Projektbereich A. of Behavioral Heterogeneity. Kurt Hildenbrand ) July 1998

Similar documents
Equal Distribution of Consumers Tastes and Perfect Behavioral Heterogeneity

Garrett: `Bernstein's analytic continuation of complex powers' 2 Let f be a polynomial in x 1 ; : : : ; x n with real coecients. For complex s, let f

2 Garrett: `A Good Spectral Theorem' 1. von Neumann algebras, density theorem The commutant of a subring S of a ring R is S 0 = fr 2 R : rs = sr; 8s 2

4.6 Montel's Theorem. Robert Oeckl CA NOTES 7 17/11/2009 1

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

1 Topology Definition of a topology Basis (Base) of a topology The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3

Author aliation Werner Hildenbrand Rheinische Friedrich-Wilhelms-Universitat Bonn Lennestrae 37 D{533 Bonn Germany Telefon (0228) Telefa (022

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 10, 4/15/10. F (ˆp, ω) =ẑ(ˆp) when the endowment is ω. : F (ˆp, ω) =0}

Vector Space Basics. 1 Abstract Vector Spaces. 1. (commutativity of vector addition) u + v = v + u. 2. (associativity of vector addition)

Linear Algebra (part 1) : Vector Spaces (by Evan Dummit, 2017, v. 1.07) 1.1 The Formal Denition of a Vector Space

The Law of Demand. Werner Hildenbrand. Department of Economics, University of Bonn Lennéstraße 37, Bonn, Germany

Topological vectorspaces

Rice University. Answer Key to Mid-Semester Examination Fall ECON 501: Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Part A

16 Chapter 3. Separation Properties, Principal Pivot Transforms, Classes... for all j 2 J is said to be a subcomplementary vector of variables for (3.

Congurations of periodic orbits for equations with delayed positive feedback

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han

On some properties of the dierence. spectrum. D. L. Salinger and J. D. Stegeman

A theorem on summable families in normed groups. Dedicated to the professors of mathematics. L. Berg, W. Engel, G. Pazderski, and H.- W. Stolle.

Pyramids and monomial blowing-ups

(1.) For any subset P S we denote by L(P ) the abelian group of integral relations between elements of P, i.e. L(P ) := ker Z P! span Z P S S : For ea

implies that if we fix a basis v of V and let M and M be the associated invertible symmetric matrices computing, and, then M = (L L)M and the

Appendix B Convex analysis

First Welfare Theorem

Konrad-Zuse-Zentrum für Informationstechnik Berlin Takustraße 7, D Berlin

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis

Stagnation proofness and individually monotonic bargaining solutions. Jaume García-Segarra Miguel Ginés-Vilar 2013 / 04

In particular, if A is a square matrix and λ is one of its eigenvalues, then we can find a non-zero column vector X with

Entrance Exam, Real Analysis September 1, 2017 Solve exactly 6 out of the 8 problems

INTRODUCTION TO NETS. limits to coincide, since it can be deduced: i.e. x

Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, February 21st, 2018

Exhaustible Resources and Economic Growth

Course 212: Academic Year Section 1: Metric Spaces

Minimum and maximum values *

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

Risk Aversion over Incomes and Risk Aversion over Commodities. By Juan E. Martinez-Legaz and John K.-H. Quah 1

PARAMETER IDENTIFICATION IN THE FREQUENCY DOMAIN. H.T. Banks and Yun Wang. Center for Research in Scientic Computation

Tijmen Daniëls Universiteit van Amsterdam. Abstract

using the Hamiltonian constellations from the packing theory, i.e., the optimal sphere packing points. However, in [11] it is shown that the upper bou

Vector fields Lecture 2

Contents. 2.1 Vectors in R n. Linear Algebra (part 2) : Vector Spaces (by Evan Dummit, 2017, v. 2.50) 2 Vector Spaces

MARKOV CHAINS: STATIONARY DISTRIBUTIONS AND FUNCTIONS ON STATE SPACES. Contents

Integral Jensen inequality

3.1 Basic properties of real numbers - continuation Inmum and supremum of a set of real numbers

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom

Economics Noncooperative Game Theory Lectures 3. October 15, 1997 Lecture 3

ON TRIVIAL GRADIENT YOUNG MEASURES BAISHENG YAN Abstract. We give a condition on a closed set K of real nm matrices which ensures that any W 1 p -grad

POLARS AND DUAL CONES

ON STATISTICAL INFERENCE UNDER ASYMMETRIC LOSS. Abstract. We introduce a wide class of asymmetric loss functions and show how to obtain

290 J.M. Carnicer, J.M. Pe~na basis (u 1 ; : : : ; u n ) consisting of minimally supported elements, yet also has a basis (v 1 ; : : : ; v n ) which f

Contractive metrics for scalar conservation laws

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad

The Skorokhod reflection problem for functions with discontinuities (contractive case)

Product differences and prices

Werner Romisch. Humboldt University Berlin. Abstract. Perturbations of convex chance constrained stochastic programs are considered the underlying

2 JOSE BURILLO It was proved by Thurston [2, Ch.8], using geometric methods, and by Gersten [3], using combinatorial methods, that the integral 3-dime

Topology. Xiaolong Han. Department of Mathematics, California State University, Northridge, CA 91330, USA address:

Coins with arbitrary weights. Abstract. Given a set of m coins out of a collection of coins of k unknown distinct weights, we wish to

Winter Lecture 10. Convexity and Concavity

IBM Almaden Research Center, 650 Harry Road, School of Mathematical Sciences, Tel Aviv University, TelAviv, Israel

Friedrich symmetric systems

Extracted from a working draft of Goldreich s FOUNDATIONS OF CRYPTOGRAPHY. See copyright notice.

Lifting to non-integral idempotents

P-adic Functions - Part 1

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

On the Existence of Price Equilibrium in Economies with Excess Demand Functions

THE FUNDAMENTAL GROUP OF NON-NEGATIVELY CURVED MANIFOLDS David Wraith The aim of this article is to oer a brief survey of an interesting, yet accessib

AN EXPLORATION OF THE METRIZABILITY OF TOPOLOGICAL SPACES

On Coarse Geometry and Coarse Embeddability

growth rates of perturbed time-varying linear systems, [14]. For this setup it is also necessary to study discrete-time systems with a transition map

The Great Wall of David Shin

2 RODNEY G. DOWNEY STEFFEN LEMPP Theorem. For any incomplete r.e. degree w, there is an incomplete r.e. degree a > w such that there is no r.e. degree

Quantum logics with given centres and variable state spaces Mirko Navara 1, Pavel Ptak 2 Abstract We ask which logics with a given centre allow for en

DS-GA 1002 Lecture notes 0 Fall Linear Algebra. These notes provide a review of basic concepts in linear algebra.

Generalized Convexity in Economics

Analysis on Graphs. Alexander Grigoryan Lecture Notes. University of Bielefeld, WS 2011/12

c Birkhauser Verlag, Basel 1997 GAFA Geometric And Functional Analysis

Tools from Lebesgue integration

106 CHAPTER 3. TOPOLOGY OF THE REAL LINE. 2. The set of limit points of a set S is denoted L (S)

Convergence of Non-Normalized Iterative

A Finite Element Method for an Ill-Posed Problem. Martin-Luther-Universitat, Fachbereich Mathematik/Informatik,Postfach 8, D Halle, Abstract

and are based on the precise formulation of the (vague) concept of closeness. Traditionally,

Midterm 1. Every element of the set of functions is continuous

Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets The Real Numbers The Cantor Set

Weak Formulation of Elliptic BVP s

A Graph Based Parsing Algorithm for Context-free Languages

08a. Operators on Hilbert spaces. 1. Boundedness, continuity, operator norms

Basic Proof Techniques

Part III. 10 Topological Space Basics. Topological Spaces

Immerse Metric Space Homework

GENERALIZED CONVEXITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS IN SCALAR AND VECTOR OPTIMIZATION


Notes on Integrable Functions and the Riesz Representation Theorem Math 8445, Winter 06, Professor J. Segert. f(x) = f + (x) + f (x).

LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

2 optimal prices the link is either underloaded or critically loaded; it is never overloaded. For the social welfare maximization problem we show that

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

An Alternative Proof of Primitivity of Indecomposable Nonnegative Matrices with a Positive Trace

Tangent spaces, normals and extrema

Math 541 Fall 2008 Connectivity Transition from Math 453/503 to Math 541 Ross E. Staffeldt-August 2008

Transcription:

Projektbereich A Discussion Paper No. A{580 On J.M. Grandmont's Modelling of Behavioral Heterogeneity by Kurt Hildenbrand ) July 1998 ) Kurt Hildenbrand, Sonderforschungsbereich 303, Universitat Bonn, Lennestrae 37, D- 53113 Bonn; e-mail: with@econ.uni-bonn.de. Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft, Sonderforschungsbereich 303 at the University of Bonn is gratefully acknowledged.

Abstract J.M. Grandmont claims in his paper "Transformations of the Commodity Space, Behavioral Heterogeneity, and the Aggregation Problem" (199) to model "behavioral heterogeneity". By a specic parametrization he denes a subset of all demand functions and assumes that the distribution of the parameters is getting more dispersed (increasing atness of the density function). This increasing dispersedness of the parameters is interpreted as "increasing heterogeneity" of the population of households described by the distribution of demand functions. But, due to the specic parametrization, increasing dispersedness of the parameters leads to an increasing concentration of the demand functions. Therefore, roughly speaking, Grandmont rather models increasing "behavioral similarity". JEL Classication System: D 11, D 30, D41, E 10 Keywords: Aggregate Demand, Aggregation, Behavioral Heterogeneity

1 Introduction Behavior of a consumer is described by his demand function, which associates with each price-income situation a demand vector. Given a probability measure on the set F of all demand functions, the mean demand of a population of consumers with identical income yet dierent demand functions is dened by f(p; w) = F f(p; w)d: One would tend to speak of \behavioral heterogeneity", if the support of the distribution contains \many dierent" demand functions and, furthermore, the distribution is not concentrated on a \small subset". Hence, in this view, a sequence ( n ) does not display increasing behavioral heterogeneity if with increasing n more and more weight is concentrated on a \small subset" of F. This is not a denition of \behavioral heterogeneity", yet it excludes situations that qualify as \behavioral heterogeneity". Since the space F of demand functions is an innite dimensional function space, it is dicult to give a precise meaning of a \small subset" in F.Toavoid this conceptional mathematical diculty many authors therefore consider the following set-up: let C IR n denote a nite dimensional parameter space and let T be a mapping of C in F. Thus, T denes a parametrization of demand functions. A probability measure on C then induces a probability measure on F that is dened as the image measure of under the mapping T. Obviously, a parameter distribution that is dispersed - a concept which is well dened since is a distribution on IR n - does not necessarily imply that the induced distribution on F models \behavioral heterogeneity". Indeed, whether a sequence ( n )onc, which is increasingly dispersed, models \increasing heterogeneity" in the above sense, depends entirely on the chosen parametrization T. It might well happen that the sequence ( n ) is increasingly dispersed yet the induced sequence ( n )onf is increasingly concentrated, that is to say, more and more weight isgiven to a very small subset of F. This is exactly what happens in Grandmont's model. The intention of this paper is to show, by using Grandmont's well-known model as an example, that every ad hoc parametrization of demand functions contains an inherent danger of misinterpretation. Easily interpretable assumptions on the parameter distribution might imply quite unintentional properties of the induced distribution of demand functions. This remark, of course, is obvious, yet, it seems that it has been overlooked in the literature on behavioral heterogeneity. 1

Grandmont's Model Behavior of a consumer is described by his demand function, which is f : IP l IP! IR l + with pf(p; w) =w and f(p; w) =f(p; w) for all p IP l ;w IP; IP where IP denotes the set of positivenumbers and l is the number of commodities. The set of all continuous demand functions is denoted by F and is endowed with the topology of uniform convergence on compact subsets. Grandmont gives the following two equivalent parametrizations, where denotes the componentwise product of two vectors, and exp() is applied componentwise. Given a xed demand function f, called the generating function 1. the parameter set is IP l and T (v)(p; w) :=v f(v p; w);v IP l. the parameter set is IR l and T ()(p; w) :=exp() f(exp() p; w); IR l : The demand functions T (v);t() are called the transformed functions and, to shorten the notation, are written as f v ;f - the latin, greek letter decides which transformation has to be used. The distribution on the -parameter space IR l is assumed to be given by a continuously dierentiable density function : Clearly, for each measure on IR l there is by the mapping exp() the corresponding image measure on IP l : To each such pair of measures (; ) belongs an image measure on F by the mappings T (v);t(): Whether a sequence ( n )or( n ) of measures on the parameter space IR l or IP l models increasing behavioral heterogeneity can only be decided by considering the sequence ( n )of measures on F: Grandmont's increasing atness condition is a condition on the sequence ( n ): His condition means increasing dispersedness of the parameter and can be interpreted as increasing heterogeneity of the -parameters. But this does not necessarily imply that also the sequence ( n ) of distributions of demand functions models \increasing behavioral heterogeneity". In fact, we will show that Grandmont's increasing atness condition implies increasing concentration of the measures n ; which can be interpreted as \increasing behavioral similarity". Grandmont considers a set A of \types" of consumers and therefore for each a A a generating demand function f(a; ; ) and a density function (a; ) getting at. Obviously, this more general set-up is not essential for the point to be made in the following two sections.

3 An Example In this section we choose an example where all calculations can be made explicit. We consider the case of commodities, the distribution of the -parameters is the -dimensional, uncorrelated, symmetric normal distribution, i.e., ( 1 ; )= 1 s exp +!, 1 ; s > 0; (1) s and the generating demand function f has the following properties and f is linear in income, i.e., f(p; w) = f(p; w); > 0 () 1 := p 1!0 p 1f 1 (p 1 ; 1; 1) and := p!0 p f(1;p ; 1) exist: (3) The normal distribution is chosen only to allow explicit calculations - in the next section we consider the general case. Clearly, Grandmont's increasing atness condition, i.e., then is equivalent with m( n ) := max h=1; IR j @n @ h ()jd,,,! n!1 0 s,!1: The assumption of linearity in income is restrictive, but simplies this example and will be dropped in the next section. The existence of the its in (3) means a mild restriction on the boundary behavior of f. The case inf p 1 f 1 (p 1 ; 1; 1) < sup p 1 f 1 (p 1 ; 1; 1) would mean p 1!0 p 1!0 that f 1 (p 1 ; 1; 1) would tend to innity ona\hysteric-like" path. Proposition 1: Assume (1), () and (3) and dene the two demand functions g 1 (p; w) := 1 ; 1,! 1 w and g (p; w) := 1,! ; w: p 1 p p 1 p Then, for every neighborhood U 1 of g 1 and U of g,respectively, with respect to the topology 1 of uniform convergence oncompact subsets, s!1 s(fjf U 1 [ U g)=1; 1 One could also use the topology of uniform convergence on compact subsets of the functionvalues and the derivative. 3

where s denotes the probability measure belonging to the density s : If U 1 \ U = ;, hence g 1 6= g, then s s (fjf U 1 g) =!1 s s (fjf U g)= 1!1 : Corollary 1: The image measures s, generated by the mapping 7! f, on the set F of all continuous demand functions, converge with respect to the weak topology to a probability measure 1 on F; given by 1 (fg 1 g)= 1 (fg g)= 1 if g 1 6= g 1 (fg 1 g)= 1 if g 1 = g : Corollary : The it mean demand function exists and is given by f 1 (p; w) := f (p; w) s ()d = 1 +(1, ) ; (1,! 1)+ w: s!1 IR p 1 p Corollary 3: If f is a CES-demand function, i.e., then f(p; w) = (a p, 1 ; (1, a) p, ) a p 1, 1 +(1, a) p 1, f 1 (p; w) = 8 >< >: w 0 <a<1 ; >0;! a (1, a) ; w if =1 p 1 p! 1 1 ; w if 6= 1: p 1 p First we discuss the above results, then we will show in Lemma 1 and the facts which lie behind. Then the proofs of Proposition 1 and its Corollaries will be straightforward. Since s () > 0 for all IR ;s IP, the support of s is equal to IR : Hence, the set of demand functions which inuence the integral R IR f (p; w) s ()d does not depend on s. Increasing atness of s, i.e. s!1, means that 4

the distribution of the -parameters becomes more dispersed, but, according to Corollary 1, the distribution of the demand functions f becomes more concentrated around the two (or one) Cobb-Douglas demand functions g 1 and g. Hence Conclusion: Increasing atness of, i.e. increasing dispersedness of the - parameters, induce increasing concentration of the demand functions f, i.e. increasing behavioral similarity. The situation becomes clearer, if one changes the parametrization. Note, enters in the mapping 7! f only as v = exp() IP l. Hence v 7! f v ;v IP l, is the \natural", or \intrinsic", parametrization. We will see that increasing dispersedness of the -parameters induces increasing concentration of the v-parameters, and this leads to increasing concentration of the considered demand functions. Using the transformation v = exp() we replace the -parameter space IR by the strictly positive orthant IP, the v-parameter space. The probability measure on IR and the transformation v = exp() generates a probability measure on IP. The connection of the two parameter spaces are illustrated in Figures 1 and. G 1 A 1 A 0 G A 1 G 1 log δ A 0 log(1- δ) 1 (1- δ ) A A G Figure 1: -space δ Figure : v-space The lines G 1 ;G correspond to the (open) rays G 0 1 ;G0 ; the areas A 1 (above G 1 ), A 0 (between G 1 and G );A (below G ) correspond to A 0 1 (\triangle" between the -axes and G 0 1), A 0 0 (\triangle" between G 0 1 and G 0 ), A 0 (\triangle" between G 0 and the 1-axes), and the hyperbel-like graph f(log ; log(1,)) j 0 < <1g corresponds to the open unit simplex. Dening the distance between the 1 5

two lines G 1 and G as ; one obtains = j log(), log(1, )j=p : One obtains (A 1 )bya45 anticlockwise rotation, i.e. A 1 f( 1 ; )j 1,g, and then integrating over. Hence =,! 1 (A 1 )= p exp, d s s =,1 becomes the strip and (A 0 );(A 1 ) when setting the interval of integration to [,;+]; [;+1); respectively. Since the integrant is the density of the one-dimensional normal distribution it follows the Lemma 1: Given 0 << 1, then s (A 0 1 )= s(a 1 )! 1 s (A 0 0 )= s(a 0 )! 0 s (A 0 )= s (A )! 1 9 >= >; for s!1: In other words, Lemma 1 states, that increasing atness of, i.e. increasing dispersedness of the -parameters, means that the v-parameters are getting more and more concentrated near the axes, in the sense that most v-vectors are contained in two \triangles" which have arbitrarily small chosen angle. Next we ask, what does the f v look like for v A 0 1 [ A 0 ; when A0 1 ;A0 are becoming small, i.e.! 0: Because we have assumed that f is linear in income, hence f v = f v ; >0, we have only to compute the its!0 We obtain the pointwise convergence f (;1,) and f (1,;) :!0 f (;1,) 1 (p; w) =f 1 (p 1 ; (1, )p ;w)=f 1 p 1 and, analogously, = w p 1 f (1,;) (p; w),,!!0 p 1 (1, )p f 1 p 1 (1, )p ; 1; 1 w p : (1, )p ; 1;!,,!!0 1 w p 1! w (1, )p 6

Obviously, this pointwise convergence is uniform, if p and w are contained in compact sets. Hence, we have shown Lemma : with g 1 (p; w) =!0 f (;1,) = g 1 and f 1,; = g!0 1w ; (1,! 1)w p 1 p and g (p; w) = (1,! )w ; w : p 1 p Now we can give the Proof of Proposition 1: Using f v = f v ; > 0; we get from Lemma that for every neighborhood U 1 of g 1 and U of g, respectively, there exists a >0 such that f v U 1 if v 1 =v < and f v U if v =v 1 <: With Lemma 1 follows the claimed convergence s!1 (fjf U 1 [ U g)=1: The remaining part of Proposition 1 is obvious in the case of a symmetric distribution. Q.E.D. Corollaries 1 and follow immediately from the proposition. To prove Corollary 3, one only has to compute the two it values 1 and. 4 The General Case In this section we do not assume a functional form of the density function ; and the generating demand function f can be any demand function. We shift all proofs to the end of this section. For IR with 0 <<1=l we dene the following subsets of the open unit simplex S := fv IR l j v 0; X v h =1g B := fv S j min v h <g I := fv S j min v h g: 7

Given a vector of direction r, i.e. P r h =1; the probability distribution on IR l ; generated by the density function, denes (according to the Theorem of Fubini) on the one-dimensional subspace hri a marginal measure with density. ' r ( )= hri? r( ; x 0 )dx 0 ; where r denotes the function written in the transformed coordinates and x 0 with respect to the subspaces hri and hri?, respectively. But note, without further arguments, we can not exclude the case that ' r ( )=1 for a nul-set of -values. Denote by @ @r := r grad() the partial derivative of in direction r. Lemma 3: (i) If m() := max h then m(; r) := j @ ()jd < 1 @ h @ @r () d p l m() (ii) If m(; r) := @ @r () d < 1 then jj' r jj := supf' r ()j IRg 1 m(; r): Grandmont's increasing atness condition means that m()! 0: What is actually used is jj' r jj! 0; a somewhat weaker property. Proposition : For every number with 0 < <1=l and every vector of direction r; which is orthogonal to the diagonal, i.e., P r h =0; (fv j v I ; >0g) p l j log jk' r k; where denotes the image measure of by the transformation v = exp(). If n isasequence of densities with k' r;n k!0 then for every 0 <<1=l n!1 n (fv j v I ;>0g) =0 n!1 n (fv j v B ; >0g) =1: 8

Hence, the integral R f v (p; w)d n (v) = R f (p; w)d n () depends more and more on those f v ; for which v= P v h gets to the boundary. How those f v are determined shows the following Proposition 3: For every compact subset K of IP l, there exists a >0, such that v p= K for all >0 ; v B ; p K: If f and g are two demand functions with f(p; w) =g(p; w) for all p= K, w>0, then f v (p; w) =g v (p; w) for all >0 ; v B ; p K; w>0: In other words, although the generating demand function is arbitrarily changed on a compact set of prices, for these prices the transformed demand function f v remains unchanged, if P v= v h is close enough to the boundary. On the other hand, according to Proposition, only those f v contribute substantially to the integral when a sequence of 's with increasing atness is considered. Roughly speaking, it is the boundary behavior of the generating demand function which determines the aggregate demand function. To assume that demand for a commodity tends to innity when its relative price tends to zero, is a useful technical assumption. But to base a theory on the speed, i.e. whether demand runs to innity slower, faster or with equal speed as the price runs to zero, is not acceptable. In fact, Grandmont \almost" assumes the boundary behavior of a Cobb-Douglas function (p. 18, Assumption (e)). If the generating demand function f is linear in income, then the relevant parameter distribution is the measure on the unit simplex, dened by (A) := (fv + 1jv A \ Sg) ;A :=fv IR l +j X v n =1g: If m( n )! 0; then the sequence ( n ) does not converge and the sequence ( n ) typically does not converge, but for the sequence ( n )wehave Proposition 4: If m( n )! 0 then for every neighborhood U of the edge-points of the simplex n (U) =1: Every subsequence of( n ) hasaconvergent subsequence whose it 1 fullls 1(f edge-points of g) =1: 9

Proof of Lemma 3: we obtain (i) by j @ @r j = Using @ @r = r grad and maxfp jr i jj P r i X @ j r h j @ h = X jr h j j @ @ h j X jrh! @ @ h j = X jrh j max h X jrh jj @ @ h j =1g = p l j @ @ h j p lm() : Now we prove (ii). If we would know that for every there are an ">0 and integrable functions g; g 1 : IR l,1! IR + with j r (; x 0 )jg(x 0 ) and @ r @r (; x0 ) g 1(x 0 ) for all [, "; + "] and x 0 IR l,1 then we would obtain (Dieudonne (1970), Th. 13.8.6) that ' r is continuously dierentiable and ' 0 ( @ r r )= @ ( ; x 0 )dx 0 : hri? Clearly, the needed condition is fullled if is a product measure with respect to the subspaces hri and hri? : But in general we have to be more explicit. Dene for every natural number k the function ( rk (; x 0 r (; x ):= 0 ) if x 0 [,k; k] l,1 0 otherwise Clearly, for rk the above stated condition is fullled, while the discontinuity of rk (;) on the boundary of the cube [,k; k] l,1 doesn't matter. Since R ' rk 1, there exist sequences n!,1 and n! +1 with ' rk ( n )! 0 and ' rk ( n )! 0 and therefore ' rk ( )=,1 '0 rk()d =, 1 ' 0 rk()d: Hence, 0= = 1 +1 ' 0 rk()d =,1,1 hri? @ k @ @r ()0 @r ()d + @ k @ @r ()0 @r ()d: @ rk @ (; x0 ) dx 0 @ k d = IR l @r ()d 10

Therefore we obtain m( k ;r) = = j@ k IR l @r ()jd @ k @ @r ()0 @r ()d, @ k @ @r ()0 @r ()d = @ k @ @r ()0 @r ()d: Hence ' rk ( ) = ' 0 rk()d,1 1,1 ' 0 rk ()0 ' 0 rk()d @r @ (;x 0 )0 @ rk @ (; x0 )dx 0 d m(; r) : Hence, we have shown ' rk ( ) m(; r) for all k and : Since rk ;k =1; ;::: ; is pointwise increasing, we obtain with the Theorem of Lebesque ' r ( ) = ' rk( m(; r) ) : k!1 Q.E.D. Proof of Proposition : The set A 0 := fvjv I ; > 0g is the image of A := flog v + 1 j v I ; IRg by the transformation v = exp(); and 1 denotes the vector with all components equal to one. Therefore we have toshow that (A ) p lj log jk' r k: Clearly, the set A remains unchanged if we replace P log v by the projection of log v on the hyperplane 1? log vh : Setting C := flog v, 1 j v I l g we have A = f + 1 j C ; IRg: Since C proj hri C hri? and 1 hri?,wehave A e A := f + 0 j proj hri C ; 0 hri? g: Hence (A ) ( A e )= ' r ()d proj <r>c k' r k length(proj hri C ): 11

For C the coordinate of proj hri with respect to the space hri is r. With X P log X X P vi log vh jrj = j r h (log v h, )j = j r h log v h, ( r h ) j l l = j X r h log v h j X jr h jj log v h j X jr h jjlog j p lj log j it follows length(proj hri C ) p lj log j. Hence, the rst part of Proposition is proved; the second part is an immediate consequence of the rst part. Q.E.D. Proof of Proposition 3: Since K is assumed to be a compact subset of IP l ; we have 0 < 1 := minfp h jp Kg and := maxfp h jp Kg < 1: We will show that every with 1 1, < (l, 1) has the required properties. For this we have to show that min(v p) h < 1 or max(v p) h > for all >0 ; v B ;pk: h h Since min(v p) h min v h max p h the assertion is proved, if by h luck < 1. Otherwise we have 1, and therefore we obtain max (v p) h max v h min p h 1, h l, 1 1 1 1, (l, 1) > : Q.E.D. Proof of Proposition 4: Denote V ij := fv Sjv i;v j g ; i 6= j; >0: With respect to the direction r dened by p r i =1= ; r j = p,1= ; r h =0 for h 6= i; j; the set V ij has a nite diameter. Hence by Lemma 3 n!1 n (V ij) =0; 1

and therefore n!1 n { [ i6=j V ij =1; where { denotes the complement. Obviously, for the given neighborhood U there exists a >0 such that { [ i6=j V ij U; which proves the rst part of Proposition 4. The second part is just an application of the weak topology of measures. 5 Discontinuity, Indeterminateness, Types of Consumers For the example, given in Section, we have shown in Corollary, that the it aggregate demand function f 1 exists. But, according to Corollary 3, the it function f 1 does not depend continuously on the generating demand function: with respect to the topology of uniform convergence on compact sets of the function values and the derivative, the CES-demand function f(; ; a; ) depends continuously on 0 < a <1, > 0, but the it function f 1 (; ) does not depend continuously on a and when a 6= 1 and = 1. This discontinuity isa consequence of the following two facts: 1. The topology of uniform convergence on compact subsets does not reect how fast a function runs to innity at the boundary. Therefore the function x, ;x IP; converges to the function x,1 ;x IP; for! 1: This means, that a CES-function converges to a Cobb-Douglas function if! 1.. According to Proposition 3, the aggregation process depends only on the boundary behavior of the generating function f. In general, the it aggregate demand function f 1 may not exist. First we consider an example. Let be ( n ) a sequence of densities on IR with m( n )! 0 and such that for even/odd n the second/fourth quadrant has full measure; such a sequence can be easily constructed. As the generating demand function choose f(p; w) = w p 1 ;! w p +(1, ) a p, 1 ; (1, a) p, a p 1, 1 +(1, a) p 1, with 0 <<1; a6= 1 ;6= 1. This function f fullls Grandmont's boundary condition (Assumption (e), p. 18). w 13

Now the sequence f n (p; w) := R f(p; w) n () d has two accumulation points, which are! 8 w w < ( w ; p (p; w) 7! ; +(1, ) 1 0) p 1 p : (0; w p ) : Although, there are two it functions, there is no contradiction to Grandmont's result (Theorem.3, p. 19), because the derivative of both it functions is a diagonal matrix with strictly negative diagonal. Now we consider the general case. For a sequence ( n ) of densities with m( n )! 0, the sequence of measures ( n )onir l does not converge; total mass vanishes to innity, i.e. n (A) = 0 for every bounded A. Also the image measures ( n ) on the v-parameter space IP l typically does not converge; some mass moves to the origin and some mass vanishes to innity. But the measures n on the unit simplex converge or have several accumulation points. If the generating demand function is linear in income, then n can be replaced by n, and hence, one expects one or several it functions. But these functions depend on the boundary behavior of the generating demand function and on the manner how total mass vanishes to innity by the measures n. Up to now, we have only considered one generating demand function f and density. Grandmont considers a set A of \types" of consumers and therefore for each a A a generating demand function f(a; ; ) and a density function (a; ) getting at. Does this help? No, it makes the story even worse! Because of Grandmont's independence assumption (p. 18, Assumption (d)), we can compute the overall aggregate demand function by rst integrating over the parameter with respect to a measure which does not depend on a, and then integrating over A; i.e. f (a; p; w)d da: aa IR l As we have seen, the inner integral depends, with increasing atness, more and more on the boundary behavior of f(a; ; ). If the family ff(a; ; ) j a Ag would display, \in some sense", behavioral heterogeneity, but with the same boundary behavior, then this heterogeneity would be lost by increasing atness of (a; ). Hence, increasing atness of the density can only destroy, but not generate behavioral heterogeneity. Nevertheless, Grandmont's model has been used by many scientic authors. 14

References Dieudonne, J. (1970). Treatise on Analysis, Vol.. New York and London: Academic Press. Grandmont, J.M. (199). Transformation of the Commodity Space, Behavioral Heterogeneity, and the Aggregation Problem. Journal of Economic Theory 57,1-35. 15