Analysis of the speed of convergence

Similar documents
Chapter 9 Solow. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos. Computational Economics: a concise introduction

Lecture 3 - Solow Model

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Convergence behaviour in exogenous growth models

Solow Growth Model. Sang Yoon (Tim) Lee. Jan 9-16, last updated: January 20, Toulouse School of Economics

Modeling Economic Growth Using Differential Equations

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Growth. Growth Theory. Mark Huggett 1. 1 Georgetown. January 26, 2018

The Solow Growth Model

From Difference to Differential Equations I

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

14.05: Section Handout #1 Solow Model

Economic Growth

Generic Analysis of Endogenous Growth Models

Topic 5: The Difference Equation

On the dynamics of basic growth models: Ratio stability versus convergence and divergence in state space

3 GROWTH AND CAPITAL ACCUMULATION: THE SOLOW MODEL

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L2: Economic growth II

A Generalized Solow Nonautonomous Model with Delay and Bounded Population Growth

The Solow Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. January 26, Econ520

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2015 P. Gourinchas/D. Romer MIDTERM EXAM

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models

Endogenous Growth Theory

Equating output per worker to GDP per capita, the growth rate of GDP per capita

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

EC9A2 Advanced Macro Analysis - Class #1

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Third Edition

THE SOLOW-SWAN MODEL WITH A NEGATIVE LABOR GROWTH RATE

Dynamical Systems. August 13, 2013

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Chapter 12 Ramsey Cass Koopmans model

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 4

The Solow Growth Model

Growth Theory: Review

Economics 202A Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 5

DYNAMIC LECTURE 1 UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

1. Basic Neoclassical Model (Solow Model) (April 14, 2014)

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 2 : Balance Growth Paths

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

General motivation behind the augmented Solow model

The Ramsey/Cass-Koopmans (RCK) Model

XLVIII Reunión Anual. Noviembre de 2013

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Econ 7110 slides Growth models: Solow, Diamond, Malthus. January 8, 2017

Input-biased technical progress and the aggregate elasticity of substitution: Evidence from 14 EU Member States

Growth Theory: Review

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

Chapter 2. The Solow Growth Model

Lecture 5 Dynamics of the Growth Model. Noah Williams

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

Problem Set 2. E. Charlie Nusbaum Econ 204A October 12, 2015

Lecture notes on modern growth theories

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L1: Economic growth I

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

The Solow Model in Discrete Time Allan Drazen October 2017

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Lecture notes on modern growth theories

Math Review ECON 300: Spring 2014 Benjamin A. Jones MATH/CALCULUS REVIEW

Solution by the Maximum Principle

Another Proof for the Stability of a Modified Solow Model

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

Economic Growth Theory. Vahagn Jerbashian. Lecture notes

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

"Solow Model" and Its' Linkage with "Harrod-Domar"

Lecture 1: The Classical Optimal Growth Model

Economics 2: Growth (Growth in the Solow Model)

On the Dynamic Implications of the Cobb- Douglas Production Function

Tvestlanka Karagyozova University of Connecticut

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Growth: Facts and Theories

Solution to Homework 2 - Exogeneous Growth Models

Taylor and Maclaurin Series. Approximating functions using Polynomials.

Introduction to Real Business Cycles: The Solow Model and Dynamic Optimization

2 The model with Kaldor-Pasinetti saving

From Economic Model to Econometric Model (The Mincer Model)

Artificial Intelligence and Economic Growth

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

4 Real Analysis. Exercise 30. Show that if A and B are both convex sets, their intersection is convex but not necessarily their union.

Taylor and Maclaurin Series. Approximating functions using Polynomials.

6x 2 8x + 5 ) = 12x 8. f (x) ) = d (12x 8) = 12

LECTURE NOTES ON MICROECONOMICS

4.4 The functional distribution of income

Problem Set #2: Overlapping Generations Models Suggested Solutions - Q2 revised

Endogenous Growth. Lecture 17 & 18. Topics in Macroeconomics. December 8 & 9, 2008

Neoclassical Models of Endogenous Growth

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PS 5, preliminary version

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Lecture 2: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn Lars Calmfors

Comparative Statics. Autumn 2018

Two-Level CES Production Technology in the Solow and Diamond Growth Models

Economics 202A Lecture Outline #3 (version 1.0)

EconS 301. Math Review. Math Concepts

A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth

Transcription:

Analysis of the speed of convergence Lionel Artige HEC Université de Liège 30 january 2010

Neoclassical Production Function We will assume a production function of the Cobb-Douglas form: F[K(t), L(t), A(t)] = A K(t) α L(t) 1- α where K(t) is the physical capital stock at time t, L(t) is labor and A is the constant level of total factor productivity. This Cobb-Douglas function is homogeneous of degree 1. Therefore, it is possible to write it in intensive form: f[k(t)] = A k(t) α where k = K/L is the capital-labor ratio. 2

Exogenous Growth Model: The Solow-Swan Model The fundamental equation of the Solow-Swan model is the equation of the capital accumulation: dk dt = sak α (n + δ) The growth rate of the capital-labor ratio is: dk/dt dk = sak α -1 (n + δ) The derivative of this growth rate with respect to k is negative. 3

f(k) Production function: graphical representation This curve is the graphical representation of the production function in intensive form, where k = K/L. The function f(k) is assumed to concave. k 4

f(k) Steady state f(k*) f[k(0)] A E The point A, whose coordinates are (k(0);f(k(0)), is the initial level of the economy. The point E, whose coordinates are (k*;f(k*)), is the steady state of the function f(k). This is the long-term level of the economy. k(0) k* k 5

f(k) Growth rate at the steady state f(k*) B E C f[k(0)] A The straight line (BC) is the tangent to the point E. On the graph, the slope of the tangent appears to be 0. This slope is the instantaneous rate of variation of the function f(k) at the value k=k*. Slope of the tangent = f (k*) k(0) k* k The growth rate of this economy at the steady state (E) is equal to 0. 6

How to calculate the instantaneous rate of variation? The instantaneous rate of variation (or derivative at a point) is f (k*) = lim k k* f(k) f(k*) k k* = lim h 0 f(k*+ h) f(k*) h For our production function, the instantaneous rate of variation at the steady state point is f (k*) = 0 This means that the production per worker does not grow at the steady state. 7

Growth rate between two points on the curve (e.g. between A and E) The level of product per worker is f [k(0)] when k = k(0) and is f (k*) when k = k*. The difference in level (f (k*) - f [k(0)]) is the increase in product per worker when k increases from k = k(0) to k = k*. Wecanalsocalculatethegrowthrate (g) of the product per worker when k increases from k = k(0) to k = k*. It is the geometric mean of all the instantaneous rates of variation between k = k(0) to k = k*: dk/dt g = = [f (k(0)) f (k*)] 1/n for all k [k(0), k*] and n k n derivatives where n is the number of compounding. When n compounding is continuous. 8

f(k) Growth rate between A and E f(k*) B E C f[k(0)] A The instantaneous rates of variation between k(0) and k* are all different since the function is non-linear. In fact, the instantaneous rates of variation decrease as k increases from k(0) to k*. The slopes are increasingly weaker. k(0) k* k Thegrowthrate betweena and E is the geometric mean of all the instantaneous rates of variation 9

Calculation of average growth rate between A and E If we know the values for f[k(0)] and f(k*) and the number of periods (e.g. number of years) that elapsed for the economy to go from k(0) to k*, then we can calculate the average growth rate between f[k(0)] and f(k*) : R = {ln f(k*) ln f[k(0)]} 1/t where t is the number of periods = (number of dates 1). (e.g. 1991, 1992 and 1993 are 3 dates but 1991-1992 and 1992-1993 are two periods). This average growth rate R is calculated by using the geometric mean where the growth rate compound continuously. If the number of periods is 1, then t = 1 and the growth rate is just the continuous growth rate between f[k(0)] and f(k*). This continuous growth rate is also called the speed of convergence. The name comes from the result that the steady state E is stable, hence the economy converges to E regardless of its initial start k(0) (except k (0) = 0). 10

Calculation of average growth rate between A and E (cont.) We can obviously use the growth rate to calculate the level of f(k*) if we know f[k(0)]: f(k*) = exp(rt) f[k(0)] To sum up, the growth rate of f[k(t)] is a non-linear function of k(t). It decreases as k(t) increases due to the concavity of the production function. Therefore, for linear estimation purposes, it is necessary to compute a growth rate that is linear in k(t) and could be a reasonable approximation of the true growth rate. 11

f(k) Graphical linear approximation of the growth rate F f(k*) B E C f[k(0)] D A Graphically, to approximate the growth rate between the points A and E, one has to draw a line (DF) passing through A and E. The slope of this straight line gives the approximation of the growth rate of the concave function. k(0) k* k The farther A is located from E, the worse is the approximation. In our graph, the approximation is bad because A is too far from E. 12

Analytical linear approximation of the growth rate To compute an analytical linear approximation of the growth rate, one has to linearize the growth rate function (dk/dt)/k around its steady state. To do so, we apply to this function a Taylor expansion of order 1 around the steady state k* to obtain a linear function: dk/dt k dk/dt = + k* dk/dt k (k k*) k k = k* In the Solow-Swan model the growth rate is dk/dt dk = sak α -1 (n + δ) At the steady state, the growth rate is 0, then : sak α -1 = (n + δ) 13

Analytical linear approximation of the growth rate Let us approximate the nonlinear Solow growth rate function by a Taylor polynomial of the first order: dk/dt k = sa(k*) α -1 (n + δ) + (sak(t) α -1 (n + δ)) (k(t) k*) k k(t) = k* = 0 + (α 1)sA(k*) α -2 (k(t) k*) Since sak α -1 = (n + δ) at the steady state, we can further simplify to: dk/dt k(t) k* = (1 α) (n + δ) dk k* where [(k(t) k*)/k*] is the rate of variation of k(t) around the steady state. This new growth function is linear in k(t). An increase in k(t) yields a decrease in the growth rate of (1 α) (n + δ)/k*. 14

log linear approximation of the growth rate A more convenient way for econometric analysis is to log linearize the original growth rate function. It allows to interpret the result as a percentage deviation from the steady state. The log linearization consists in applying a first-order Taylor expansion of log(k) around log(k*). Let us write dk/dt dk = sak α -1 (n + δ) in log: d log k(t) dt = sa e (α 1) log k(t) (n + δ) (α 1) log k(t) Let us define g[log k(t)] = sa e (n function: + δ). Let us approximate this g[log k(t)] = g[log k*] + g[log k(t)] log k(t) log k(t) = log k* (log k(t) log k*) 15

log linear approximation of the growth rate g[log k(t)] = sa e (α 1) log k* (n + δ) + (α 1) sa e (α 1) log k* (log k(t) log k*) = 0 + (α 1) (n + δ) (log k(t) log k*) Therefore, the log linear form of the growth rate function is: d log k(t) dt = (1 α) (n + δ) (log k(t) log k*) And d{d log k(t)/dt} where β = d log k(t) d{d log k(t)/dt} d log k(t) = (1 α) (n + δ) is called the speed of convergence in the economic growth literature. 1% deviation from k* yields a percentage change in the growth rate of k equal to (1 α) (n + δ) when the production function is Cobb-Douglas. 16

log linear approximation of the growth rate In fact, we are interested in the growth rate of income per capita rather than in the growth rate of the capital labor ratio. But, they are the same: dy(t)/dt y(t) = d lny(t) dt = d ln k(t)α dt = d [α ln k(t)] dt = d [α ln k(t)]. dk(t) d k(t) dt = α dk/dt dk And y(t) = k(t) α => y(t) y* log y(t) = a log k(t) y* k* k(t) α k(t) α = = Taking the log : y* (k*) α => log y(t) log y* = α [log k(t) log k*]. Then d log k(t) dt = β (log k(t) log k*) => 1 α d log y(t) dt = β 1 α (log y(t) log y*) 17

log linear approximation of the growth rate As a result: d log y(t) dt = β (log y(t) log y*) (1) The speed of convergence is the same for the income per capita as for the capital-labor ratio. Equation (1) is a first-order differential equation of the type: log y (t) + β log y(t) = β log y* where log y (t) is the time derivative of log y(t). It can be solved in four steps: 18

Solution of the linear differential growth equation of the first-order Let us first define: z(t) = log y(t) First step: Solution of the corresponding homogenous equation z (t) + β z(t) = 0 z (t) z(t) = β => z (t) z(t) dt = β dt => log z(t) + b 1 = βt + b 2 => log z(t) = βt + b where b = b 1 +b 2 => e log z(t) = e βt + b => z 1 (t) = e βt e b => z 1 (t) = e βt θ where θ = e b Second step: Particular solution of the equation z (t) + β z(t) = β z* An obvious particular solution is at the steady state where z (t) = 0, then z 2 (t) =z*. 19

Solution of the linear differential growth equation of the first-order Third step: General solution of the equation z (t) + β z(t) = β z* This is the sum of the solution of the homogenous equation and the particular solution of our equation: z(t) = z 1 (t) + z 2 (t) = e βt θ + z* (2) Fourth step: Final solution of the equation z (t) + β z(t) = β z* What is left to do is to give a value for θ. This value can be determined by a value for z(t) at a particular date t. For example, the initial condition is a good candidate: z(0) for t = 0. Then, at t = 0, z(0) = e 0 θ + z* => θ = z(0) z* Substituting in (2) for θ : z(t) = e βt [z(0) z*] + z* => z(t) = (1 e βt ) z* + e βt z(0) 20

Solution of the linear differential growth equation of the first-order Eventually, as z(t) = log y(t), the solution of our differential equation is log y(t) = (1 e βt ) log y* + e βt log y(0) (3) where β = (1 α)(n + δ) and y* = (k*) α If we have data on GDP per capita in an initial date and a terminal date, then we can estimate the speed of convergence β. If we substract log y(0) from both sides of (3) and substitute for y* then log y(t) log y(0) = (1 e βt ) log 1 1 - α [log sa log (n + δ] + (1 e βt ) log y(0) In the Solow-Swan model, the growth of income (left-hand side) is a function of the determinants of the steady state and the initial level of income. 21