a = (a 1; :::a i )

Similar documents
Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem

1 Theory of the Firm: Topics and Exercises

EconS Microeconomic Theory I Recitation #5 - Production Theory-I 1

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

ECONOMICS 207 SPRING 2008 PROBLEM SET 13

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics

ECON5110: Microeconomics

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production

Modelling Production

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3)

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016

Advanced Microeconomics Problem Set 1

Implicit Function Theorem: One Equation

Microeconomics CHAPTER 2. THE FIRM

Lecture 4: Optimization. Maximizing a function of a single variable

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy.

Tutorial 2: Comparative Statics

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions

PROFIT FUNCTIONS. 1. REPRESENTATION OF TECHNOLOGY 1.1. Technology Sets. The technology set for a given production process is defined as

; p. p y p y p y. Production Set: We have 2 constraints on production - demand for each factor of production must be less than its endowment

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem

MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods. Course Notes 4

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

BEE1024 Mathematics for Economists

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis

Additional questions for Chapter 1 - solutions: 1. See Varian, p.20. Notice that Varian set a1=a2. 2. See Varian, p.20.

Addendum to: New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?

EconS Cost Structures

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

The Firm: Optimisation

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

z = f (x; y) = x 3 3x 2 y x 2 3

The Envelope Theorem

THE FIRM: OPTIMISATION

Comparative Statics Overview: I

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Notes on Convexity. Roy Radner Stern School, NYU. September 11, 2006

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

Lecture 1- The constrained optimization problem

EC400 Math for Microeconomics Syllabus The course is based on 6 sixty minutes lectures and on 6 ninety minutes classes.

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid May Microeconomics Grade

Advanced Microeconomics

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers

Advanced Microeconomics I: Consumers, Firms and Markets Chapters 1+2

Solutions to selected exercises from Jehle and Reny (2001): Advanced Microeconomic Theory

Microeconomic Theory: Lecture 2 Choice Theory and Consumer Demand

Local disaggregation of demand and excess demand functions: a new question

Game Theory. Bargaining Theory. ordi Massó. International Doctorate in Economic Analysis (IDEA) Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (UAB)

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

Chapter 4: Production Theory

Game Theory and Economics of Contracts Lecture 5 Static Single-agent Moral Hazard Model

Midterm Examination: Economics 210A October 2011

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

Rice University. Answer Key to Mid-Semester Examination Fall ECON 501: Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Part A

4. Duality and Sensitivity

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Calculus and optimization

1 + x 1/2. b) For what values of k is g a quasi-concave function? For what values of k is g a concave function? Explain your answers.

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

The Solow Model in Discrete Time Allan Drazen October 2017

Mathematical Economics. Lecture Notes (in extracts)

Chapter 5 Notes. These notes correspond to chapter 5 of Mas-Colell, Whinston, and Green.

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

Week 9: Topics in Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 2)

Lecture 6: Contraction mapping, inverse and implicit function theorems

Mathematical Foundations -1- Convexity and quasi-convexity. Convex set Convex function Concave function Quasi-concave function Supporting hyperplane

Advanced Microeconomics

Optimal taxation with monopolistic competition

Consumer Theory. Ichiro Obara. October 8, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Consumer Theory October 8, / 51

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich

Technology 1. that describes the (net) output of the L goods of the production process of the firm. By convention,

Microeconomics Fall 2017 Problem set 1: Possible answers

Adv. Micro Theory, ECON

MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMISTS. Course Convener. Contact: Office-Hours: X and Y. Teaching Assistant ATIYEH YEGANLOO

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice

Linear and non-linear programming

Fall Final Examination Solutions Thursday 10 January 2012

1 Convexity, concavity and quasi-concavity. (SB )

Essential Mathematics for Economists

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid June Microeconomics Grade

Non-convex Aggregate Technology and Optimal Economic Growth

Lagrangian Duality. Richard Lusby. Department of Management Engineering Technical University of Denmark

Workshop I The R n Vector Space. Linear Combinations

Technologies. Chapter Eighteen. Technologies. Input Bundles. Production Functions. Production Functions. Technology

Workbook. Michael Sampson. An Introduction to. Mathematical Economics Part 1 Q 2 Q 1. Loglinear Publishing

C02, C32, C43, D24, D42, D92, E01, E22, F11, H44, L51, M40, O47

Transcription:

1 Pro t maximization Behavioral assumption: an optimal set of actions is characterized by the conditions: max R(a 1 ; a ; :::a n ) C(a 1 ; a ; :::a n ) a = (a 1; :::a n) @R(a ) @a i = @C(a ) @a i The rm s pro t maximization problem reduces to choice of the price of outputs (or price of inputs) and levels of output (or inputs). The rm faces: Technological Constraints: feasibility of the production plan. Market constraints: e ect of actions of other agents on the rm. For competitive rms we assume price taking behavior. 1.1 Description of technology Suppose the rm has n possible goods to serve as inputs and/or outputs. We represent a speci c production plan by a vector y in R n where y i is negative if the i th good serve as a net input and positive if it serves as a net output. Such a vector is called a net output or netput vector. The set of all feasible production plans (netput vectors) is called production possibilities set (Y a subset of R n ). In the short run: Restricted or short-run production possibilities Y (z) consists of all feasible netput bundles compatible with the constraint z. 1. A rm produces one output with vector of inputs x. V (y) = x in R n +: (y,... x) is in Y. For the case above we can de ne the isoquant: Q(y) = x in R n +: x is in V (y), x is not in V (y 0 ) for y 0 > y the isoquant gives all input bundles that produce exactly y. 3. If the rm has only one output we can de ne the production function: f(x) = fy in R: y is the maximum output associated with x in Y g 1

4. A production plan y in Y is called e cient if there is no such y 0 such that y 0 = y, i.e. if there is no way to produce more output with the same inputs or to produce the same output with less inputs. We describe the set of e cient production plans by some function T :R n! R where T (y) = 0 only if y is e cient. Example 1: Cobb-Douglas Y = (y; x 1 ; x ) in R 3 : y 5 x 1 x 1 0 < < 1 V (y) = (x 1 ; x ) in R +:y 5 x 1 x 1 Q(y) = (x 1 ; x ) in R +:y = x 1 x 1 Y (z) = (y; x 1 ; x ) in R 3 : y 5 x 1 x 1, x = z T (y; x 1 ; x ) = y x 1 x 1 Leontief technology f(x 1 ; x ) = x 1 x 1 Y = (y; x 1 ; x ) in R 3 : y 5 min (ax 1 ; bx ) V (y) = (x 1 ; x ) in R +: y 5 min (ax 1 ; bx ) Q(y) = (x 1 ; x ) in R +:y = min (ax 1 ; bx ) T (y; x 1 ; x ) = y min (ax 1 ; bx ) f(x 1 ; x ) = min (ax 1 ; bx ) 1. Description of Production Sets and Input Requirement Sets The input set is monotonic if: Monotonicity: x is in V (y) and x 0 = x, then x 0 is in V (y) The input set is convex if: Convexity: if x is in V (y) and x 0 is in V (y) then tx+(1 t)x 0 is in V (y) for all 0 5 t 5 1. That is V (y) is a convex set.

1.3 The technical rate of substitution Consider x n (x 1 ;...x n 1 ) the (implicit) function that tell us how much of x n it takes to produce y if we are using x 1 ;...x n 1 of the other factors. Then the function x n (x 1 ;...x n 1 ) has to satisfy the identity: f(x 1 ; :::x n 1 ; x n (x 1 ; :::x n 1 ) y We are interested for an expression for @x n (x 1;...x n 1)=@x 1. Di erentiating the above identity we nd: or @f(x ) @x 1 = @f(x ) @x n @x n (x 1; :::x n 1) @x 1 = 0 @x n (x 1; :::x n 1) @x 1 = @f(x )=@x 1 @f(x )=@x n Example: Technical rate of Substitution in a Cobb-Douglas Technology. f(x 1 ; x ) = x 1 x 1 @f(x) = x 1 1 x 1 @x 1 @f(x) @x = (1 )x 1 x @x (x 1 ) = x 1 1 x 1 @x 1 (1 )x 1 x = (1 ) x x 1 1.4 Returns to Scale Constant Return to Scale. A technology exhibits constant return to scale if any of the following are satis ed: 1. y is in Y implies ty is in Y for all t > 0.. x is in V (y) implies tx is in V (ty) for all t > 0. 3. f(tx) = tf(x) for all t > 0 i.e. f(x)is homogeneous of degree 1. Increasing Return to Scale. A technology exhibits increasing return to scale if f(tx) > tf(x) for all t > 1. Decreasing Return to Scale. A technology exhibits increasing return to scale if f(tx) < tf(x) for all t > 1. Restricted Production Possibility sets may exhibits decreasing return to scale. Consider what happens if we increase all inputs by some small amount t. This is given by: 3

@f(tx) @t We convert this into an elasticity: @f(tx) @t t f(tx) We evaluate this at t = 1 to see what elasticity of scale is at t = 1: e(x) = @f(tx) @t t f(tx) j t=1 The elasticity of scale measures the percent increase in scale. We say that the technology exhibits increasing, constant or decreasing return to scale if e(x) is greater, equal or less than 1. 1.5 The Competitive Firm Consider the problem of a rm that takes prices as given in both its output and its factor markets. Let p be a vector of prices for inputs and outputs of the rm The pro t maximization problem of the rm can be stated as: (p) = max py s:t:y is in Y Since output are positive numbers and inputs are negative numbers, this problem give us the maximum of revenue minus costs. The (p) is the pro t function of the rm. In a short-run maximization problem we may de ne the short-run or restricted pro t function: (p; z) = max py s:t:y is in Y (z) If the rm produces only one output it may be written as: (p; w) = max pf(x) where p is now the scalar price of output and w is the vector of factor prices. In this case we can also write a variant of the restricted pro t function, the cost function: wx c(w;y) = min wx s:t:x is in V (y) 4

In the short-run we want to consider the restricted or short-run cost function: c(w;y; z) = min wx s:t:(y; x)is in Y (z) The cost function gives the minimum cost of producing a level of output y when factor prices are w. Pro t-maximizing and cost-minimizing behavior may be calculated. The rst-order conditions for the single output pro t maximization problem are: or pdf(x ) = w p @f(x ) @x i = w i These conditions say that the value marginal product of each factor must be equal to its price. The second-order condition for pro t maximization is that the matrix of second order derivatives of the production function must be negative semide nite at the optimum point, that is: @ D f(x f(x ) ) = @x i @x j satis es the condition that hd f(x )h 0 for all vectors h. Geometrically this means that the production function must be locally concave in the neighborhood of an optimum. For each vector of prices (p; w) there will in general be some optimal choice of factors x. The function x(p; w) that gives us the optimal choice of inputs as a function of the prices is called the demand function of the rm. Similarly, y(p; w) = f(x(p; w)). is called the supply function of the rm. We consider the problem of nding a cost-minimizing way to produce a given level of output: min wx s:t:f(x) = y The Lagrangian expression for cost minimization is: L(x;) = wx (f(x) y) The rst-order conditions characterizing an interior solution to this problem are: 5

w = Df(x ) where is the lagrange multiplier of the constraint and the second order conditions : or: hd f(x )h 0 for all h satisfying wh = 0 @ L(x ; ) @ f(x ) = @x i @x j @x i @x j Algebraically, this means that D f(x ) must be negative semide nite for all directions h orthogonal to w. The production function should be locally quasi-concave which is another way of saying that the input requirement sets must be locally convex. From the rst order conditions (since = 1 @f(x ) w i @x i for all i) we have that: w i w j = @f(x ) @x i @f(x ) @x j i; j = 1; :::n The term @f(x ) @x i n @f(x ) @x j represents the technical rate of substitution at what rate factor j can be substituted for factor i while maintaining a constant level of output. The term w i nw j represents the economic rate of substitution at what rate factor j can be substituted for factor i. For each choice of w and y there will be some choice of x that minimizes the cost of producing y units of output. We will call the function that gives us this optimal choice the conditional factor demand function and write it as x(w; y). That conditional demand depends on the level of output produced and on the factor prices. We can combine the problem of cost minimization and pro t maximization for a price-taking rm by writing the pro t maximization problem in the following way: max py c(w; y) Here the rst term gives revenue and the second term the minimum cost of achieving that revenue. The rst order conditions for pro t maximization are: p = @c(w; y ) @y or price equals marginal costs. The second order condition is @ c(w; y )=@y = 0 or that marginal cost must be increasing at the optimal level of output. 6

1.6 Average and Marginal Costs The cost function is our primary means of describing the economic possibilities of a rm. The cost function can always be expressed as the value of the conditional factor demands: c(w; y) wx(w; y) In the short-run some of the factors of production are xed at predetermined levels. Let x f be the vector of xed factors, and break up w into w = (w w ; w f ) the vector of prices of the variables and the xed factors. The short-run conditional factor demand functions will generally depend on x f so we write them as x v (w; y; x f ):Then the short-run cost function may be written as: c(w; y; x f ) w v x v (w; y; x f ) + w f x f The term w v x(w; y; x f ) is called the short-run variable costs and the term w f x f is xed costs. We can de ne various derived cost concepts from these basic units: SAC = c(w; y; x f ) y SAV C = w vx v (w; y; x f ) y SAF C = w f x f y ST C = w v x(w; y; x f ) + w f x f = c(w; y; x f ) SMC = @c(w; y; x f ) @y When all factors are variable the rm will optimize in the choice of x f. The long-run cost function only depends on the factor prices and the level of output. Let x f (w; y) be the optimal choice of the xed factors and let x v (w; y) = x v (w; y; x f (w; y)) be the optimal choice of the variable factors. Then the longrun cost function may be written as: c(w; y) = w v x v (w; y) + w f x f (w; y) = c(w; y); x f (w; y)) The long-run cost function can be used to de ne: LAC = LMC = c(w; y) y @c(w; y) @y 7

1.7 The Geometry of Costs In the short-run the cost function has two components: xed costs and variable costs. We can write: SAC = c(w; y; x f ) = w f x f y y = SAF C + SAV C + w vx v (w; y; x f ) y 1.8 Long Run and Short Run Cost Curves Let us write the long-run cost function as c(y) = c(y; z(y)). Here we have omitted the factor prices since they are assumed xed, and we let z(y) be the cost-minimizing demand for the xed factors. Let y be some level of output and let z = z(y ) be the associated demand for the xed factors. The short-run cost c(y; z ) must be at least as greater as the long-run cost c(y; z(y)) for all levels of output, and the short run cost will equal the long-run costs at output y : c(y ; z ) = c(y ; z(y )). Hence the long run and the short run cost curves must be tangent at y. The slope of the long-run cost curve at y is: dc(y ; z(y )) dy = @c(y ; z ) dy + P i @c(y ; z ) @z i (y ) dy i @y But since z is the optimal choice of the xed factors at the output level y, we must have: @c(y ; z ) = 0 all i dy i Thus the long run marginal costs at y equal short-run marginal costs at (y ; z ). 1.9 Cost and Pro t Function with Variable Factor Prices Properties of the Cost Function: 1. (nondecreasing in w)if w 0 > w then c(w 0 ; y) > c(w; y). (homogeneous of degree 1 in w) c(tw; y) = tc(w; y) for t > 0 3. (concave in w) c(tw + (1 t)w 0 ; y) > tc(w; y) + (1 t)c(w 0 ; y) 4. continuous in w) c is continuous as a function ofw for w 0t: Properties of the Pro t Function: 1. (nondecreasing in p,nondecreasing in w )If p 0 > p and w 0 w then (p 0 w 0 ) > (p; w). (homogeneous of degree 1 in (p; w)) (tp; tw) = t(p; w) for t > 0 8

3. (convex in p; w) Let (p 00 ; w 00 ) = (tp + (1 t)p 0 ; tw + (1 t)w 0 ) Then: (p 00 ; w 00 ) t(p; w) + (1 t)(p 0 w 0 ) for 0 t 1 4. (continuous in (p; w)) at least when p > 0 and w 0. 1.10 Properties of Demand and Supply Functions These functions give the optimal choices of inputs and outputs as a function of the prices are known as demand and supply functions. The factor demand function x i (p; w)must satisfy the restriction that: x i (tp; tw) = x i (p; w) so they must be homogeneous of degree zero. A function f : R n +! R is homogeneous of degree k if f(tx) = t k f(x) for all t > 0. In particular f is homogeneous of degree 0 if f(tx) = f(x) and it is homogeneous of degree 1 if f(tx) = tf(x). Euler s law: If f is a di erentiable function homogeneous of degree 1 then: f(x) = nx i=1 @f(x) x i @x i If f(x) is homogeneous of degree 1 then @f(x) @x i is homogeneous of degree 0. 1.11 The Relationship between Demand Function and Pro t Function Hotelling s Lemma: Let y(p; w) be the rm s supply function and let x i (p; w) be the rm s demand function for factor i. Then: y(p; w) = @(p; w) @p @(p; w) x i (p; w) = @w when the derivative exists and when w 0 p 0. When a price of a factor changes in nitesimally, there will be two e ects. First, there is a direct e ect on pro ts of d = dw i x i (p; w) because if the price of a factor changes by 1 euro and the rm is employing 100 units of that factor, the pro ts will go down of 100 euros. Second, there is an indirect e ect in that the rm will nd in its interests to change its production plan. But the impact on pro ts of any in nitesimal change in the production plan must be zero since we are already at the optimum production plan. Hence, the total impact of the indirect e ect is zero, and we are left only with the direct e ect. 9

Shephard s lemma: Let x i (w;y) be the rm s conditional factor demand for input i. Then if c is di erentiable at (w;y), and w 0 x i (w;y) = @c(w; y) @w i If we are operating at a cost-minimizing point and the price w i increases, there will be a direct e ect, in that the expenditure on the rst factor will increase. There will also be an indirect e ect, in that we will want to change the factor mix. But since we are operating at a cost-minimizing point, any such in nitesimal change must yield zero additional pro ts. We have shown that cost function have certain properties that follow from the structure of the cost minimization properties; we have shown above that the demand function are simply the derivatives of the cost function. Hence, the properties we have found concerning the cost function will translate into certain restriction on its derivatives, the factor demand functions. 1. The cost function is increasing in factor prices. Therefore, x i (w;y) > 0. @c(w;y) @w i =. The cost function is homogeneous of degree 1 in w. Therefore, the derivative of the cost function, the factor demands, are homogeneous of degree 0 in w. 3. The cost function is concave in w. Reminder: A function f : R n! R is concave if f(tx + (1 t)y) = tf(x) + (1 t)f(y) for all 0 5 t 5 1. If f is twice di erentiable we have equivalent criteria: The function f is concave if f(y) 5 f(x) + Df(x)(y x) for all x and y in R n. The function f is concave if the matrix of second derivatives D f(x) is negative semide nite at all x. 1.1 Duality We have seen if we are given a speci cation of the technology, say, as a production function, and if this technology satis es certain stated properties, we can obtain its cost function under certain conditions. Could the exercise be carried out in reverse? That is, if we knew the cost function, could we infer the production technology that might have generated this cost function? The answer is "yes, provided the technology is convex and monotonic." given the cost function, we can obtain a special form of the input requirement set as follows: V (y) = fxjwx wx(w; y) = c(w; y) for all w 0g 10

where the asterisk indicates that it is a special kind of input requirement set. We can now try and relate this input-requirement set, constructed on cost considerations, to the usual technologically de ned input-requirement set, V (y). The claim is, if V (y) represents a convex and monotonic technology, V (y) = V (y). Further, if the technology is non-convex or non-monotonic, V (y) will be a convexi ed, monotonized version of V (y). The overall implication is that the cost function summarises all the economically relevant aspect of the underlying technology. 11