Economics 202A Lecture Outline #3 (version 1.0)

Similar documents
The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Advanced Macroeconomics

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

Econ 204A: Section 3

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

Dynamic Optimization Using Lagrange Multipliers

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2015 P. Gourinchas/D. Romer MIDTERM EXAM

The Growth Model in Continuous Time (Ramsey Model)

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions)

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Lecture 1: The Classical Optimal Growth Model

Advanced Macroeconomics

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Problem Set 3: Proposed solutions Econ Fall 2012 (Prof. Roberto Chang)

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Solution to Homework 2 - Exogeneous Growth Models

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

The Ramsey/Cass-Koopmans (RCK) Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Endogenous Growth. Lecture 17 & 18. Topics in Macroeconomics. December 8 & 9, 2008

Volume 29, Issue 4. Stability under learning: the neo-classical growth problem

Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452)

Introduction to Real Business Cycles: The Solow Model and Dynamic Optimization

Lecture 3: Dynamics of small open economies

Chapter 15. Several of the applications of constrained optimization presented in Chapter 11 are. Dynamic Optimization

The Solow Model in Discrete Time Allan Drazen October 2017

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

A Note on the Ramsey Growth Model with the von Bertalanffy Population Law

Chapter 12 Ramsey Cass Koopmans model

Economic Growth

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

ECON607 Fall 2010 University of Hawaii Professor Hui He TA: Xiaodong Sun Assignment 2

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital

The Solow Growth Model

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 2

Economic Growth: Lectures 10 and 11, Endogenous Technological Change

Housing in a two sector dynastic altruism model

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Neoclassical Growth Model / Cake Eating Problem

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

14.05: Section Handout #1 Solow Model

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

The Quest for Status and Endogenous Labor Supply: the Relative Wealth Framework

Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks

Problem 1 (30 points)

Overlapping Generations Model

Chapter 3 Task 1-4. Growth and Innovation Fridtjof Zimmermann

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Economic Growth (Continued) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model. 1 Literature. Ramsey (1928) Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965) 2 Households (Preferences)

Macroeconomic Theory I. Cesar E. Tamayo Department of Economics, Rutgers University

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

On the Dynamic Implications of the Cobb- Douglas Production Function

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

On the dynamics of basic growth models: Ratio stability versus convergence and divergence in state space

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

Generic Analysis of Endogenous Growth Models

Introduction to Recursive Methods

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 2, Review of Endogenous Growth: Expanding Variety Models

The Neoclassical Growth Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models

Modern Macroeconomics II

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Neoclassical Models of Endogenous Growth

From Difference to Differential Equations I

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

The Necessity of the Transversality Condition at Infinity: A (Very) Special Case

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Real Business Cycle Models. Jordi Galí. Universitat Pompeu Fabra Spring 2018

Macroeconomics I. University of Tokyo. Lecture 12. The Neo-Classical Growth Model: Prelude to LS Chapter 11.

The basic representative agent model: Ramsey

Macroeconomics Theory II

On the Invariance of the Rate of Return to Convex Adjustment Costs

How much should the nation save?

Economic Growth Theory. Vahagn Jerbashian. Lecture notes

Econ 7110 slides Growth models: Solow, Diamond, Malthus. January 8, 2017

Lecture 15 Real Business Cycle Model. Noah Williams

Bubbles and Credit Constraints

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

Solution by the Maximum Principle

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

The Solow Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. January 26, Econ520

Lecture 5 Dynamics of the Growth Model. Noah Williams

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

Transcription:

Economics 202A Lecture Outline #3 (version.0) Maurice Obstfeld Steady State of the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model In the last few lectures we have seen how to set up the Ramsey-Cass- Koopmans Model in discrete time, and with an in nite horizon. We have reviewed the solution method for (bivariate) di erence equation systems and derived an exact solution to the model in a special case. I have not yet developed the main qualitative implications of the model however. These can perhaps be drawn out most conveniently by de ning the model s steady state (or balanced growth allocation) and linearizing the model around that long-run destination. As we saw, when f 00 (k) = 0 as in the last lecture, the model has no steady state in c and k, but in the customary case with f 00 (k) < 0 a well-de ned steady state exists. It is instructive to examine its properties. Let c and k denote the steady-state values. Then they must satisfy the intertemporal Euler equation u 0 (c) = + f 0 k u 0 (c); which is equivalent to f 0 k = + : () Intuitively, this states that the net marginal product of steady-state capital, f 0 k, equals the rate of pure time preference. Steady state values must also ensure that or, solving for c, that k = f k + ( ) k c ; + n c = f k (n + ) k: (2) If = =( + ); then we call the rate of pure time preference. With this notation eq. () becomes f 0 k = + :

Di erentiation of eq. (2) shows that per capita consumption is maximized when the constant capital stock equals k ; where f 0 (k ) = n + : (3) This is the golden rule point where the marginal product of capital just equals replacement needs. Because the model assumed (+n) <, however, it follows that n < : Because f 00 (k) < 0, a comparison of (3) with () shows that k < k : Given the consumer optimization assumed in this model, there is no possibility of a dynamically ine cient steady state with capital over-accumulation. This is one di erence compared to the Solow model. An excellent exercise is to linearize this model in the neighborhood of c; k and investigate its dynamic properties, in particular showing that the two chacteristics roots are, respectively, greater than and less than. The rst question on Problem Set 2 involves an example like that one, so I will not pursue the linearization here. Instead, I will look in greater detail at the continuous-time version of this model, using that as a springboard to a discussion of optimal control theory. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model in Continuous Time The rst tool we need is compound interest. Please bear with me if this is familiar ground. Suppose you invest $ for a year at 3% interest, compounded annually. After a year you will have + :03 = $:03: What if, instead, interest is compounded every six months? In other words, the interest plus principal accrued after six months is reinvested for another six months at a 3% annualized rate. In that case, after a year you will have (approximately) + :03 2 $:030225: 2 2

Clearly you get more money if interest is compounded periodically. and the more frequently it is compounded, the more you earn. For example, with quarterly compounding you end the year holding + :03 4 $:03033: 4 Weekly compounding gets you yet more, about $.03044. The numbers are approaching a limit as the time intervals become progressively ner. That limit is the (hypothetical) case of continuous compounding, which yields lim ( + h!0 :03h)=h e :03 $:03045: With this background, let s imagine time is measured in intervals of length h, so that t = 0; h; 2h; 3h; 4h; etc. The intertemporal objective to be maximized is now X ( + nh) t=h ( + h) t=h hu(c t ); t=0 where we multiply u(c t ) by h on the theory that the ow of utility from consumption at rate c t over a period of length h is proportional to the length of the period. In the limit as h! 0, this objective takes the form of an integral, Z 0 e ( n)t u [c(t)] dt Maximization is carried out subject to the constraint k t+h = hf(k t) + k t hk t hc t : + nh Above, f(k t ) is interpreted as the rate of output ow and as the rate of depreciation (per unit time). The Lagrangian for the optimization problem is L = X t=0 t=h + nh fhu(c t ) + t [hf(k t ) + k t hk t hc t ( + nh)k t+h]g : + h 3

First-order conditions are @L @k t+h = @L @c t = + nh + h t=h h [u 0 (c t ) t ] = 0; t=h (t+h)=h + nh + nh (+nh) t + t+h [hf 0 (k t+h) + h] = 0: + h + h These can be simpli ed to read (a familiar condition) and u 0 (c t ) = t (4) t+h h t = t [ + f 0 (k t+h )] + hf 0 (k t+h ) h : Going to the limit of continuous time (and assuming that (t) has a right-hand derivative) gives us lim h!0 t+h h t = _ (t) = (t) f + f 0 [k(t)]g : (5) Because the accumulation equation can be rewritten as k t+h k t h its continuous-time limit is = f(k t) (n + ) k t c t ; + nh _k(t) = f [k(t)] c(t) (n + )k(t): (6) Also necessary is the transversality condition lim e ( n)t u 0 [c(t)] k(t) = 0: t! To reduce this all to a di erential equation system in c and k, note that because u 0 (c t ) = t, _(t) = u 00 [c(t)] _c(t): By condition (5), u 00 [c(t)] _c(t) = u 0 [c(t)] f + f 0 [k(t)]g ; or 4

_c(t) c(t) = u 0 [c(t)] c(t)u 00 [c(t)] ff 0 [k(t)] ( + )g : This equation and eq. (6) constitute the desired system in c and k. To simplify the notation, I assume that u(c) has the isoelastic form u(c) = c in which case the last equation becomes _c(t) c(t) = ff 0 [k(t)] ( + )g : (7) In this equation (which is the continuous-time analog of the dynamic Euler equation), ; as noted earlier in this course, is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. Together with eq. (6), eq. (7) de nes the system s potential dynamic paths. The parameter helps determine the response of consumption to changes in the interest rate (or marginal product of capital). When is high, marginal utility declines more gently when consumption rises. Thus, for example, if f 0 [k(t)] rises above, c(t) will fall sharply, making _c(t) strongly positive. c(t) We will look more closely at the relationship among, saving, and interest rates later in the course. The system consisting of (7) and (6) has a useful phase diagram representation; I borrow the diagrams from David Romer s book. The steady state point in this diagram is a saddle point; given k(0); there is a unique value of c(0) that places the economy on the unique convergent saddle path. In the in nite-horizon case, the saddle path de nes the unique equilibrium consumption level. Why? Given a k(0). imagine that we start o at c(0) above the saddle. Then the dynamics of the system will cause the economy to crash into the y-axis, as k goes to zero. At that point c must drop abruptly to zero, which cannot be optimal. What if, given k(0), c(0) starts o below the saddle. Notice that the solution for eq. (7) is: c(t) = c(0)e R t 0 ff 0 [k(s)] (+)gds : (Why? Be sure you know how to di erentiate this expression.) Then lim e ( n)t u 0 [c(t)] k(t) = lim e ( n)t c(0) R t e 0 ff 0 [k(s)] (+)gds k(t) t! t! = c(0) lim k(t)e R t 0 ff 0 [k(s)] (n+)gds : t! 5 ;

This limit is zero along the saddle path (because f 0 (k)! + > n + ), but along the rising capital, declining consumption paths, f 0 (k) eventually falls below n + and the previous limit therefore is strictly positive. Thus, the transversality condition is violated. Perhaps surprisingly, the diagram can also be used to study the nitehorizon (T < ) case, but in that situation the equilibrium path looks di erent. Equations (7) and (6) still apply, but the terminal condition is k(t ) = 0. Thus, the economy appears to be on an unstable path of the diagram, with c(0) determined by the requirement that k hit 0 exactly at time T. Obviously, c(0) will always be above the saddle path in a nitehorizon problem. But the bigger is T, the closer is c(0) to its saddle value and the closer does the economy draw to c; k before veering o toward k(t ) = 0 relatively shortly before the terminal time T. Exogenous Growth We can easily add to the model an exogenous rate of labor-augmenting technological advance, g = A=A. _ For an individual the intertemporal Euler equation is the same. However, if we de ne consumption per e ciency labor unit as c E c=a, then we have _c E c = f 0 k E ( + ) g E = nf 0 k E + + g o : In addition, from _ k(t) = f [k(t)] c(t) (n + )k(t) and k E k=a we derive so that _k E k = k _ E k g = = f ke k E F (K=N; A) K=N c E k E C=N K=N (n + + g); _k E = f k E c E (n + + g)k E : (n + ) g Comparing the last two dynamic equations with (7) and (6), we see that there is a balanced growth path (steady state) c E ; k E where c and k both grow at rate g. As g is determined outside the model, we have exogenous growth, just as in the Solow model. 6

Optimal Control and the Maximum Principle The previous model illustrates a more general approach to solving continuoustime dynamic optimization problems. That approach is called the maximum principle. You will see that it givs precisely the same answers we derived above by passing to the continuous-time limit. A generic problem would be to maximize with respect to the path of the control variable c(t) the objective function Z 0 e t v [c(t); k(t)] dt subject to the transition equation for the state variable, k, _ k(t) = G [c(t); k(t)] ; with k(0) given. (In general c and k can be vectors of controls and states.) To implement it, set up the (present-value) Hamiltonian H [c(t); k(t); (t)] = e t (v [c(t); k(t)] + (t) fg [c(t); k(t)]g) : The multiplier is called the costate variable (it is a vector if k is a vector). It has an interpretation as the shadow price of the stock k, making H the present shadow value of the ow of consumption plus stock accumulation. Necessary conditions for an optimum are as follows. Optimality of the control: @H @c = e t (v c + G c ) = 0: Equation of motion for the costate variable: d dt e t = Equation of motion for the state variable: Initial condition k(0): Transversality condition: @H @k : _k = G [c(t); k(t)] : lim e t (t)k(t) = 0: t! 7

The rst of these conditions implies, of course, that v c + G c = 0; while the second can be expressed as _ = (v k + G k ) ; or, more intuitively, as the arbitrage formula _ + v k + G k = : An interpretation of the latter di erential equation comes from its integral solution, (t) = Z e (s t t) fv k [c(s); k(s)] + (s)g k [c(s); k(s)]g ds; which gives as a present discounted value of future marginal returns to k. Let us ask how to t the (discounted) Ramsey problem into this framework. The Hamiltonian is H [c(t); k(t); (t)] = e ( n)t (u [c(t)] + (t) ff [k(t)] c(t) (n + )k(t)]g) : The rst-order condition with respect to the control c is @H @c = 0 () u0 (c) = 0: The dynamic equation for the costate variable is _ = ( n) G k = ( n) [f 0 (k) (n + )] = [ + f 0 (k)] : These correspond exactly to eqs. (4) and (5) above. 8