Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Similar documents
Second Welfare Theorem

First Welfare Theorem

Competitive Equilibrium

Introduction to General Equilibrium

1 General Equilibrium

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

Uniqueness, Stability, and Gross Substitutes

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Advanced Microeconomics Problem Set 1

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

ANSWERS TO ODD NUMBERED EXERCISES IN CHAPTER 3

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Welfare Economics: Lecture 12

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

Notes on General Equilibrium

Microeconomics, Block I Part 2

Alp Simsek (MIT) Recitation Notes: 1. Gorman s Aggregation Th eorem2. Normative Representative November 9, Household Theorem / 16

Adding Production to the Theory

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

General Equilibrium and Welfare

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Lecture 7: General Equilibrium - Existence, Uniqueness, Stability

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

1 Second Welfare Theorem

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Applications I: consumer theory

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Equilibrium and Pareto Efficiency in an exchange economy

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

Public Economics Ben Heijdra Chapter 9: Introduction to Normative Public Economics

Lecture #3. General equilibrium

Regularity of competitive equilibria in a production economy with externalities

4 Lecture Applications

Monotone comparative statics Finite Data and GARP

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics

Pareto Efficiency (also called Pareto Optimality)

Advanced Microeconomics

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 12-4/22/10. Core is the most commonly used. The core is the set of all allocations such that no coalition (set of

Lecture Notes for January 8, 2009; part 2

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Market Failure: Externalities

3. THE EXCHANGE ECONOMY

General equilibrium with externalities and tradable licenses

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Answers Econ 805

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Foundations of Neoclassical Growth

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

General Equilibrium with Production


Introductory Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics

Market Equilibrium Price: Existence, Properties and Consequences

1. Pareto E cient Allocation and Social Welfare Maximization

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

Advanced Microeconomics

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad

Problem Set Suggested Answers

Noncooperative Games, Couplings Constraints, and Partial Effi ciency

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 8, 4/8/10

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions

Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ).

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

Walrasian Equilibrium in an exchange economy

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

Competitive Market Mechanisms as Social Choice Procedures

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Transcription:

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 19, November 7 Outline 1 Welfare Theorems in the differentiable case. 2 Aggregate excess demand and existence. 3 A competitive equilibirum is a fixed point.

Welfare Theorems in the Differentiable Case Question What is the relationship between the first order conditions that correspond to a competitive equilibrium and those that give Pareto optimality? Assumptions needed for differentiability Consumers Let X i = R L + and assume there exist u i (x) representing i that satisfy strong monotonicity and convexity for each i. Normalize things so that u i (0) = 0. Assume each u i (x) is twice continuously differentiable, with u i (x) 0 for any x, and also assume that u i (x) is quasi-concave. Producers Production sets are Y = { y R L : F (y) 0 }, where F (y) = 0 defines the transformation frontier. Assume each F (y) is convex, twice continuously differentiable, with F (y) 0 for any y, and also assume that F (0) 0.

Welfare Theorems in the Differentiable Case Remark Given these assumptions, Pareto effi ciency solves the planner s problem. An allocation is Pareto optimal if and only if it is a solution to the following: subect to max u 1 (x 11, x 21,..., x L1 ) (x,y ) R LI R LJ u i (x 1i, x 2i,..., x Li ) v i i = 2, 3,..., I x li i ω l + y l l = 1, 2,..., L F (y 1,..., y L ) 0 = 1, 2,..., J

Welfare and Equilibirum In the Differentiable Case (ˆx, ŷ) is Pareto optimal if and only if it solves the following max u 1 (x 1 ) (x,y ) R L(I +J) s.t. u i (x i ) v i F (y ) 0 i x li ω l + y l i = 2, 3,..., I = 1, 2,..., J l = 1, 2,..., L We can also write the maximization problems that must be solved by a competitive equilibrium. A competitive equilibrium with transfers x, y, p solves the following I + J optimization problems (with w i = p xi for all i): and max u i (x i ) s.t. p x i w i i = 2, 3,..., I x i 0 max y p y s.t. F (y ) 0 = 1, 2,..., J What is the connection between the first order conditions of these two optimization problems?

Welfare and Equilibrium In the Differentiable Case (x, y ) is Pareto optimal if and only if it solves the following max u 1 (x 1 ) (x,y ) R L(I +J) s.t. u i (x i ) ū i i = 2, 3,..., I F (y ) 0 = 1, 2,..., J I i=1 x li ω l + J =1 y l l = 1, 2,..., L The first order conditions for a Pareto optimum are: u i (x { i ) 0 x li : δ i µ x l li = 0 if x li > 0 for all i and l y l : µ l γ F (y ) y l = 0 for all and l where, to make the notation more compact, δ 1 = 1. With convexity assumptions, these conditions are also suffi cient.

Pareto Optimality In The Differentiable Case The first order conditions for a Pareto optimum are: u i (x { i ) 0 x li : δ i µ x l li = 0 if x li > 0 for all i and l y l : µ l γ F (y ) y l = 0 for all and l where, to make the notation more compact, δ 1 = 1. Interpret the multipliers as follows: µ l is the change in consumer 1 utility from a marginal increase in the aggregate endowment of good l (this the shadow price of good l). δ i is the change in consumer 1 utility from a marginal decrease in the utility of consumer i. γ is the marginal cost of tightening production constraint. F Thus γ y l is the marginal cost of increasing y l ; it must be equal to the marginal benefit of good l (measured in consumer 1 utility).

There are three types of effi ciency embedded in Pareto optimality (what?). Marginal Conditions for Pareto Optima At an interior solution (x li > 0) we can rewrite these first order conditions as the usual equalities between marginal rates of substitution and transformation. MRS between any two goods must be equal across any two consumers: u i u i x l i = u i u i x l i for all i, i and l, l MRT between any two goods must be equal across any two firms: F y l F y l = F y l F y l for all, and l, l MRS must be equal to MRT: u i u i x l i = F y l F y l for all i, and l, l

Equilibrium in the Differentiable Case A price equilibrium with transfers solves max u i (x i ) s.t. p x i w i i = 2, 3,..., I and max p y s.t. F (y ) 0 = 1,..., J x i 0 Let α i be the Lagrange multiplier associated with i s budget constraint. There are I of these. Let β be the Lagrange multiplier associated with s technology constraint. There are J of these. The first order necessary and suffi cient conditions for these problems yield: x li : ui α i pl { 0 = 0 if x li > 0 i, l y l : pl F β y l = 0, l When the non-negativity constraints bind, the consumers conditions imply p l p l = The firms conditions imply p l p l = These should look familiar. u i u i = x l i F y l F = y l u i u i x l i F y l F y l y for all i, i and l, l for all, and l, l

Welfare Theorems in the Differentiable Case An allocation is Pareto optimal if and only if it is a solution to: max u 1 (x 1 ) (x,y ) R L(I +J) s.t. u i (x i ) ū i i = 2, 3,..., I F (y ) 0 = 1, 2,..., J I i=1 x li ω l + J =1 y l l = 1, 2,..., L The first order conditions evaluated at an optimum are (with δ 1 = 1): x li : δ i u i µ l { 0 = 0 if x li > 0 i, l and y l : µ l γ F y l = 0, l A price equilibrium with transfers solves max u i (x i ) s.t. p x i w i i = 2, 3,..., I and max p y s.t. F (y ) 0 = 1,..., J x i 0 The first order necessary (and suffi cient) conditions evaluated at (x, y ) yield: { 0 x li : ui α i pl = 0 if x li > 0 i, l y l : pl F β y l = 0, l y Let µ l = p l, δ i = 1 α i, and γ = β Then, any solution to the first optimization problem solves the others.

Welfare Theorems in the Differentiable Case Summary In the case of a differentiable economy, we can use the first order conditions to prove the following. Every Pareto optimal allocation is a price equilibrium with transfers for some appropriately chosen price vector p and welfare transfers w (Second Welfare Theorem); Any allocation corresponding to a price equilibrium with transfers must be Pareto optimal (First Welfare Theorem). As an exercise, write these conclusions like formal theorems rather than observations. Note: the price of each good corresponds to its marginal value in the Pareto optimality problem.

Similar to the separating step in the proof of the Second Welfare Theorem: i=1 The Other Planner s Problem An equivalent maximization problem (also called the "Planner s problem") I F (y ) 0 = 1, 2,..., J max λ i u i (x i ) s.t. I (x,y ) RL(I +J) i=1 x li ω l + J =1 y l l = 1, 2,..., L The first order conditions for this problem are: x li : λ i u i ψ l Connect to the other planner s problem: µ l = ψ l λ 1, δ i = λi λ 1, and { 0 = 0 if x li > 0 i, l y l : ψ l η F y l = 0 γ = η λ 1 Conect to equilibrium:, l p l = ψ l, α i = 1 λ i, and β = η This yields a new interpretation of equilibrium prices at an interior optimum L l=1 λ i ui = L l=1 ψ l and thus λ i u i L l=1 λi u i = ψ l L l=1 ψ l for all l (r.h.s. same for all i). For any two consumers i and : u u i x x li L u i = l L u = p l L l=1 l=1 x l=1 p l l Prices reflect the common marginal utilities of consumption. for all l

Existence of A Competitive Equilibrium The Existence Problem We have theorems about the welfare properties of a competitive equilibrium, but no result stating that such a thing exist. Existence is always a crucial question (any statement is true of the empty set), and one that was solved only in the early 1950s. Is it hard to prove existence? What assumptions do we need? As it turns out, economists search for a proof for a long time hit a dead end. Until a mathematician came along that inspired them to look at the problem in a different way. To answer these questions, we study the conditions that characterize an equilibrium.

Existence of A Competitive Equilibrium: Equations and Unknowns For some price vector p, suppose we find Walrasian demand xi (p) for each consumer and supply y (p) for each firm. We find an equilibrium if we find a p that solves the following system of L equations: I J (x1i (p) ω 1i ) y1 (p) = 0 i=1 I (xli (p) ω Li ) i=1 =1... J yl (p) = 0 In general we may have correspondences, but ignore that for now. Since one of the equations is redundant, we can add a normalization (prices sum up to one, or price of one of the goods is equal to one). Counting equations and unknowns does not really work, but thinking about the left hand side of this system inspired ideas helpful to to find a way to prove that (under some conditions) an equilibrium exists. =1

Definition Excess Demand The market excess demand correspondence z : R L + R L is: I J z(p) = ω i ) where y i=1 (x i y (p) for each = 1,..., J, and xi xi (p) for each i = 1,..., I. =1 y For each good, this measures the difference between total demand and total supply. If Walrasian demand and firm s supply are single valued, aggregate excess demand is a function. Suppose p is an equilibrium price vector. Then L I J p z(p ) = pl (xli ω li ) l=1 i=1 yl =1 = 0 because at an equilibrium either the terms in square parenthesis are 0, or the corresponding price is equal to 0.

Walras Law Theorem (Walras Law) In an economy with locally non satisted preference p z (p) = 0 for all p Proof. The value of aggregate excess demand is zero for any price vector. For a fixed price vector p, take any y I p z (p) = p = i=1 }{{} = by l.n.s. J I =1 i=1 [x i ω i ] p I p ω i + i=1 θ i p y y (p) and xi J I =1 J =1 J p y =1 y = θ i p y i=1 x i (p) [p x i p ω i }{{} = 0 I i=1 θi =1 p ω i ] J =1 p y J =1 p y

Consequence of Walras Law Theorem (Walras Law) In an economy with locally non satisted preference p z (p) = 0 for all p The value of aggregate excess demand is zero for any price vector. If L 1 markets clear, the L-th market also clears If the equilibrium conditions are satisfied in all but one markets, they are also satisfied in the last market. The equilibrium[ conditions can be written as pl z I l (p ) = pl i=1 (x li ω li ) ] J =1 y l = 0 for each l. Why? Because either I i=1 (x li ω li ) J =1 y l = 0 or pl = 0. Suppose p l z l (p) = 0 for all goods but k. By Walras Law: L 0 = p l z l (p) = p l z l (p) + p k z k (p) = 0 + p k z k (p) l=1 l k

Excess Demand and Competitive Equilibirum A competitive equilibrium says: everyone maximizes (1. and 2.) and I J (xi ω i ) y 0 and pl = 0 if the inequality for good l is strict i=1 =1 One can re-state this condition using market excess demand: z (p ) 0 and p l = 0 if the inequality for good l is strict Hence, we have an equilibrium price vector if we find a price vector such that market excess demand is weakly negative, and prices are zero whenever market excess demand is strictly negative.

Monotonicity and Zero Prices If preferences are strongly monotone (this is more restrictive than local non satiation), then an equilibrium price vector must be strictly positive: if not, consumers would demand an infinite amount of any free good. With strong monotonicity, a price vector is an equilibrium if and only if it clears all markets Formally, a price vector p is an equilibrium if and only z l (p ) = 0 for all l, this is a system of L equations in L unknowns.

Equilibrium in an Edgeworth Box Assume strictly convex preferences: all excess demands are functions. Let the p 2 = 1, so we need only find p 1, and write market excess demand as z (p 1, 1) = (z 1 (p 1, 1), z 2 (p 1, 1)) By Walras Law, an equilibrium satisfies z 1 (p 1, 1) = 0 (the other market also clears). An equilibrium exists if for some price of good one z 1 (p 1, 1) = 0. z 1 (p 1 ) The aggregate excess demand function z 1 (p 1,1) A zero of the excess demand function is an equilibrium p 1 p * 1 In an Edgeworth Box Economy Showing an equilibrium exists is like showing that some function has a zero. Use the Intermediate Value Theorem: any continuous function over an interval that has negative and positive values must have (at least) one zero. With more than 2 goods we need a more general version of this idea.