Heterogeneity. Krishna Pendakur. May 24, Krishna Pendakur () Heterogeneity May 24, / 21

Similar documents
Consumer Demand and the Cost of Living

Tricks With Hicks: The EASI Demand System

The Common-Scaling Social Cost-of-Living Index. Thomas F. Crossley and Krishna Pendakur

Unobserved Preference Heterogeneity in Demand Using Generalized Random Coefficients

Unobserved Preference Heterogeneity in Demand Using Generalized Random Coefficients

How Revealing is Revealed Preference?

Unobserved Preference Heterogeneity in Demand Using Generalized Random Coefficients

Consumer theory Topics in consumer theory. Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

Index-Number Tests and the Common-Scaling Social Cost-of-Living Index 1

Index-Number Tests and the Common-Scaling Social Cost-of-Living Index 1

Stochastic Demand and Revealed Preference

Welfare Comparisons, Economies of Scale and Indifference Scale in Time Use

Individual Heterogeneity and Average Welfare

Week 9: Topics in Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 2)

PRICES VERSUS PREFERENCES: TASTE CHANGE AND TOBACCO CONSUMPTION

Estimating Consumption Economies of Scale, Adult Equivalence Scales, and Household Bargaining Power

Chapter 1 Consumer Theory Part II

Consumption Peer Effects and Utility Needs in India

EASI made Easier. Krishna Pendakur. December Abstract

Identifying Sharing Rules in Collective Household Models

Microeconomics II Lecture 4. Marshallian and Hicksian demands for goods with an endowment (Labour supply)

Regressor Dimension Reduction with Economic Constraints: The Example of Demand Systems with Many Goods

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters

Identifying Sharing Rules in Collective Household Models

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 1 September Q1. Are the preferences described below transitive? Strictly monotonic? Convex?

Necessary Luxuries: A New Social Interactions Model, Applied to Keeping Up With the Joneses in India

Econ 5150: Applied Econometrics Empirical Demand Analysis. Sung Y. Park CUHK

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

Econometrics Lecture 10: Applied Demand Analysis

SEMIPARAMETRIC ESTIMATION AND CONSUMER DEMAND

THE SOCIAL COST-OF-LIVING: WELFARE FOUNDATIONS AND ESTIMATION

Conditions for the Existence of Control Functions in Nonseparable Simultaneous Equations Models 1

Keeping up with peers in India

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

from Indonesia September 13, 2010 Abstract This paper estimates equivalence scales and tests the empirical relevance of the price

Collective household welfare and intra-household inequality

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Economic Theory of Spatial Costs. of Living Indices with. Application to Thailand

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Poverty, Inequality and Growth: Empirical Issues

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

The New Palgrave: Separability

Section 1.5. Solution Sets of Linear Systems

Applications I: consumer theory

Semiparametric Estimation of Consumer Demand Systems in. Real Expenditure

Problem set 2 solutions Prof. Justin Marion Econ 100M Winter 2012

Thomas Demuynck. The homogeneous marginal utility of income assumption RM/15/013

Using Economic Contexts to Advance in Mathematics

WELFARE: THE SOCIAL- WELFARE FUNCTION

Notes on Consumer Theory

Revealed Preference Heterogeneity. (Job Market Paper)

Midterm Examination: Economics 210A October 2011

A time series plot: a variable Y t on the vertical axis is plotted against time on the horizontal axis

1.8 Aggregation Aggregation Across Goods

Econometric Analysis of Games 1

Nonparametric Welfare Analysis for Discrete Choice

Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics

STRUCTURE Of ECONOMICS A MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Sam Cosaert, Thomas Demuynck. Nonparametric welfare and demand analysis with unobserved individual heterogeneity RM/14/010

Individual Counterfactuals with Multidimensional Unobserved Heterogeneity

AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES

The General Neoclassical Trade Model

13 Endogeneity and Nonparametric IV

Incentives and Nutrition for Rotten Kids: Intrahousehold Food Allocation in the Philippines

VALUATION USING HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTION LECTURE PLAN 15: APRIL 14, 2011 Hunt Allcott

Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

The Identification of Fixed Costs from Consumer Behaviour*

EQUALITAS Working Paper No. 47. Informational Content of Equivalence Scales based on Minimum Needs Income. Andrew Grodner Rafael Salas

A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 14: Control Functions and Related Methods. Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008

Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO

Re-estimating Euler Equations

IDENTIFICATION OF MARGINAL EFFECTS IN NONSEPARABLE MODELS WITHOUT MONOTONICITY

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision:

ECON 4117/5111 Mathematical Economics Fall 2005

Estimating Semi-parametric Panel Multinomial Choice Models

Identification of Random Resource Shares in Collective Households Without Preference Similarity Restrictions

Professor: Alan G. Isaac These notes are very rough. Suggestions welcome. Samuelson (1938, p.71) introduced revealed preference theory hoping

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm Suggested Solutions 2/8/ (a) The equation of the indifference curve is given by,

Equivalent-Income Functions and Income-Dependent Equivalence Scales*

Demand Theory. Lecture IX and X Utility Maximization (Varian Ch. 7) Federico Trionfetti

Pareto Efficiency (also called Pareto Optimality)

Chapter 5: Preferences

Social Choice Theory. Felix Munoz-Garcia School of Economic Sciences Washington State University. EconS Advanced Microeconomics II

Identification and Estimation Using Heteroscedasticity Without Instruments: The Binary Endogenous Regressor Case

Stochastic Demand and Revealed Preference

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

Principles Underlying Evaluation Estimators

Introduction: structural econometrics. Jean-Marc Robin

Applied Econometrics (MSc.) Lecture 3 Instrumental Variables

x 1 1 and p 1 1 Two points if you just talk about monotonicity (u (c) > 0).

Sometimes the domains X and Z will be the same, so this might be written:

Control Functions in Nonseparable Simultaneous Equations Models 1

Textbook Producer Theory: a Behavioral Version

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem

Week 5 Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Ch.2)

Transcription:

Heterogeneity Krishna Pendakur May 24, 2015 Krishna Pendakur () Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 1 / 21

Introduction People are heterogeneous. Some heterogeneity is observed, some is not observed. Some heterogeneity affects cost, some affects preferences, some affects both. We need to account for heterogeneity when measuring inequality, poverty, the cost-of-living, etc. Equivalence scales, which measure the ratio of cost (functions) across household types, are venerable (Engel (1895), Sydenstricker and King (1921), Rothbarth (1943), Prais and Houthakker (1955), Barten (1964), Gorman (1976), Lewbel (1985). Equivalent income, equal to income scaled by the equivalence scale, gives the amount of money needed for a single individual to attain the same utility level as some reference type of individual. Comparing cost across people is comparing utility across people. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 2 / 21

Equivalence Scales p price vector, x expenditure, z characteristics vector, u utility, w budget-share vector. C (p, u, z) cost to attain utility u for person with characteristics z when facing prices p. V (p, x, z) indirect utility (inverse of cost over u). Define (p, u, z) = C (p, u, z)/c (p, u, z) as the equivalence scale relating costs for a person with characteristics z to a reference person with characteristics z. is not identified from behaviour: given a z-specific monotonic transformation φ (u, z), (p, φ (u, z), z) = C (p, u, z)/c (p, u, z) φ (u, z) affects the equivalence scale, but not behaviour: thus there are an infinite number of equivalence scale functions consistent with the same behaviour. φ (u, z) structures interpersonal comparisons of utility. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 3 / 21

What are characteristics? Could include characteristics of individuals, e.g., disability status. this clearly affects cost, but may also affect preferences. So, (p, u, z) should have both a level part (to hit cost regardless of prices) and a price response (to hit preferences). Could include characteristics of household, like size of household. the household doesn t have utility, just the individuals inside it. E.g., let z = n, the number of household members. C (p, u, n) then gives the amount of household expenditure needed to give each of the n members of the household a utility level of u. Embedded here is the assumption that each individual in the household gets the same utility level. More on this later. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 4 / 21

IB/ESE and Identification of Equivalence Scales Let (p, u, z) = E (p, z) which is independent of u. This restriction is called independent of base utility (IB) or equivalence-scale exact (ESE), and has been studied by Lewbel (1989), Blundell and Lewbel (1991), Blackorby and Donaldson (199), Pendakur (1999), Blundell, Duncan and Pendakur (1998) and Donaldson and Pendakur (2004, 2006). Given a z-specific monotonic transformation φ (u, z), (p, φ (u, z), z) = (p, u, z), so there are an infinite number of equivalence scale functions consistent with behaviour. But, Blackorby and Donaldson (1993) show that, given IB/ESE, only one of them is independent of utility. The functional form restriction solves the identification problem. Here, cost is related across z by C (p, u, z) = E (p, z)c (p, u, z) Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 5 / 21

Shape-Invariance Pendakur (1999) shows that, given IB/ESE, the budget-share vector-function w(p, x, z) satisfies w(p, x, z) = w (p, (ln x ln E (p, z)), z) + d(p, z) for any integrable w(p, x, z), where the vector-function d(p, z) = ln p ln E (p, a). Specify an indirect utility function for the reference type, e.g., QAI: w(p, x, z) = a + A ln p + b ln x + q ln x 2 exp (b ln p). where ln x = ln x ln p ( a + 1 2A ln p) Substitute the lower equation into the upper one, and estimate. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 6 / 21

Shape-Invariant Engel Curves An Engel curve is a budget share equation evaluated at a single price regime. Without price variation (ie, evaluated at some p), and evaluating over ln x, we have w(ln x, z) = w(ln x ln E (z), z) + d(z) where d(z) = ln p ln E (p, z). These Engel curves are shape-invariant, with the horizontal translation giving ln E. You don t even need to know what shape w(ln x, z) has over ln x. You can just draw pictures of w over ln x for different z, and find the closest translations. Blundell, Chen and Christensen (2007) do this. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 7 / 21

Operationalising Equivalence Scales ln E is the log of equivalence scale. By definition, if you give $x to a person with characteristics z, they have the same utility level as a reference person(with characteristics z) with $x/e. We therefore say that $x/e is the equivalent-expenditure of that person. Equivalent expenditures structure interpersonal comparisons of utility they make one person equivalent in a welfare sense to another person (with a different expenditure level). the equivalence in welfare terms derives from 2 things: 1) social welfare functions are anonymous, in that if two people have the same utility, they affect social welfare equally; and 2) the equivalence scale structures interpersonal comparisons of utility enough so that we can tell when two people have the same utility. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 8 / 21

Using Equivalence Scales To measure inequality or poverty, you: compute E h for each household h = 1,..., H in the population. Assign to each individual member of each household the equivalent expenditure x e i = x h /E h for all i in h. Do your welfare analysis: poverty (count xi e below a threshold); inequality (what is the variance of xi e); welfare (what is mean of x i e less a variance penalty). Do not follow Ebert and Moyes (2006) and weight individuals by 1/E h. This is required to get household inequality measures to coincide with individual inequality measures. But, household measures are meaningless, since individuals have utility, not households. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 9 / 21

Equivalence Scales and the Cost of Living exact equivalence scales also put structure on the cost-of-living index. consider the cost-of-living change for a price change given ESE: so C (p, u, z) = E (p, z)c (p, u, z), C (p 1, u, z) C (p 0, u, z) = E (p 1, z) C (p 1, u, z) E (p 0, z) C (p 0, u, z). So, the cost-of-living change for anybody is equal to that of the reference household multiplied by the relative size of the equivalence scale in the two price regimes. the cost-of-living index has an elasticity wrt utility that does not depend on characteristics. This completely characterises the behavioural restrictions of IB/ESE. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 10 / 21

Donaldson and Pendakur (2004, 2006) give other, more general, functional form restrictions that allow identification. These allow for equivalence scales which rise or fall with expenditure. ESE: Generalised ESE: Absolute ESE: ln x e i Generalised Absolute ESE: ln x e i = ln R(p) + ln x = ln R(p) + c(p) ln x x e i = A(p) + x x e i = A(p) + R(p)x Carsten, Kouvoulatianos, and Schroeder (2005, 2007) pursue a different, more Leiden-like, strategy: they ask people how costs vary with characteristics. This circumvents the identification problem without functional form restrictions. They find some support for Generalised Absolute ESE. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 11 / 21

Unobserved Preference Heterogeneity Up to now, heterogeneity has been observable. observed by the researcher? It screws up pretty much everything. What if it is not E.g., if there is unobserved heterogeneity in the level of cost, then ln E has an unobserved component, like ln E = ln E + ν. So, our nonlinear Engel curve equations w(ln x, z) = w(ln x ln E (z) ν, z) + d(z) have a regressor (ln x) with measurement error (ν). If there is unobserved heterogeneity in preferences, then could also be error terms in d(z). But, since d(z) is the price elasticity of E (p, z), this has implications on price responses of equivalence scales. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 12 / 21

More Unobserved Preference Heterogeneity Hoderlein (2007, 2008) shows that unobserved preference heterogeneity also makes it hard to test rationality restrictions with cross-sectional data. Although tests of homogeneity are robust to the presence of such heterogeneity, tests are symmetry and concavity are totally ruined. Matzkin (so many papers) and Beckert (a couple of papers) show that one can estimate demand models that allow for arbitrary unobserved preference heterogeneity by using quantile estimators. But, Slutsky symmetry and concavity tend to be pretty hard to impose in these contexts. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 13 / 21

Hicks Demands Let ɛ be a vector of random utility parameters. (Forget observed heterogeneity for the moment). Log total expenditure ln x, Log cost function ln x = ln C (p, u, ɛ) Shephard s lemma: w = Ω(p, u) = p C (p, u, ɛ). These are Hicks demands, easy to have flexible p and u effects, linear in parameters, and additive errors. e.g., C a poly in p, u plus p ɛ: ln C = ln p (a + 1 2 A ln p + bu + 1 ) 2 B ln pu + cu2 +... + ɛ w = Ω(p, u, ɛ) = a + Ap + bu + Bpu + cu 2 +... + ɛ If u were observable, this would be totally easy to do. Alas, it isn t observable. Pendakur and Sperlich (2009, 2010) provide a difficult semiparametric way to estimate u and then w. Allows for arbitrary A(u). Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 14 / 21

Implicit Marshallian Demands Problem with Hicks demands: u not observed. Solution: Implicit Marshallian Demands. Lewbel and Pendakur 2009, Tricks with Hicks: The EASI Demand System. The idea: construct C (p, u, ɛ) so that u = g [Ω(p, u, ɛ), p, x] for a simple g. Then let y = g(w, p, x) and estimate Implicit Marshallian demand functions: w = Ω(p, y, ɛ) In our applications y is linear in x, and y a log money metric utility measure so will call y log real expenditures. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 15 / 21

Implicit Marshallian Demands: Trivial Example let lnx = ln C (p, u, ɛ) = u + ln p [m(u) + ɛ] By Shephard s lemma, w = Ω(p, u, ɛ) = m(u) + ɛ so u = ln x ln p [m(u) + ɛ] = ln x ln p Ω(p, u, ɛ), so let y = g(w, p, x) = ln x ln p w. ln p w is the log of the geometric mean of prices. The geometric mean of prices was proposed by Stone (1954) as an intuitive price index, and is named after him. y is the log of Stone index deflated x. Implicit-Marshallian budget shares are w = m(ln x ln p w) + ɛ w = m(y) + ɛ Endogenous y, but instruments ln p, ln x are available. Here, y is Exact Stone Index (ESI) deflated expenditure. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 16 / 21

An EASI model Make a model where y is exactly affine in stone-index (EASI) deflated expenditure: Consider the cost function ln C (p, u, z, ɛ) = u + ln p [ M r= 0 b r u r + Cz + Dzu + 1 L 2 z l ln p A l ln p + 1 2 ln p B ln pu + ln p ɛ. l=0 Has Implicit Marshallian demands: ] where w = M r= 0 b r y r + Cz + Dzy + L l=0 z l A l ln p + B ln py + ɛ, y = g(w, p, x, z) = x ln p w + L l=0 z l ln p A l ln p/2 1 ln p. B ln p/2 Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 17 / 21

Nice and EASI Engel curves are arbitrary functions in y, z. The rank of demand is M. There are no Gorman type rank restrictions. Additive errors are (coherent, invertible) random preference heterogeneity. Like AI demands, linear in parameters up to y. Approximate model takes y = x ln p w. Could get via linear estimation. Closed form expressions for consumer surplus, cost of living indices, etc.,. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 18 / 21

EASI Estimation The empirical model in Lewbel and Pendakur 2009 is where w = 5 r= 0 b r y r + Cz + Dzy + L l=0 z l A l ln p + B ln py + ɛ, y = g(w, p, x, z) = x ln p w + L l=0 z l ln p A l ln p/2 1 ln p. B ln p/2 So, nonlinear system GMM would make instruments r as close as possible to orthogonal to a residual vector e = w 5 r= 0 b r y r + Cz + Dzy + L l=0 z l A l ln p + B ln py y is the endogenous variable. Instruments are natural: y = g(w, p, x, z), so p, x, z are the instruments. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 19 / 21

What s the Point? Heterogeneity is everywhere. Measurement of the cost-of-living, cost-of-characteristics, inequality, poverty, etc, have to take it seriously. We ve made progress over the last decade. Observed heterogeneity can be accomodated in demand. We can estimate its effect on cost and on demand Unobserved heterogeneity can be accomodated in demand, too. Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 20 / 21

Where to Go? Heterogeneity of unknown form what can we learn, eg, about averages? (Hoderlein 2009) What form does unobserved heterogeneity take? panels (Christensen 2008); Crawford and Pendakur (2009) Is it almost ignorable, like in approximate representative agent macro models? Collective Household models Krishna Pendakur (Simon Fraser University) Heterogeneity May 24, 2015 21 / 21