Using Economic Contexts to Advance in Mathematics

Similar documents
GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 1 September Q1. Are the preferences described below transitive? Strictly monotonic? Convex?

PRESENTATION OF MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS SYLLABUS FOR ECONOMICS HONOURS UNDER CBCS, UNIVERSITY OF CALCUTTA

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Notes on Consumer Theory

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Applications I: consumer theory

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Consumer theory Topics in consumer theory. Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

A Simple Computational Approach to the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

ARE202A, Fall 2005 CONTENTS. 1. Graphical Overview of Optimization Theory (cont) Separating Hyperplanes 1

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Multivariate calculus

Competitive Consumer Demand 1

First Welfare Theorem

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

1 Introduction. Erik J. Balder, Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht, Netherlands

Choice Theory. Matthieu de Lapparent

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

ECON 4117/5111 Mathematical Economics Fall 2005

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index.

PhD Qualifier Examination

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Chapter 1 Consumer Theory Part II

1. Suppose preferences are represented by the Cobb-Douglas utility function, u(x1,x2) = Ax 1 a x 2

Microeconomics II Lecture 4. Marshallian and Hicksian demands for goods with an endowment (Labour supply)

ARE211, Fall 2005 CONTENTS. 5. Characteristics of Functions Surjective, Injective and Bijective functions. 5.2.

OPTIMISATION 2007/8 EXAM PREPARATION GUIDELINES

Midterm Examination: Economics 210A October 2011

A Summary of Economic Methodology

STATIC LECTURE 4: CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION II - KUHN TUCKER THEORY

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008.

The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

ECON 5111 Mathematical Economics

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16

Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, February 21st, 2018

Monotone comparative statics Finite Data and GARP

University of California, Davis Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics ARE 252 Lecture Notes 2 Quirino Paris

Contents. Set Theory. Functions and its Applications CHAPTER 1 CHAPTER 2. Preface... (v)

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

Principles in Economics and Mathematics: the mathematical part

Mathematics for Economics and Finance

Review of Optimization Methods

Sample of Ph.D. Advisory Exam For MathFinance

Econ Slides from Lecture 14

OPTIMISATION /09 EXAM PREPARATION GUIDELINES

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

Rice University. Answer Key to Mid-Semester Examination Fall ECON 501: Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Part A

Constrained optimization.

4 Lecture Applications

Revealed Preferences and Utility Functions

Tvestlanka Karagyozova University of Connecticut

Midterm Exam, Econ 210A, Fall 2008

Microeconomic Theory I Midterm

Week 9: Topics in Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 2)

Mathematics for Economics and Finance. 2018, fall semester

Functions. Paul Schrimpf. October 9, UBC Economics 526. Functions. Paul Schrimpf. Definition and examples. Special types of functions

EE290O / IEOR 290 Lecture 05

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 3: Preferences and Choice. Today s Aims. The Story So Far. A Short Diversion: Proofs

STRUCTURE Of ECONOMICS A MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS

Discussion Papers in Economics

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm Suggested Solutions 2/8/ (a) The equation of the indifference curve is given by,

Mathematics for Economics and Finance

Microeconomic Theory I Midterm October 2017

How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

Lecture 1. Econ 2001: Introduction to Mathematical Methods (a.k.a. Math Camp) 2015 August 10

Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

Calculus Review Session. Rob Fetter Duke University Nicholas School of the Environment August 13, 2015

Adv. Micro Theory, ECON

Professor: Alan G. Isaac These notes are very rough. Suggestions welcome. Samuelson (1938, p.71) introduced revealed preference theory hoping

Foundations of Analysis. Joseph L. Taylor. University of Utah

MAT2342 : Introduction to Applied Linear Algebra Mike Newman, fall Projections. introduction

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

Trinity Area School District. Overarching Big Ideas, Enduring Understandings, and Essential Questions (These spiral throughout the entire curriculum.

Sometimes the domains X and Z will be the same, so this might be written:

Course Handouts ECON 4161/8001 MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Linear Programming. Larry Blume Cornell University, IHS Vienna and SFI. Summer 2016

Preferences and Utility

Introduction to Machine Learning Prof. Sudeshna Sarkar Department of Computer Science and Engineering Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur

Transcription:

Using Economic Contexts to Advance in Mathematics Erik Balder University of Utrecht, Netherlands DEE 2013 presentation, Exeter Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 1 / 17

Background Evidence shows basic mathematical skills to be important for students performance at intermediate micro and macro level This explains why undergraduates in economics take one or more courses of the type maths for economics ; minimally these cover some calculus (preferably also multivariate), linear algebra and probability However, research-oriented undergraduates could handle more than just these basic subjects, which make them miss out in particular on analytical skills (including the capacity to understand and produce proofs) that are essential for several graduate programmes This talk discusses some problems with the present structure for those students and suggests alternatives Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 2 / 17

Current problems with standard maths for economics 1. If taught by mathematicians: as a rule, both course material and teacher disregard most aspects of economics because of ignorance of or disinterest in economic contexts. Essentially, what they teach is maths for physical sciences 2. If taught by economists: all too direct (or even erroneous) adoption of material from mathematical textbooks. This invariably ignores some unique aspects of economic models (e.g. nonnegativity of variables like quantities or prices, concavity, monotonicity) Consequently, students can only partially explore economic contexts and then they usually do so uncritically, because some incisive mathematical insights and tools have not been taught E.g., in optimization/micro delicate boundary aspects are avoided by a priori exclusion of models with corner solutions (this explains absence of linear utility functions...), non-differentiability of Leontiev functions is side-stepped by jumping to a graphical plot, shut-down price is often not presented as a corner solution, etc. Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 3 / 17

So both educational arrangements 1. and 2. tend to produce a cookbook-cum-recipe approach to maths for economics, which leaves little room for the understanding of underlying reasoning or proofs While this may still be acceptable for generic majors, it represents a definite handicap for research-oriented undergraduates in economics, the target group of this talk To compound these problems: even if supplementary math courses (e.g., multivariate calculus, (geometric) linear algebra, optimization, convex analysis,...) are available, they often demand too much time from a senior undergraduate and lack of training in mathematical reasoning may be another obstacle In both arrangements it is not sufficiently realized by economics departments that mathematics, even in basic maths for economists courses, could be tweaked for greater educational benefit, in particular to those students Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 4 / 17

Some possible improvements Some simple possible improvements of basic maths for economics courses (non-traditional subjects from a math perspective): Already scalar optimization should spend time on optimization over intervals (preferably parametrized), so as to handle boundary optima ( corner solutions ) early on Parametrized problems (e.g. optimization or differential equations, etc.) should be practised at an early stage; e.g. think of influence of exogenous variables on endogenous ones (i.e. outcomes). This leads to student being able to distinguish different cases giving different outcomes. With parameter dependence shown by outcomes one can practice (monotonicity, limits...) and then match this with economic intuition Systems of inequalities can be just as important for economics as more standard systems of equalities (e.g. linear equalities); e.g. think of linear programming or mathematical finance models Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 5 / 17

maths-plus within economics : a catch-up course for research-oriented undergraduates Outline of a course maths-plus that better prepares undergraduate students of economics for graduate school Mathematical subjects treated (within coherent economic contexts): linear algebra, multivariate calculus and optimization, convex analysis Note: hardly any attention for stochastics, because of time constraints The course trains students both in calculations and in reasoning/proofs Coherent accounts within economics, interspersed with mathematical intermezzi contrast with maths for economics On many occasions student is invited to complete proofs, produce counterexamples, etc. Important role for self-testing for correctness of outcomes of computations this facilitates self-study Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 6 / 17

Examples of such self-testing Approximate correctness of calculated least squares estimate can be seen from data-plot; complete correctness can be seen by verifying normal equations Correctness of no-arbitrage price of a contingent claim can be checked by duality arguments with risk-neutral probabilities Correctness of calculated Marshallian demand function can be verified by (i) validity of Roy s identity, (ii) limit behaviour when prices or income go to infinity, (iii) validity of homogeneity, (iv) graphical solution methods, etc. Correctness of calculated Marshallian and Hicksian demand functions can be checked by verifying duality relationships Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 7 / 17

Outline of maths-plus within economics 1. Least squares method requires intermezzi with linear algebra (column space, linear independence, orthogonality, etc.) 2. Connect least squares method with orthogonal projections and best approximation (of a column space) 3. Optional: via least squares modification move to best approximation of convex cones; yields Farkas lemma, separation of convex sets, etc. To illustrate background of such connections, consider picture of best approximation of vector x by convex set S, with associated obtuse angle property: ˆx s S obtuse angle (0,0) x Figure: (x ˆx) (s ˆx) 0 FOR ALL s S Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 8 / 17

4. Optional: apply 3. to no-arbitrage pricing in simple mathematical finance model (finitely many states of nature) 5. Study of consumer demand: full study requires careful study of optimization, including some convex analysis and a bespoke Kuhn-Tucker theorem for utility maximization and expenditure minimization. It deals with hitherto overlooked (!) peculiar properties of utility functions: e.g., even the simple x 1 x 2 (Cobb-Douglas) or ( x 1 + x 2 ) 2 (CES) utility functions are non-differentiable in points where x 1 = 0 or x 2 = 0 A powerful associated optimization method 1 serves as generator of concrete Marshallian and Hicksian demand functions. This yields rather non-trivial calculations, whose outcomes can be subjected to the aforementioned self-testing, such as: 1 See reference at end of presentation Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 9 / 17

checking the validity of Roy s identity practices multivariate differentiation skills matching limit behaviour of demand with economic intuition when, say, prices or income go to infinity practices limit taking skills checking the homogeneity of demand function practices algebraic skills checking the validity of duality relationships or Slutsky s decomposition practices skills to substitute, differentiate and reason logically Comparable comments apply to production theory 6. For completeness, some attention could be given to other subjects (e.g. partial equilibrium computation), but their marginal contribution to practising the above-mentioned skills is small Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 10 / 17

Three examples of exercises To test the understanding of least squares: Exercise 1. Consider the constrained least squares problem minimize y Xθ 2 over all θ R d such that Aθ = 0. X design matrix (full column rank), matrix A Prove, by using Pythagoras theorem that the optimal solution is given by θ = (X T X) 1 X T y (X T X) 1 A T [A(X T X) 1 A T ] 1 A(X T X) 1 X T y after showing that A(X T X) 1 A T is invertible and that A θ = 0 Hint: imitate the Pythagoras-based proof of LSE in the main text, but do not substitute the longish expression on the right too soon. Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 11 / 17

Comments about solving Exercise 1: Proving invertibility imitates and extends the proof of invertibility of X T X that the student has digested As for the use of Pythagoras, next to finding the correct imitation, which requires insight in the nature of the least squares estimator, the student must prove the orthogonality needed to apply Pythagoras, i.e. (y X θ) X( θ θ) = 0 must be proven for every θ with Aθ = 0. This certainly requires some algebraic skills because of formula for θ is so involved. Of course this also produces the normal equations for this linear model A more challenging version of this exercise would ask the student to come up with the proper formula for θ (say by Lagrange s FONC) and then continue with the questions asked in the exercise Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 12 / 17

To test understanding of no-arbitrage pricing: Exercise 2. Consider a financial one-period model with state space Ω := {ω 1,ω 2,ω 3 } and three assets. The first asset (index = 0) is risk-less and carries interest r = 0. The second asset (index = 1) has value W 1 (t) = 4 at time t = 0 and values W 1 (t)(ω 1 ) = 8, W 1 (t)(ω 2 ) = 6 and W 1 (t)(ω 3 ) = 3 at time t = 1. For the third asset these values are W 2 (0) = 7 and (W 2 (ω 1 ), W 2 (ω 2 ), W 2 (ω 3 )) = (10, 8, a), where a R is a parameter. (i) Determine for every a R the (possibly empty) set of all risk neutral probability vectors (ii) Determine the set A of all a R for which an arbitrage opportunity exists (iii) Determine for every a A precisely one concrete (but still in terms of a of course) arbitrage opportunity that has value zero at t = 0 (iv) Determine for every a R the set of all replicable (= hedgeable) contingent claims (C 1, C 2, C 3 ) at t = 1. Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 13 / 17

Comments about solving Exercise 2: Here the student must understand the basics of the dual relationship between no-arbitrage and risk-free probability vectors Part (iii) requires the student to come up with a concrete solution of a system consisting of one linear equality and three linear inqualities Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 14 / 17

Exercise 3. Preferences of a consumer can be represented by u(x 1, x 2 ) = min( x 1, x 2 β) on R 2 +. Here β 0 is a parameter. (i) Determine for β = 2 the indifference set that contains the bundle (4, 6) and also the indifference set containing (9, 1). (ii) Use the graphical solution method to determine the formula (so do not just indicate points in a picture) of the Marshallian demand (x m 1 (p 1, p 2, y), x m 2 (p 1, p 2, y)) of the consumer for all values p 1, p 2, y > 0. (iii) Determine (x m 1 (p 1, p 2, y), x m 2 (p 1, p 2, y)) also entirely analytically, by following the utility maximization solution method. Check that your outcome is the same as in (ii). (iv) Test your outcome in (ii)-(iii) by computing its limit for β and by verifying if this limit behaviour matches your economic intuition. Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 15 / 17

Comments about solving Exercise 3: (i) helps the student on his/her way in part (ii) The desired bundle is graphically seen to be (1) the intersection of x 2 = x 1 +β and the budget line p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 = y if β y/p 2 and (2) the corner point (0, y/p 2 ) if β > y/p 2 In case (1) the student must see that he/she can employ the standard solution formula for solving quadratic equations after substituting z 1 := x 1. The ensuing algebra is not entirely trivial, as can be seen from the formulas for the outcome: x1 m = ( p 2 + 1 p 2 2p 1 2p 2 + 4p 1(y p 2 β)) 2, 1 x m 2 = p 2 2p 1 +β + 1 2p 1 p 2 2 + 4p 1(y p 2 β), As mentioned before, such heavily parametrized formulas open the way to several self-tests and questions. Here part (iii) is kept simple: for β only case (2) prevails, which has (0, y/p 2 ) as the optimal bundle. Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 16 / 17

For more information and critical evaluations of current literature: www.staff.science.uu.nl/~balde101/#edu For more information regarding footnote 1: www.staff.science.uu.nl/~balde101/giffenvol.pdf Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic contexts 5 September, 2013 17 / 17