, divide the numerator and denominator by σ(1 βρ g ) to write ϕ yg = 1 ρ g 1 ρ g + ψ (1 Γ), ψ 1 [ ] φ y + (φ π ρ g ) > 0 σ 1 βρ g where ψ > 0 since φ π > 1 (and 1 > ρ g ). Now first consider ρ g = 0, a completely transitory stimulus. Then we have 0 < ϕ yg ρg=0 = 1 + 1 σ 1 ](1 Γ) < 1 Γ [φ y + φ π and so the multiplier, which is given by the effect on output itself, rather than the output gap, is greater than Γ but less than one. Moreover, at the other extreme, consider ρ g = 1, a completely permanent stimulus (government purchases a random walk). Then we have ϕ yg ρg=1 = 0 + 1 σ 0 [ ](1 Γ) = 0 φ y + (φ 1 β π 1) in which case government purchases have zero effect on the output gap and hence the effect on output is simply Γ. In short, for ρ g = 0 we have a multiplier less than one but larger than Γ while for ρ g = 1 we have the lower multiplier Γ. Hence we expect the multiplier to be decreasing in ρ g. The more persistent is the increase in government purchases, the larger is the expected inflation response and hence (if the Taylor principle is satisfied), the more vigorous is the monetary response. For completeness, here is the calculation for general ρ g. Dividing the numerator and denominator in (10) by (1 βρ g )(1 ρ g ) we have ϕ yg = σ σ + 1 1 ρ g φ y + (φ π ρ g) (1 βρ g)(1 ρ g) (1 Γ)

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 6 Hence the response coefficient ϕ yg is decreasing in ρ g if and only if D(ρ g ) 1 (φ π ρ g ) φ y + 1 ρ g (1 βρ g )(1 ρ g ) is increasing in ρ g. Differentiating D(ρ g ) with respect to ρ g gives, after some simplifications, D 1 [ { }] (ρ g ) = φ (1 ρ g ) 2 y + (φ π ρ g )(1 + β 2βρ g ) (1 ρ g )(1 βρ g ) 1 βρ g which is certainly positive so long as the term in braces { } is. This term is quadratic in ρ g and can be rearranged to give the condition where Q(ρ g ) > 0 D (ρ g ) > 0 Q(ρ g ) βρ 2 g 2βφ π ρ + (1 + β)φ π 1 Now observe that Q(0) = (1 + β)φ π 1 > 0 (since φ π > 1) but Q(ρ g ) is decreasing in ρ g, so it may seem that for high enough ρ g we could get Q(ρ g ) < 0 which would be a pain. But in fact even at ρ g = 1 we have Q(1) = (1 β)(φ π 1) > 0 (again, since φ π > 1), so luckily we know that Q(ρ g ) > 0 for all ρ g [0, 1]. In turn this implies D (ρ g ) > 0 for all ρ g and so indeed, as conjectured, the response coefficient ϕ yg is decreasing in ρ g. 2. Multipliers, the ZLB, and the duration of fiscal stimulus. Consider a new Keynesian model with government purchases g t and shocks t to the interest rate facing households ỹ t = 1 σ (i t + t E t [π t+1 ] r n t ) + E t [ỹ t+1 ] π t = βe t [π t+1 ] + ỹ t Monetary policy is set according to an interest rate rule but also faces a zero lower bound i t = max[0, ρ + φ π π t + φ y ỹ t ] The natural real rate and natural output are given by r n t = ρ σ(1 Γ)E t [ g t+1 ], y n t = Γg t The interest spread shock t can take on two values L, H with H = 0 and L > 0. The economy starts in the L state. With probability α it stays in the L state. With probability 1 α it transitions to the H state. Once it enters the H ( normal ) state it stays there forever. Suppose that g H = 0. We are interested in calculating economic outcomes as a function of fiscal policy g L in the L ( crisis ) state. (a) To begin with, suppose that g L = 0. Solve for the equilibrium values of inflation, the output gap, and the nominal interest rate in the L state. (5 points) (b) Now explain how an increase in government purchases to some g L > 0 would affect inflation, expected inflation, output and the nominal and real interest rates in the L state. Explain how your answers depend on the size of the interest spread L. How large is the government purchases multiplier? Does this value depend on the the size of the fiscal stimulus? (15 points)

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 7 Now consider the possibility that government purchases g L persist at an elevated level after the crisis has abated. To be specific, imagine that there are three states, L, S, H. The economy starts in the L state with L > 0. Suppose the initial interest spread L is sufficiently high that the ZLB is binding in the L state. With probability α the economy transitions to the S state. In the S ( transitional ) state, the crisis is over S = H = 0. In the S state, with probability λ the fiscal stimulus continues with government purchases g S = g L > 0. With probability 1 λ the fiscal stimulus ends with g S = g H = 0. (c) Let π S, ỹ S, i S denote the equilibrium values of inflation, the output gap and the nominal interest rate in the S state. Following the same logic as in part (a), solve for these equilibrium values as a function of the size of the fiscal stimulus g L > 0. Explain how your answers depend on whether the fiscal stimulus continues g S = g L, or not g S = g H. (15 points) (d) Using your results from part (c), now solve for the equilibrium values of inflation, the output gap and the nominal interest rate in the initial L state given that with probability λ the fiscal stimulus continues after the crisis has abated. How does the government purchases multiplier compare to the one you found in part (b)? How does the multiplier vary with the probability of the stimulus continuing? Explain. (15 points) [Hint: this question is based on Woodford s article Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics. 3(1): 1 35, especially Section IV.B] Solutions: (a) From the new Keynesian Phillips curve in the low state we have and the natural rate in the low state is π L = 1 αβ ỹl r n L = ρ + σ(1 Γ)(1 α)ĝ L Plugging these into the IS curve in the low state we have (1 α)ỹ L = 1 σ (r L i L ) + where r L ρ L. So for a given i L the output gap is α σ(1 αβ)ỹl + (1 Γ)(1 α)ĝ L ỹ L = ϑ r (r L i L ) + ϑ g ĝ L with coefficients and ϑ g ϑ r (1 αβ) σ(1 α)(1 αβ) α > 0 σ(1 α)(1 αβ) (1 Γ) > 1 Γ > 0 σ(1 α)(1 αβ) α

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 8 But the nominal interest rate i L is endogenous, given by the policy rule i L = max[0, ρ + φ π π L + φ y ỹ L ] [ ( ) ] = max 0, ρ + φ π 1 αβ + φ y ỹ L [ ( ) ] = max 0, ρ + φ π 1 αβ + φ y (ϑ r (r L i L ) + ϑ g ĝ L ) This is one nonlinear equation in one unknown, i L. Once we have solved for i L, we can then recover ỹ L and π L from the expressions above. Mathematically, we are solving a problem of the form x = f(x), f(x) max[0, b ax], x 0 given two constants a > 0 and b. If b > 0 then this equation has a unique solution x and that solution lies on the positive branch, x = b/(1 + a) > 0. But if b < 0 then there is a unique solution at x = 0. The size (and sign) of the intercept is determined by (i) the size of the shock, L and (ii) the size of the fiscal stimulus ĝ L. The ZLB will bind if either the shock is large enough and/or the fiscal stimulus is too small. (b) Specifically, suppose that ĝ L = 0. Then the ZLB binds if ( ) ρ + φ π 1 αβ + φ y ϑ r r L < 0 or equivalently, whenever (( r L < rl φ π Since r L = ρ L, this is also equivalent to ) ) 1 1 αβ + φ y ϑ r ρ < 0 L > L = ρ r L > 0 That is, the ZLB binds when the shock is large enough. Now if the ZLB binds (and continuing to assume ĝ L = 0) then i L = 0 and we have that the output gap is ỹ L = ϑ r r L with inflation π L = 1 αβ ϑ rr L A small increase in government purchases ĝ L would cause output to rise to ỹ L = ϑ r r L + ϑ g ĝ L with a corresponding increase in inflation (and expected inflation) so long as the ZLB continues to bind. In this case, the government purchases multiplier is dy L dĝ L = dỹ L dĝ L + dyn L dĝ L = ϑ g + Γ > 1 Γ + Γ > 1 If the increase in government purchases is large enough, however, the ZLB will cease to bind and the multiplier will fall back to Γ < 1. In short, output is a piecewise linear function of ĝ L with a slope that switches from above to below 1 at a critical threshold fiscal stimulus.

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 9 (c) The approach here follows the same steps as in part (a) above except that the transition probability α is replaced with λ and the interest spread in the transitional state is S = 0. In particular, from the new Keynesian Phillips curve in the transitional state we have π S = and the natural rate in the transitional state is 1 λβ ỹs r n S = ρ + σ(1 Γ)(1 λ)ĝ S Plugging these into the IS curve in the transitional state we then have (1 λ)ỹ S = 1 σ (ρ i S) + So for a given i S the output gap is λ σ(1 λβ)ỹs + (1 Γ)(1 α)ĝ S with coefficients and ϑ g,λ ϑ r,λ ỹ S = ϑ r,λ (ρ i S ) + ϑ g,λ ĝ S (1 λβ) σ(1 λ)(1 λβ) λ > 0 σ(1 λ)(1 λβ) (1 Γ) > 1 Γ > 0 σ(1 λ)(1 λβ) λ (i.e., the same as in part (a) with λ replacing α). Again, the nominal interest rate is found by solving i S = max[0, ρ + φ π π S + φ y ỹ S ] [ ( ) ] = max 0, ρ + φ π 1 λβ + φ y ỹ S = max [0, ρ + Ψ (ϑ r,λ (ρ i S ) + ϑ g,λ ĝ S )] where Ψ φ π + φ 1 λβ y > 0. Once we have solved for i S, we can then recover ỹ S and π S from the expressions above. Since the crisis is over, the intercept term is strictly positive, ρ + Ψ (ϑ r,λ ρ + ϑ g,λ ĝ S ) > 0 so the solution is on the positive branch where the ZLB is slack. Hence the solution for i S is given by i S = ρ + Ψϑ g,λ ĝ S 1 + Ψϑ r,λ Plugging this into the expressions above for the output gap and inflation ỹ S = ϑ g,λ 1 + Ψϑ r,λ ĝ S and π S = ϑ g,λ ĝ S 1 λβ 1 + Ψϑ r,λ

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 10 Hence, if in the transitional state the fiscal stimulus does not continue, i.e., if ĝ S = ĝ H = 0, then i S = ρ and so in this case ỹ S = 0 and π S = 0. In short, if the fiscal stimulus is over, then there is no difference between the transitional S state and the full end-of-crisis H state. But if the fiscal stimulus continues, i.e., if ĝ S = ĝ L > 0, then the interest rate is greater than ρ, there is a positive output gap ỹ S > 0 and positive inflation π S > 0 (and positive expected inflation). In short, with an on-going active fiscal stimulus and away from the ZLB, monetary policy responds by increasing interest rates. (d) (Sketch) We can now roll back to the crisis L period to see how the possibility of the fiscal stimulus continuing even after the crisis has abated affects the equilibrium in this earlier period. For example, we now have from the the new Keynesian Phillips curve in the L state π L = β[απ L + (1 α)π S ] + ỹ L so π L = β 1 αβ (1 α)π S + 1 αβ ỹl where π S is given from part (c) above. The natural rate is r n L = ρ σ(1 Γ)(1 α)(ĝ S ĝ L ) which either simply equals ρ if the fiscal stimulus continues in the S state or is the same as in part (a) if the fiscal stimulus shuts off in the S state. Likewise, from the IS curve we then have ỹ L = 1 σ (i L + L απ L (1 α)π S r n L) + αỹ L + (1 α)ỹ S where again π S and ỹ S are determined as in part (c) above. To solve the model, we then need to determine the interest rate i L from i L = max[0, ρ + φ π π L + φ y ỹ L ] It should be clear that if the fiscal stimulus does not continue, i.e., if ĝ S = ĝ H = 0, then everything reduces to being as in part (a) above. But if the fiscal stimulus does continue, so that i S > 0, ỹ S > 0 and π S > 0 then following the discussion in Woodford (pages 23 24) the size of the fiscal multiplier will be decreasing in the probability λ of the transitional state recurring (i.e., in the expected duration of the excess period of fiscal stimulus). Intuitively, this is because once inflation and the output gap increase in the transitional phase, monetary policy is off the ZLB and increases rates (via the interest rate rule coefficients φ π, φ y ), i.e., monetary policy chokes off some of the fiscal policy-induced rise in demand. The more aggressive this monetary policy offsetting response, the smaller (or even negative) the fiscal policy multiplier.