Linear Contracts. Ram Singh. February 23, Department of Economics. Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, / 22

Similar documents
Relative Performance Evaluation

Moral Hazard: Characterization of SB

Moral Hazard in Teams

Moral Hazard. EC202 Lectures XV & XVI. Francesco Nava. February London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC202 Lectures XV & XVI Feb / 19

1 Moral Hazard: Multiple Agents 1.1 Moral Hazard in a Team

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

Moral Hazard: Hidden Action

LEN model. And, the agent is risk averse with utility function for wealth w and personal cost of input c (a), a {a L,a H }

Game Theory and Economics of Contracts Lecture 5 Static Single-agent Moral Hazard Model

This is designed for one 75-minute lecture using Games and Information. October 3, 2006

Some Notes on Moral Hazard

The Principal-Agent Problem

What happens when there are many agents? Threre are two problems:

Game Theory, Information, Incentives

Hidden information. Principal s payoff: π (e) w,

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard

A New Class of Non Existence Examples for the Moral Hazard Problem

1. Linear Incentive Schemes

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Moral Hazard: Part 2. April 16, 2018

Module 8: Multi-Agent Models of Moral Hazard

Moral Hazard. Felix Munoz-Garcia. Advanced Microeconomics II - Washington State University

Screening. Diego Moreno Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. Diego Moreno () Screening 1 / 1

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard

Contracts in informed-principal problems with moral hazard

Microeconomics. 3. Information Economics

Economics 385: Suggested Solutions 2

(a) Output only takes on two values, so the wage will also take on two values: z(0) = 0 0 z(0) 0. max s(d)z { d. n { z 1 0 (n + d) 2.

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming

Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018

Advanced Microeconomics

Technical Appendix to "Sequential Exporting"

Lectures on the Theory of Contracts and Organizations. Lars A. Stole

1.1 A Simple Model of Price Discrimination Full Information Benchmark: First-Best Outcome or Perfect Price

Lecture 5: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Teoria das organizações e contratos

Optimal Incentive Contract with Costly and Flexible Monitoring

What is Screening? Economics of Information and Contracts Screening: General Models. Monopolistic Screening: A More General Model.

Decision, Risk and Operations Working Papers Series

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

Lecture Notes on Solving Moral-Hazard Problems Using the Dantzig-Wolfe Algorithm

Choice under Uncertainty

5. Relational Contracts and Career Concerns

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments

Labor Economics, Lectures 5 and 6: Career Concerns and Multitasking

Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts

Module 16: Signaling

Two-Dimensional Comparison of Information Systems. in Principal-Agent Models

Economics 385: Homework 2

Collusion, Delegation and Supervision with Soft Information

Supplementary Material to Monopoly Insurance and Endogenous Information

Moral Hazard and Persistence

Almost essential: Consumption and Uncertainty Probability Distributions MICROECONOMICS

Knightian uncertainty and moral hazard

x ax 1 2 bx2 a bx =0 x = a b. Hence, a consumer s willingness-to-pay as a function of liters on sale, 1 2 a 2 2b, if l> a. (1)

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

1 Web Appendix: Equilibrium outcome under collusion (multiple types-multiple contracts)

Game Theory Review Questions

Microeconomics 2 Lecture notes

Other-Regarding Preferences in Organizational Hierarchies

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Problem Set 3 Answer Key The distribution was as follows: <

1. The General Linear-Quadratic Framework

Bounds on the Welfare Loss from Moral Hazard with Limited Liability

Choice under uncertainty

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Slides to accompany 13. Markets and Efficient Risk-Bearing: Examples and Extensions

Online Appendix for Dynamic Procurement under Uncertainty: Optimal Design and Implications for Incomplete Contracts

FINM6900 Finance Theory Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium for Multiple Risky Assets

Winter Lecture 10. Convexity and Concavity

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University

AJAE appendix for Risk rationing and wealth effects in credit markets: Theory and implications for agriculture development

Interbank Lending and Systemic Risk

Contract Theory - Intro. Roman Inderst

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

The Value of Symmetric Information in an Agency Model with Moral Hazard: The Ex Post Contracting Case

Advanced Economic Theory Lecture 9. Bilateral Asymmetric Information. Double Auction (Chatterjee and Samuelson, 1983).

Other-Regarding Preferences in Organizational Hierarchies

Fall 2017 Recitation 10 Notes

Existence and monotonicity of solutions to moral hazard problems

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Introduction to Game Theory: Simple Decisions Models

Consumer theory Topics in consumer theory. Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

1. The General Linear-Quadratic Framework

Asymmetric Information in Economic Policy. Noah Williams

Optimal contract under adverse selection in a moral hazard model with a risk averse agent

Adverse selection, signaling & screening

Perfect Competition in Markets with Adverse Selection

Final Exam (Solution) Economics 501b Microeconomic Theory

Lecture Slides - Part 1

Recitation 7: Uncertainty. Xincheng Qiu

Computing Solutions of Moral-Hazard Problems

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

Incentives and Nutrition for Rotten Kids: Intrahousehold Food Allocation in the Philippines

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Estimating AR/MA models

Regulation Under Asymmetric Information

Transcription:

Ram Singh Department of Economics February 23, 2015 Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 1 / 22

SB: Linear Contracts I Linear Contracts Assumptions: q(e, ɛ) = e + ɛ, where ɛ N(0, σ 2 ). Principal is risk-neutral. V (q, w) = q w Agent is risk-averse. u(w, e) = e r(w ψ(e)), r > 0, where ψ(e) is the (money) cost of effort e. r = u u > 0, i.e., CARA ψ(e) = 1 2 ce2, c > 0. Contract: w(q) = t + sq, where s > 0. w = Certainty equivalent of the reservation (outside) wage Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 2 / 22

SB: Linear Contracts II Linear Contracts Note u(w, e) is increasing in w and decreasing in e. The First Best: The first best is solution to max E(q w) e,t,s s.t. e r(w ψ(e)) = e r w, i.e., w ψ(e) = w, i.e., w = w + ψ(e). Therefore, the first best is solution to max E(e + ɛ w ψ(e)), i.e., e max e {e 1 2 ce2 }, since E(ɛ) = 0. Therefore, the first best effort level is given by the following foc Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 3 / 22

SB: Linear Contracts III ce = 1, i.e., e = 1 c. (1) When e contractible, the following contract can achieve the first best: w = w + 1 2c if e = 1 c ; w = otherwise. Second Best: e is not contractible but q is. The principal solves s.t. max E(q w) e,t,s E(u(w, e)) = E( e r(w ψ(e)) ) e r( w) = u( w) (IR) e = arg max E( e r(w ψ(ê)) ) ê (IC) Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 4 / 22

SB: Linear Contracts IV Note that r(w ψ(e)) = r(t + sq ψ(e)) = r(t + s(e + ɛ) ψ(e)), i.e., r(w ψ(e)) = r(t + se ψ(e)) rsɛ. Therefore, E( e r(w ψ(e)) ) = E(e r(t+se ψ(e)) rsɛ ), i.e. E( e r(w ψ(e)) ) = E(e r(t+se ψ(e)).e rsɛ ), i.e. E( e r(w ψ(e)) ) = e r(t+se ψ(e)) E(e rsɛ ). Since for a random variable x is such that x N(0, σ 2 x ), so Therefore, we have E(e γx ) = e γ2 σ 2 x 2. E( e r(w ψ(e)) ) = e r(t+se ψ(e)).e r 2 s 2 σ2 2, i.e., Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 5 / 22

SB: Linear Contracts V E( e r(w ψ(e)) ) = e r(t+se ψ(e))+r 2 s 2 σ2 2. (2) Remark Let s define From (2) and (3) e rŵ(e) = E( e r(w ψ(e)) ) (3) rŵ(e) = r(t + se ψ(e)) + r 2 s 2 σ2 2, i.e., ŵ(e) = t + se 1 }{{}}{{} 2 ce2 rs 2 σ2 }{{ 2 } certainty equivalent wage expected wage risk premium Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 6 / 22

SB: Linear Contracts VI Therefore, the agent will choose e to solve the foc for which is s ec = 0, i.e., max{ŵ(e) = r(t + se ψ(e)) r 2 s 2 σ2 ê 2 }. e SB = s c (4) Therefore, the Principal s problem can be written as s.t. max e,t,s E(q w), i.e., max E(e + ɛ (t + sq)), i.e., e,t,s max E(e + ɛ t s(e + ɛ)), i.e., e,t,s max(e t se) e,t,s Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 7 / 22

SB: Linear Contracts VII That is, ŵ(e) = t + se ψ(e) rs 2 σ2 2 w (IR) e = s c (IC) s.t. That is, max t,s { s c t s s c } t + s s c c 2 s 2 σ2 rs2 c2 2 = w max{ s s c s2 c + s2 σ2 + rs2 2c 2 s2 c } Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 8 / 22

SB: Linear Contracts VIII The foc w.r.t. s is s = 1 1 + rcσ 2 (5) Remark r > 0 s < 1, and s < 1 e SB < e. r = 0 s = 1, i.e., e SB = e. s 1 r, s 1 c and s 1 σ. Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 9 / 22

Linear Contracts: Sharecropping I Model: q = output; q = q(e, ɛ); q {q L, q H }, q L < q H. Monetary worth of q = q (assume price is 1) ɛ = a random variable, a noise term; e = effort level opted by the agent; e {0, 1}. ψ(0) = 0 and ψ(1) = ψ. p H = Pr(q = q H e = 1) is the probability of the realized output being q H ; and p L = Pr(q = q H e = 0). w = wage paid by the principal to the agent; w(.) = w(q). Let the wage contract w(q) = sq be linear; say, 0 s 1. Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 10 / 22

Linear Contracts: Sharecropping II Assume that both parties are risk-neutral. So Payoff functions are: Principal: V (x) = x, V > 0, V = 0; Agent: u(w, e) = u(w) ψ(e), where u > 0, u = 0. Optimum Linear Contract: Suppose the P wants to induce e = 1. Then, risk-neutral P will solve s.t. max{(1 s)[p H q H + (1 p H )q L ]} s s[p H q H + (1 p H )q L ] ψ 0 (6) s[p H q H + (1 p H )q L ] ψ s[p L q H + (1 p L )q L ] (7) Note s > 0 and (7) implies (6). Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 11 / 22

Linear Contracts: Sharecropping III Let p = p H p L and q = q 1 q 0. Exercise: Ignoring IR, show that IC binds the foc w.r.t. s is s SB = ψ p q Find out whether IR finds Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 12 / 22

Linear Contracts: Sharecropping IV Second Best: Suppose the P wants to induce e = 1. Then, risk-neutral P will solve max w L,w H {p H [q H w H ] + (1 p H )[q L w L ]} s.t. Exercise: p H w H + (1 p H )w L ψ 0 (8) p H w H + (1 p H )w L ψ p L w H + (1 p L )w L (9) The SB contract is superior to the sharecropping; that is linear contract is NOT Second Best Compared to the SB, the agent is better-off under sharecropping contract Find out whether IR finds Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 13 / 22

Sub-optimality of Linear Contracts I Suppose: q = q(e, ɛ) = e + ɛ The error term ɛ [ k, k], where 0 < k < For instance, assume ɛ has uniform distribution over [ k, k] Principal is risk-neutral. V (q, w) = q w Agent is risk-averse. u(w, e) = u(w) ψ(e), where u > 0, u < 0 and ψ(e), is the dis-utility of effort e; ψ (e) > 0, ψ (e) > 0 Let e FB = e Let w solve u(w ) = ψ(e ). Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 14 / 22

Sub-optimality of Linear Contracts II Note since q = q(e, ɛ) = e + ɛ, q [e k, e + k] if e = e. q < e k only if e < e. So, when the output has bounded support which depends on the effort, q can sever as a perfectly informative about e. Recall w solves u(w ) = ψ(e ). Now consider the following contract: { w w(q) =, if q [e k, e + k];, if q [e k, e + k. This contract ensures the FB outcome; it implements e as well, and provides full insurance to the risk-averse agent. Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 15 / 22

Sub-optimality of Linear Contracts I Now we consider unbounded support for the output. Mirrlees (1975, 1999 RES) showed that even with unbounded support, output can be sufficiently informative about effort. Assumptions: q(e, ɛ) = e + ɛ, where ɛ N(0, σ 2 ). f (q, e) = 1 σ 2π (q e) 2 exp 2σ 2 Principal is risk-neutral. V (q, w) = q w Agent is risk-averse. u(w, e) = u(w) ψ(e), u > 0, u < 0 where ψ(e), is the (money) cost of effort e; ψ (e) > 0, ψ (e) > 0. Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 16 / 22

Sub-optimality of Linear Contracts II Note that f e (q, e) = 1 exp (q e) 2 2πσ Therefore, for given effort level e, 2σ 2 f e (q, e) f (q, e) = q e σ 2 (q e) σ 2 q f e(q, e) f (q, e) (10) q f e(q, e) f (q, e) That is, for given e, the likelihood ratio fe(q,e) f (q,e) bounds. (11) is increasing in q, without Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 17 / 22

Sub-optimality of Linear Contracts III First-Best: The P solves s.t. max {E(q w)} e,w(q) E(u(w(q), e)) = u(w(q))f (q, e)dq ψ(e) ū = 0 Let (e, w ) be the solution. Clearly, in the FB the risk-averse agent is fully insured. The FB wage w is given by the binding IR, i.e., E(u(w, e )) = u(w )f (q, e)dq ψ(e ) = u(w ) ψ(e ) = 0, i.e., q u(w )f (q, e )dq + u(w )f (q, e )dq ψ(e ) = 0 (12) q Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 18 / 22

Sub-optimality of Linear Contracts IV In view of (11) for any M > 0, however large, q such that ( q < q)[ f e(q, e ) f (q, e ) < M], i.e., ( q < q)[f (q, e ) < 1 M f e(q, e )] (13) Now, consider the following contract { w, if q q; w(q) = K, if q < q. w(q) will induce the FB effort e if e = arg max{e(u(w(q), e)) = u(w(q))f (q, e)dq ψ(e)}, i.e., if K is such that Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 19 / 22

Sub-optimality of Linear Contracts V q e = arg max{ u(k )f (q, e)dq + q q u(k )f e (q, e )dq + q q u(w )f (q, e)dq ψ(e)}, i.e., u(w )f e (q, e )dq = ψ (e ), i.e., (14) q u(w )f e (q, e )dq ψ (e ) = u(k )f e (q, e )dq (15) Suppose, K in the above contract satisfies (14), i.e., (15). Under the contract the agent s payoff is q Now (14) (16) give us u(k )f (q, e )dq + q u(w )f (q, e )dq ψ(e ) (16) Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 20 / 22

Sub-optimality of Linear Contracts VI q [u(w ) u(k )]f (q, e )dq = I say (17) Note the above contract fails to meet IR only by the term in the LHS of (14), i.e., by I. But (17), in view of (13), implies l 1 M This in view of (15) gives l 1 M q [u(w ) u(k )]f e (q, e )dq u(w )f e (q, e )dq ψ (e ) But, RHS tends to zero as M. Therefore, the above contract almost satisfies IR for sufficiently large M. Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 21 / 22

Sub-optimality of Linear Contracts VII From (13), note that Therefore q as M. q implies the penalty captured by K increases FB can be approximated arbitrarily through sever punishment by the following contract { w + ɛ, if q q; w(q) = K, if q < q; q. The agent is almost fully insured As the size of punishment grows, the frequency of its use falls However, existence of unbounded punishment is critical to the above claims. References: Mirlees (1999 RES) and BD Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, 2015 22 / 22