A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

Similar documents
Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Economic Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

14.05: Section Handout #1 Solow Model

From Difference to Differential Equations I

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

Solution to Homework 2 - Exogeneous Growth Models

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Advanced Macroeconomics

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Economics 202A Lecture Outline #3 (version 1.0)

Advanced Macroeconomics

First Welfare Theorem

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Problem 1 (30 points)

14.452: Introduction to Economic Growth Problem Set 4

Agricultural Productivity, Comparative Advantage, and Economic Growth Kiminori Matsuyama

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

Time-varying Consumption Tax, Productive Government Spending, and Aggregate Instability.

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Growth Theory: Review

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions)

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Online Appendix The Growth of Low Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market. By David H. Autor and David Dorn

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks

Growth Theory: Review

Lecture 15 Real Business Cycle Model. Noah Williams

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Economic Growth (Continued) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model. 1 Literature. Ramsey (1928) Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965) 2 Households (Preferences)

Online Appendix I: Wealth Inequality in the Standard Neoclassical Growth Model

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

Market Structure and Productivity: A Concrete Example. Chad Syverson

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Econ 204A: Section 3

Structural Change in a Multi-Sector Model of Growth

Solutions to Macro Final 2006

Lecture 1: Overview, Hamiltonians and Phase Diagrams. ECO 521: Advanced Macroeconomics I. Benjamin Moll. Princeton University, Fall

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies:

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

The Real Business Cycle Model

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change

4.4 The functional distribution of income

Housing with overlapping generations

Second Welfare Theorem

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

The Solow Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. January 26, Econ520

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Introduction to Real Business Cycles: The Solow Model and Dynamic Optimization

Endogenous growth with addictive habits

Clarendon Lectures, Lecture 1 Directed Technical Change: Importance, Issues and Approaches

Cointegration and the Ramsey Model

The Ramsey/Cass-Koopmans (RCK) Model

Expanding Variety Models

Economic Growth Theory. Vahagn Jerbashian. Lecture notes

Endogenous growth theory. Tom Holden PhD Macroeconomics, Semester 2

14.999: Topics in Inequality, Lecture 4 Endogenous Technology and Automation

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Neoclassical Models of Endogenous Growth

A Note on the Ramsey Growth Model with the von Bertalanffy Population Law

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 2 : Balance Growth Paths

Macroeconomics Theory II

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

The Growth Model in Continuous Time (Ramsey Model)

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides Model

Competitive Equilibrium

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies

Dynamic Three-Factor Models of International Trade *

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Transcription:

Notes on Kongsamut et al. (2001) The goal of this model is to be consistent with the Kaldor facts (constancy of growth rates, capital shares, capital-output ratios) and the Kuznets facts (employment in services is increasing, in manufacturing it is roughly constant, in agriculture it is decreasing). The second fact that the authors advance is that the real consumption of different products vary a lot less over time than nominal consumption shares. Related, employment growth and relative price inflation are positively correlated (services become relatively more expensive and have a higher and higher worker share; opposite for agriculture). The primary mechanism that the authors propose is that there are varying income elasticities for food, manufactured products, and services. There are three sectors: agriculture, services, and manufacturing; labor can be reallocated, within periods, without adjustment costs. This makes sense because we are trying to match long-run patterns. Manufactured products can either be consumed or can be used to as investment, to augment the next period capital stock. The production of agricultural products and services are straightforward A t B A F (φ A t K t, N A t t ) S t B S F (φ S t K t, N S t t ) M t + δk + K B M F (φ M t K t, N M t t ) The total stock of labor is equal to 1 (i.e., the N s sum up to 1). Same for the φ s; they represent the fraction of capital that is used in each of its three possible uses. The final building block for the production side of the economy, g is the constant growth rate of the labor-augmenting technology term. That is: Ẋ t t g. It is crucial that the productivity growth is labor augmenting (and not, for example, factor neutral). We will set the manufactured good to be the numeraire; call P A and P S the price of the agricultural good and the service good (these can potentially vary across periods, but they won t so long as the productivity growth rates are constant across industries. There are other restrictions: that productivity growth is the same for all industries, and that the production functions of the three sectors are the same. The authors show, in a working paper version of the article, that these restrictions can be relaxed. The differential growth rates will result from the specification on preferences that we make. (It can t be from the technology side, since all industries have identical production functions and productivity growth rates.) 1

U e ρt C(t)1 σ 1 dt, where 1 σ C(t) ( A(t) Ā) β ( M(t) S(t) + S ) θ The key, here, is that the income elasticities of these products are different from 1: max ( A(t) Ā) β ( M(t) S(t) + S ) θ s.t. I(t) PS S(t) + P A A(t) + M(t) S(t) + S θ ( I PS S + PA Ā ) P S A(t) Ā β P A ( I PS S + PA Ā ) M(t) ( I P S S + PA Ā ) This is very similar to the Cobb-Douglas demand curves; the effective income is shifted down/up by P S S + PA Ā, and there is some necessary / surplus amount of the agricultural/service good that the representative consumer purchases before getting to the Cobb- Douglas part. log S(t) log I log A(t) log I Iθ > 1 (I + P S S PA Ā)θ P S S Iβ (I + P S S PA Ā)β + P A Ā < 1 The goal, remember, is to provide conditions under which the aggregate economy behaves as if it is on a balanced growth path. (Industries will grow at different rates, agriculture will grow more slowly; services more quickly. These rates will change over time as well. But we want output, capital per worker, and other aggregate variables to grow at constant, related rates). The first step will be to write out the real interest rate, and find conditions under which this real interest rate in constant. Then we will solve for the growth rate of consumption shares and labor shares of each of the sector outputs, and then finally graphically analyze the transitional dynamics when the condition for constant real interest rates fails to hold. We can write out the real interest rate using a no-arbitrage-type condition. Consumers can buy a unit of capital today in exchange for one unit of the manufactured good, rent that unit to firms who will pay B M F 1 (k, 1) for it, and have (1 δ) units of capital in the following period from which they will earn (1 δ) units of the manufactured good. They would be 2

indifferent with this series of transactions and buying a bond that earned a gross interest rate of (1 + r). (One fuzzy thing about these statements is that the model is written in continuous time.) Putting these statements together: 1 + r B M F 1 (k, 1) + 1 δ r B M F 1 (k, 1) δ The real interest rate will be constant if k is constant, which occurs if and only if K is constant (meaning that K must grow at rate g). The fact that all three products are produced using the same production function F implies that the allocation of capital to labor is the same across industries. and N s each sum to 1: The budget constraint: 1 φ A t Nt A φs t N S t φm t N M t Since the φ s if K t + δk t + M t + P A A t P S S t B M F (k, 1) Along a BGP, the left hand side grows at g; the left hand side grows at rate g if and only 1 Use the budget constraint for the manufactured good, then the homogeneity of the function F, and the fact that φa t N A t φs t N S t φm t N M t 1: ) K t + δk t + M t B M F (φ M t K t, Nt M t ( ) φ M t K t Nt M t B M F Nt M, 1 t ( ) Nt M Kt t B M F, 1 t N M t t B M F (k t, 1) Add services and agricultural goods to the previous equation: K t + δk t + M t + N S t t B M F (k t, 1) + N A t t B M F (k t, 1) N M t t B M F (k t, 1) + N S t t B M F (k t, 1) +N A t t B M F (k t, 1) t B M F (k t, 1) Now use the fact that B M B A P A and B M B S P S and then the definition of S and A : K t + δk t + M t + N S t t B S P S F (k t, 1) + N A t t B A P A F (k t, 1) N M t t B M F (k t, 1) + N S t t B M F (k t, 1) +Nt A t B M F (k t, 1) K t + δk t + M t + P A A t + P S S t t B M F (k t, 1) 3

P A A t P S S t grows at rate g From before: P S S t ( P S S + θ I PS S + PA Ā ) P A A t P A Ā + β ( I P S S + PA Ā ) Thus we need P S S + PA Ā + (θ + ) ( I P S S + PA Ā ) to grow at rate g. This can only happen if P S S PA Ā, which is equivalent to ĀB S SB A. This is the main proposition of the paper. 2 What are the growth rates of A t, M t, S t? ( St + S ) ( S 0 + S ) e gt Ṡ t S t t ( S0 e gt + S (e gt 1) ) t Ṡ t g S t + S S t S t g ( S 0 + S ) e gt Similarly: What about labor shares? A t A t g A t Ā A t From the definition of the production function N A t Ṅ A t A t B A F (k, 1) t A t A t Ẋ t B A F (k, 1) t B A F (k, 1) ( t ) 2 g ( A t Ā) A t g B A F (k, 1) t B A F (k, 1) t gā ; (goes to 0 as t ) B A F (k, 1) t 2 Side note: Is this a reasonable condition? In the data, the relative price for services (vs. agricultural products) has been trending upward. Kongsamut et al. would counter that quality improvements have led conventional service-price indices to have overstated growth rates. Still though, this knife edge condition will almost surely be violated in the data. At the same time, the requirement of constant r is probably too strict. It could be the case that P S S PA Ā yields an r that changes only very slowly (where the trend is clear only with a very long sample). 4

Similarly: Ṅt M 0 Ṅt S g S B S F (k, 1) t OK, but now what happens if ĀB S SB A? Write the Hamiltonian: What are the transitional dynamics? H(t) e ρt [ (A(t) Ā ) β ( M(t) S(t) + S ) ] θ 1 σ 1 1 σ +λ [B M F (K(t), ) δk(t) M(t) P A A(t) P S S(t)] Take first order conditions Thus: H M [ (A(t) M e ρt Ā ) β ( M(t) S(t) + S ) ] θ 1 σ λ 0 1 H P S S θ [ (A(t) S + S e ρt Ā ) β ( M(t) S(t) + S ) ] θ 1 σ λ 0 1 H P A A β [ (A(t) Ā ) β ( M(t) S(t) + A S ) ] θ 1 σ λ 0 Āe ρt H K B MF K (k, 1) δ Let P S S(t) θ M(t) B M B S S P A A(t) β M(t) + B M Ā B A κ ( ) β ( ) θ BA β BS θ B M B M ε B M B M S Ā B S B A Then we can re-write the Hamiltonian as follows: 5

H(t) e ρt [κm]1 σ 1 + λ [B M F (K(t), ) δk(t) 1 ] 1 σ M(t) ε And, again, take FOC (replacing F with a Cobb-Douglas function): Define: e ρt κ 1 σ M σ λ [ ] 1 λ M eρt κ σ 1 σ λ λ B MαK α 1 1 α δ K B M K α 1 α δk(t) 1 M(t) ε B M K α 1 α δk(t) 1 [ ] 1 λ σ 1 σ eρt κ σ ε Then: λ σ e ρt κ 1 σ λ; K K. λ λ αb M K α 1 + δ + ρ + σg K K B M α δ(t) 1 K α B M δ 1 K. K K B M K α 1 (δ + g) 1 M(t) ε [ ] 1 λ σ 1 σ eρt κ σ [ ] 1 σ λ ε K 1 ε If there is time: Talk through Figures 4-6 (reproduced here). The figure plots out the K and λ loci. The term is what is causing the K loci to shift over time. Assuming ε is less than 0, as time passes the term gets bigger, meaning ε gets smaller; this will shift down the K loci as time passes. Now consider the phase diagram for a given λ, K pair (i.e., imagine that we could hold ε fixed for a moment). What would the transitional dynamics look like for the phase diagram? Looking at the first equation, if K > K then λ is positive (negative otherwise). Looking at the second equation, if we are above the K τ locus, then K is positive (negative otherwise). Thus we can draw the transitional dynamics as in Figure 5. 6

7

But now there is the additional complication that the K locus is moving around? What is the economic intuition for this loop? (With ε 0, we would have the interest rate monotonically converging from below to the steady-state interest rate). The real interest rate increases first and then comes back to the original level. Notes on Ngai and Pissarides (2007): Here, the empirical facts that we would like to fit are similar to the Kuznets facts: movement out of certain industries (e.g., agriculture), and towards others (e.g., services). There is an additional fact that Ngai and Pissarides mention: that the changes in the relative consumption of different types of goods is much more stark in nominal rather than real (where we take into account the movements in relative prices of different goods) terms. words, over time PsCs P ac a changes a lot more than Cs C a. Overview of the model: one industry produces capital goods and In other consumption goods; all others only produce different consumption goods. Industries have identical production functions, except for differential rates of productivity growth. Preferences are nested CES. There is a constant intertemporal elasticity of substitution and a different constant elasticity of substitution across products within periods. The definition of a balanced growth path here is somewhat different than in Kongsamut et al. It is not a requirement that the real interest rate is constant. Rather we seek conditions under which the aggregate ratios (e.g., k, c are constant). In fact, for Ngai and Pissarides y y the real interest rate will not be constant. The second part of the goal is to have differential growth rates of employment across industries, depending on industries TFP growth rates. Preferences are similar to Kongsamut et al, but without the non-homotheticity terms. U C(t) e ρt C(t)1 θ 1 dt, where 0 1 θ [ m ] ε ω i (c i ) ε 1 ε 1 ε i1 Here ε is the elasticity of substitution across products; θ is the inverse intertemporal elasticity of substitution. On the production side of the economy, there are m sectors. In these equations n i is the fraction of the labor force (which grows at rate υ 3 ) that is employed in industry i; the capital-labor ratio in industry i is k i. Each industry has nearly identical production functions: 3 In class, we had set υ 0. 8

c i F (n i k i, n i ) k α i n i, for all industries except for industry m. For industry m: c m + k + (δ + υ) k A m k α mn m Define i as the TFP growth rate in industry i. The final building block of the model are the labor market clearing conditions. The labor-market clearing condition and capitalmarket clearing conditions state that ni 1 ; ni k i k This is it for the set-up of the model. We will solve for the equilibrium allocation in a few steps. We will write out the firstorder conditions of the planner s problem, and then use these expressions to write out the evolution of consumption, employment, and output in each industry. We will then use these expressions to find conditions under which employment shares are changing over time (i.e., when there is structural change), and conditions under which the aggregate economy has a balanced growth path (where consumption and capital per worker grow at constant rates.) Finally, we will write out the long-run implications (for the labor, consumption, and output shares) of the balanced growth path). Step 1: Define p i as the price of good i. Since all goods have identical production functions, with identical factor intensities, the relative prices for any two goods will just be inversely related to their TFP terms. In particular, p i p m A m Consider, first the first-order conditions of the consumer that is choosing among the m products: The demand curves that follow from this maximization problem are ( ) 1 ε ( ) ε p i c i pi ωi p m c m p m ω m ( Am ) 1 ε ( ) ε ωi x i Here, x i is the consumption expenditure share of good i relative to that of the manufactured good. For future reference define Define x i and c and y as aggregate ω m 9

consumption and output (again relative to manufacturing): 4 c y m i1 m i1 m i1 m i1 p i c i p m p i F i p m A m F i m i1 A m k α i h i A m k α mh i A m k α The dynamic effi ciency condition states that: 5 θ ċ c + ( 1 θ ε 1 u cm Where does this equation come from? αa m km α 1 + (δ + ρ + υ) u cm ) Ẋ αa mkm α 1 + (δ + ρ + υ) Write out the Hamiltonian, as in the notes of Kongsamut et al. Take first order conditions; this expression comes from the [c m ] FOC, and plugging in λ at the appropriate point. λ Step 2: Expressions for consumption, employment, output, across industries 4 Use the equations at the beginning of "Step 2" to get from the third-to-last equation to the penultimate equation. 5 Side note: Take first-order conditions with respect to c m ( ) 1 θ u cm (ω m ) ε ε 1 1 θ c ε 1 c θ c m log (u cm ) Differentiate with respect to time: (ω m ) ε ε 1 1 θ 1 θ ε 1 c θ ( ε ε 1 ) (1 θ) log (ω m ) 1 θ log θ log c ε 1 u cm u cm θ ċ c + ( ) 1 θ Ẋ ε 1 10

From the k FOCs: p i p m F m K F i K F m N F i N A m A m ( k m ) α 1 k i ) α ( k m k i These equations imply k m k i k for all industries. What about the n s? For i m, c i k a i n i k a n i. Thus: n i k α c i k α A m c i p i p m 1 y c i p i p m c m y c i p i c m c m p m y x i c x i y The n s need to sum to 1 and x i 1, thus: n m c ( x m y + 1 c ) y From the definition of x i : ẋ i x i (1 ε) ( m i ) and Ẋ (1 ε) ( m ) Thus: ṅ i n i. c/y c/y + (1 ε) ( i) Since n i 1 (and thus ṅ m i m n i), we can solve for ṅ m ṅ m (1 ε) ( m ) c x m y c/y. ( 1 x ) m Step 3: Conditions for structural change There are two ways in which we can have employment shares changing over time. Either c is changing over time (so that employment in manufacturing is either shrinking or y growing over time), or c is constant but the employment shares are changing around for the y consumption sectors. From before, we know that ) ṅ i (ṗi ṅj (1 ε) ṗj (1 ε) ( ) n i n j p i p j i j So structural change requires either that c y is changing or that both ε 1 and i j for at least one pair of consumption industries. 11

Compare the above equation to: Ngai and Pissarides ague that ċi c i ċj c j that ε 1. ċ i c i ċj c j ε ( i j ) Step 4: Conditions for an aggregate balanced growth path We know that: changes a lot less than ṅi n i ṅj n j. This indicates k A m k α mn m c m (δ + υ) k k k A mk α 1 n m c m (δ + υ) k Substitute (n m 1 n i, and c m c/ x i ) ( ( k c k A mk α 1 x m y + 1 c )) c m y k A m k α 1 c ( y A mk α 1 1 x ) m A m k α 1 c k ( 1 1 A m k α 1 c (δ + υ) k Also from before, we have that: θ ċ c + ) c k 1 c k (δ + υ) 1 (δ + υ) ( ) 1 θ Ẋ ε 1 αa mkm α 1 + (δ + ρ + υ) θ ċ c (1 θ) ( m ) αa m k α 1 m + (δ + ρ + υ) θ ċ c αa m k α 1 m (δ + υ) (δ + ρ + υ) + (θ 1) ( m ) Thus, we need θ 1 for c and k to be growing at the same (constant) rate. the definition of a BGP is different from that in Kongsamut et al (2001) (which relied on a constant interest rate). With a unitary intertemporal elasticity of substitution, consumption is a constant fraction of the present value of wealth (it is independent of the interest rate). 6 6 Side Calculations. Consider a consumer who faces a constant real interest rate R, and define the present value of consumption as W. If the utility function is: u(c 0, c 1, c 2, c 3...) 12 t0 β t (c t ) σ 1 σ σ 1 σ So,

Step 5: Long-run evolution of employment, consumption, output shares. Now, finally, we are interested in the long-run evolution of employment and output. It will be useful to describe how average productivity, evolves over time. Remember that the definition of x i i. What we are interested in is how this average productivity growth changes over time. Taking derivatives of this expression, with respect to time, we have that: ẋ i x i d dt x i (ẋi i ) ẋ j... (1 ε) x i x i ( i ) 2 The first equality is an application of the quotient rule. The second equality applies (1 ε) ( i m ) and then some substitutions. What is important about this expression is that average productivity in the economy is monotonically decreasing (increasing) provided ε is less than (greater than) 1. When ε is smaller than 1, more and more of the economy s resources will be devoted to industries that have low productivity growth, pulling down the average over time. The only way this can be true, for all time periods, is for to approach min i from above. Notice that employment in all but one of the consumption industries will tend to 0 in the long run. Why is this? Remember that:. ṅ i c/y (ε 1) ( n i ) + i c/y The second term will go to 0 on a BGP (because c, y, and k all grow at the same rate). What about the first term? Suppose we are in the ε < 1 case. Then this term will be negative for all industries with faster than average productivity growth, and negative for all industries with slower than average productivity growth. We also know that is decreasing over time, heading in the limit to the min i, so that more and more industries have higher than average productivity growth, as time goes by. Hump-shaped employment is possible (was not in the Kongsamut et al. paper), because i could at first be smaller than and The first order conditions are: Manipulating the intertemporal budget constant: c t+1 β σ (1 + R) σ c t W c 0 (β σ (1 + R) 1 σ) k k0 c 0 1 β σ (1 + R) 1 σ c 0 W [1 β σ (1 + R) 1 σ] Thus, consumption is independent of R if σ 1. 13

then bigger than. Thus ṅi n i is negative for more and more industries, and is positive only for the industry with the minimum. In other words, n i lim n i 0 for all consumption industries that have productivity growth above the minimum. So the only thing to work out is the employment share of the least-productive consumption industry, and the employment share in manufacturing. Take the equations that we worked out before. Then define consumption and the capital stock in terms of effi ciency units: c e ca 1/(1 α) m and k e ka 1/(1 α) m : ċ e [ ake α 1 (δ + υ + ρ) ] m c e 1 α ( ) k e ke α m c e 1 α + δ + υ k e Manipulating these equations (looking for the BGP where ċ e k e 0 and using a to denote the BGP values): (ke) α 1 1 [ ] m α 1 α + δ + υ + ρ ( ) c e (ke) α m 1 α + δ + υ Solving this system equations gives up c e and k e. From here, we know how much consumption is occurring along the BGP, and how much labor must be allocated to produce this consumption good. Proposition 5: Side Calculations: n c 1 α ( m 1 α + δ + υ) m 1 α + δ + υ + ρ n m α ( m 1 α + δ + υ) m 1 α + δ + υ + ρ k e k e c e [ m + δ + υ + ρ 1 α α [ m 1 α + δ + υ + ρ α ] 1 α 1 ] [ α α 1 1 α ( m + δ + υ) ] 1 α m + δ + υ + ρ 1 α }{{} n c In the ε < 1 case, even though n i is equal to 0 for all but two sectors, consumption (and output) are still positive (and bounded away from 0) for every sector. The faster productivity growth outweighs the decline in employment shares for the faster-growing consumption 14

industries. In particular: F i F i i + α k i. + ṅi k i n i i + mα 1 α + (ε 1) ( i ) ε i + mα + (1 ε), 1 α which is positive for all sectors provided ε < 1. When ε > 1, is increasing over time, and some of the slower-growth consumption sectors will disappear (If α is small enough, and ε is large enough, (1 ε) + ε i will be negative). 15