The Race Between Technology and Human Capital

Similar documents
Technology, Skill and Long Run Growth

Technology, Skill and Long Run Growth

Technology, Skill and Long Run Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Technology, Skill and Long Run Growth

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Notes on Heterogeneity, Aggregation, and Market Wage Functions: An Empirical Model of Self-Selection in the Labor Market

The Aggregate Implications of Innovative Investment. September 2017

Firm Dynamics in the Neoclassical Growth Model

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

Macroeconomics Theory II

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Aggregate Implications of Innovation Policy

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

CFCM. Working Paper 15/17. Omar Licandro. Produced By:

Corporate Profits Tax and Innovative Investments

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

ENTRY, EXIT AND MISALLOCATION FRICTIONS JOB MARKET PAPER 1

Advanced Macroeconomics

Innovation by Entrants and Incumbents

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

Innovation by Entrants and Incumbents

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

The Slow Growth of New Plants: Learning about Demand?

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INNOVATION BY ENTRANTS AND INCUMBENTS. Daron Acemoglu Dan Vu Cao. Working Paper

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

Expanding Variety Models

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

1 The Basic RBC Model

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Economics 210B Due: September 16, Problem Set 10. s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0 given, lim. and

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Web Appendix for Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Not for Publication)

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Innovation, Knowledge Diffusion, and Selection

B Search and Rest Unemployment Fernando Alvarez and Robert Shimer Additional Appendixes not for Publication

Dynastic Altruism, Population Growth, and Economic Prosperity

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Aggregate Implications of Innovation Policy

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies:

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation

Endogenous information acquisition

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

On the Invariance of the Rate of Return to Convex Adjustment Costs

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

The Real Business Cycle Model

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 1

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Internation1al Trade

Economic Growth: Lectures 9 and 10, Endogenous Technological Change

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Knowledge licensing in a Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

Topic 8: Optimal Investment

Housing with overlapping generations

Do Financial Factors Drive Aggregate Productivity? Evidence from Indian Manufacturing Establishments

On-the-Job Search with Match-Specific Amenities

2008/73. On the Golden Rule of Capital Accumulation Under Endogenous Longevity. David DE LA CROIX Grégory PONTHIERE

The Impact of Trade on Organization and Productivity

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Advanced Macroeconomics

Internationa1 l Trade

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath

On the existence, efficiency and bubbles of a Ramsey equilibrium with endogenous labor supply and borrowing constraints

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Transcription:

The Race Between Technology and Human Capital Nancy L. Stokey University of Chicago May 29, 2014 Preliminary and incomplete Race-47 Abstract This paper develops a model in which heterogenous firms invest in R&D to improve technology, and heterogeneous workers invest in human capital to increase their earnings. Both investment technologies have stochastic components, and the balanced growth path has stationary, nondegenerate distributions of technology and human capital. Technology and human capital are complements in production, so the labor market produces assortative matching between firms and workers: firms with higher productivity employ higher quality workers and pay higher wages. Thus, wage differentials across firms have two sources: differences in firm productivity and differences in labor quality. I am grateful to Gadi Barlevy, Paco Buera, Jesse Perla, and participants in the M&M Development Workshop at the Chicago Fed for useful comments. 1

1. OVERVIEW This paper develops a model in which heterogenous firms invest in R&D to improve technology, and heterogeneous workers invest in human capital to increase their earnings. Both investment technologies have stochastic components, and the balanced growth path has stationary, nondegenerate distributions of technology and human capital. Technology and human capital are complements in production, so the labor market produces assortative matching between firms and workers: firms with higher productivity employ higher quality workers and pay higher wages. Thus, wage differentials across firms have two sources: differences in firm productivity and differences in labor quality. The heterogeneous firms produce intermediate goods, which are combined with a Dixit-Stiglitz aggregator to produce the single final good. Final goods are used for consumption and three kinds of investment. Incumbent firms invest to improve their productivity, and they die stochastically. Entering firms pay a fixed cost to obtain an initial technology. Workers invest to increase their human capital. One goal of the model is to examine the interplay between human accumulation and technological change as contributors to long-run growth. From an empirical point of view, the chicken-and-egg issue makes it difficult to distinguish a single engine of growth. A theoretical framework that builds inthesymbioticnatureofimprovements in the two factors may provide insights for assessing, in particular contexts, the role of each. A second goal is assess the sources of wage inequality. Empirically, it is not easy to distinguish the importance of technology and human capital differences in generating wage differentials across firms. A theoretical framework that incorporates complementarity between the two may be useful in assessing the importance of each. 2

The setup here builds on the model of technology growth across firms in Luttmer (QJE, 2007), incorporating an active investment decision as Atkeson and Burstein (JPE, 2010). On the human capital side, it develops a similar investment model. From a substantive point of view, the model provides a link between the literature on human capital-based growth, as in Alvarez, Buera and Lucas (2008, 2013), Lucas (1988, 2009), Perla and Tonetti (2014), Perla, Tonetti and Waugh (2014), and others, and the literature on technology-driven growth, as in Atkeson and Burstein (2010), Klette and Kortum (2004), Luttmer (2007), and others. The model also has implications for wage inequality across age cohorts of workers, as documented in Deaton and Paxson (1994), and for productivity dynamics in firms, as documented in Bailey et. al. (1992), Bartelsman and Doms (2000), Dunne Roberts and Samuelson (1989), and Hsieh and Klenow (2014). It is also related to the model of technology and wage inequality in Jovanovic (1998). To start, we will assume that both the average productivity of entering firms and the average initial human capital of new workers grow at a common rate We will look for a BGP where the cross-sectional distribution of productivities across firms and of human capital across workers are both lognormal, with constant variances. The entering productivities for new firms and workers can then be made endogenous. Specifically, at each date they will be draws from a distribution that depends on the current cross-sectional distribution. A. Variables Exogenous: population is exogenous and constant, with birth and death at rate ; exit rate for firms, 0; productivity of entering firms at date is lognormally distributed, with a fixed 3

variance and a mean that grows at the constant rate ln 0 + 2 ; human capital of entering workers at date is lognormally distributed, with fixed variance and a mean that grows at the constant rate ln 0 + 2 Individual decisions: productivity at age of incumbent firm that entered at date is a geometric Brownian motion, with fixed variance 2 The firm s investment decision is the choice of the drift human capital at age of worker who entered at date is a geometric Brownian motion, with fixed variance 2 The worker s investment decision is the choice of the drift Endogenous: the (constant) number of incumbent firms, is determined by free entry. is an aggregate variable, average productivity. It grows at rate. Its level depends the cross-sectional distribution of productivities = + is firm s relative productivity at age. OnaBGP, has a stationary cross-sectional distribution that depends on 2 2 Firm s labor demand and profits at date + depend on ( + ) = + is worker s relative human capital. On a BGP, has a stationary cross-sectional distribution that depends on 2 and 2 ( ) is the wage of a worker with relative human capital in an economy with average productivity. 4

2. THE STATIC MODEL In this section we solve for the static equilibrium, given and the distribution functions () () A. Final good technology The final good is produced by competitive firms using intermediate goods as inputs. All intermediates enter symmetrically into final good production, but demands for them differ if their prices differ. Specifically, intermediate producers are indexed by their productivity 0 which determines the price () for their good. Let () denote the density for across intermediate producers, and let be the number (mass) of firms. Each final good producer has the CRS technology Z = () () ( 1) ( 1) (1) where 1 is the substitution elasticity. The final goods sector takes the prices () as given. As usual, the price of the final good is Z = () () 1(1 ) 1 (2) and input demands are µ () () = all (3) B. Intermediate producers: choice of labor quality Intermediate producers use heterogeneous labor, differentiated by its human capital level as the only input. The output of a firm depends on the size and quality of its workforce, as well as its technology. In particular, if a firm with technology employs workers with human capital then its output is = ( ) 5

where ( ) isthecesfunction ( ) ( 1) +(1 ) ( 1) ( 1) (0 1) (4) The elasticity of substitution between technology and human capital is assumed to be less than unity, and is the relative weight on human capital. Firms could employ workers with different human capital levels, and in this case their outputs would simply be summed. In equilibrium firms never choose to do so, however, and for simplicity the notation is not introduced. Let () denote the wage function. For a firm with technology the cost of producing one unit of output with labor of quality is ()( ) Optimal labor quality () minimizes this expression. Conjecture that the wage function has the constant elasticity form () = 0 1 (0 1) (5) Then optimal labor quality is proportional to with a constant of proportionality that depends on () = (6) where Unit cost is then where µ 1 ( 1) 1 (7) ( ) ( ) = 1 0 (8) 0 0 ( 1) (9) For () as in (5), the cost minimization problem is concave if (and only if) (0 1) as assumed here. The quantity of labor hired is proportional to the target level of output, (; )= 0 1 (10) 6

Figure 1 displays isoquants for output and expenditure (total wage bill) in qualityquantity space, for the model parameters =05 =05 0 =1 =05 and the technology, output, and expenditure levels 1 = 05 2 =1 1 =05 2 =1 11 = 07071 12 =14142 21 =05 22 =1 The dashed curves are output isoquants for the technology level 1 and the broken curves are isoquants for 2 1 The four solid curves are expenditure isoquants, and the small circles indicate the four cost-minimizing input mixes. With fixed, a higher output level increases only the quantity of labor input. With fixed, a higher technology level increases labor quality and reduces quantity Note that cost minimization by firms implies positively assortative matching: firms with better technologies hire workers with more human capital. C. Intermediate goods: pricing problem Suppose the wage function has the conjecture form in (5), so unit cost is as in (8). Given the price for the finalgood,anintermediatefirm with productivity chooses its price ˆ() to maximize profits. As usual, the optimal price is a markup ( 1) over unit cost. Let 0 0 denote the scale for the real wage. Then (relative) price, quantity, labor input, and (real) profits for the intermediate firm involve various powers of ˆ() = ˆ () = 1 0 0 0 (11) 1 0 µ ˆ() ( 0 0 ) (12) 7

ˆ() = ˆ () 1 0 1 ( 0 0 ) 1 0 (13) ˆ() = 1 1 ˆ() ˆ () 1 ( 0 0 ) 1 ( 1) (14) where is output of the finalgood,andtheconstant 0 1 1 0 depends on The price ˆ() depends only on 0 and while the quantities ˆ () ˆ() and ˆ() also depend on Note that firms with higher have lower prices, higher sales, and higher profits. input, in (13), depends on the elasticity of the wage function. The effect of productivity on labor D. State variables To analyze investment by firms and households, it is convenient to exploit the fact that on a BGP the means of the s and s grow at the common, constant rate and to look at normalized variables. To this end, define average productivity E 1 ( 1) (15) and the relative values On a BGP grows at the constant rate and, have stationary distributions. Thus, aggregates depend on and individual choices on ( ) or( ) It is immediate from the definitions of and that E =1 (16) Use (11) in the price index (2) to find that the scale for the real wage is Z 0 0 = 1( 1) () 1( 1) ( 1) Conjecture that =1 which implies 0 0 () = 1( 1) 1 (17) 8

From (13), it also implies that the quantity of labor demanded is the same for all technologies. Hence aggregate clearing in the labor market ignoring heterogeneity across workers then requires = 1 ( 0 0 ()) 0 so output of the final good is () = 0 1( 1) (18) For firms, use (17) and (18) in (11)-(14) to write relative price, output, labor input, and (real) profits as () = 1( 1) 1 (19) ( ) = 0 () = ( ) = 0 1+1( 1) From (19), revenue and profits are proportional to Sincemoreproductivefirms employ higher quality workers, the wage paid, ( ) = 0 () () 1 1 = 1 0 1( 1) 1 ( ) 1 1 = 1 0 1( 1) ( ) is also proportional to Over time, average real wages grow at the rate with part of the growth coming from productivity growth, in 0 () andpartfromgrowthin average human capital, in = 3. INTERMEDIATE PRODUCERS: INVESTMENT Let denote the stochastic process for the productivity of incumbent firm that enters at date as function of its age It is a geometric Brownian motion, with 9

parameters ( ) 2 where the firm chooses the drift which is its investment decision, and the variance 2 is fixed. Since grows at the rate so the firm s relative productivity is also a geometric Brownian motion, with parameters ( ). 2 A. Investment by incumbents Consider a firm s choice of Recall from (19) that the (real) profit flow for a firm with state ( ) is proportional to The cost of investment is paid in goods and, we will assume, as in Atkeson and Burstein, that the cost is scaled by current profitability. Thus, the cost of investment for that firm, if it chooses drift is ( ) where the function is strictly increasing and strictly convex. Since there is no fixed cost of operating, there is no voluntary exit, and the firm operates until the exogenous exit shock hits. Let ( ) denotethevalueofthe firm as a function of the state. The HJB equation for the firm is ½ ( + ) 0 ( ) = max 1+1( 1) ( ) +( ) + 1 2 2 2 + It is straightforward to show that has the homogeneous form ( ) = so the HJB equation can be written as ( + ) = max The first-order condition for investment is ¾ 0 1+1( 1) ( ) (20) +( ) + 1 2 2 ( 1) + 0 ( )= (21) so is independent of ( ) and using in (20) we find that = 0 1+1( 1) ( ) ( + ) ( ) ( 1) 2 2 10

= 1 0 1+1( 1) ( ) (22) where + 1 ( + ) 1 2 ( 1) 2 (23) and we require so the firm has finite value. Since average productivity at incumbent firms could be growing faster than productivity at entrant firms. Nevertheless, incumbents are exiting at a sufficiently rapid rate so that aggregate growth is coming entirely from growth in entrant productivity. Use (22) in (21) to write the FOC for as 0 1+1( 1) = ( )+( ) 0 ( ) (24) Assume that the technology depreciates at a fixed rate 0 if there is no investment. The following assumption Inada conditions in insures that (24) has a unique soluion. Assumption X: The cost function ( ) is continuously differentiable, strictly increasing, and strictly convex. In addition, ( )=0and 0 ( )=0 where 0 and lim 0 ( )=+ where 0 Under Assumption X the RHS of (24) is a strictly increasing function of taking the value zero at = and diverging as An increase in 0 1+1( 1) the slope of the profit function, increases the solution as does anything that decreases Hence an increase in or a decrease in increases B. The distribution of relative productivity Since the investment choice is independent of ( ) it follows that is a geometric Brownian motion with parameters ( 2 ). Assume that the initial values 11

for each cohort of entrants are lognormally distributed, with a fixed variance 2 and a mean that grows at the constant rate over time. Thus, for the cohort of age at date + ln ( + + 2 2 2 + 2 ) all where is the mean of log productivity for entrants at =0 Since grows at the constant rate relative productivity = + for the cohort also has a lognormal distribution. Define =ln and 0 ln 0 and 1 2 2 where 0 must be determined. Then has a normal distribution that does not depend on where () Σ 2 () all () = 0 + (25) Σ 2 () = 2 + 2 The distribution of across firms of all ages is a mixture of normals. In particular, since the exit rate 0isfixed, the cohort of age gets weight all 0 and () = Z 0 Φ ; 0 + 2 + 2 (26) where Φ(; 2 ) is a normal cdf with parameters ( 2 ) Hence the mean of the mixed distribution is = Z () 1 = 0 + (27) The variance for the cohort of age grows like 2 Since the exit rate is exponential in, the variance of the mixed distribution is finite. 12

C. Entry Entry costs are also paid in goods. At date a potential entrant can invest units of goods and obtain a new product. Hence the entry condition is h i E[ ( 0 )] = E 0 with equality if firms enter. Entry is strictly positive on the BGP, and from (25), the distribution of relative productivity for entrants is constant. Hence the entry condition is h i = E 0 (28) 4. HOUSEHOLDS Individuals, who are finite-lived, are organized into infinitely-lived dynastic household, with each household comprising a representative cross-section of the population. Individual members of a dynasty pool their earnings, and the dynasty allocates family income to consumption and investment in human capital. There is a continuum of identical households of total mass one. A. Consumption Individual household members die at a constant rate and are replaced by an equal inflow of new members, so the size of each household, is constant. Each household member supplies one unit of labor inelastically, so is also aggregate labor supply. All household members share equally in consumption, and the household has the usual constant-elasticity preferences = Z 0 ˆ 1 1 ()1 13

where ˆ 0 is the pure rate of time preference and 1 0istheelasticityof intertemporal substitution. On the BGP, per capita consumption grows at the rate so the real interest rate is =ˆ + (29) Household income also grows at the rate so its PDV is finite if and only if The following restriction ensures that this is so. Assumption G: Assume ˆ (1 ) B. Investment in human capital New entrants into the workforce at date have initial human capitals 0 that are lognormally distributed with a mean that grows at the rate over time time. That is, ln 0 ( + ) 2 Each individuals then makes investments continuously over his lifetime to maximize the expected (net) discounted value of lifetime earnings. Theinvestmentprocessisliketheoneforfirms. Specifically, the individual chooses the drift for his human capital, and pays the associated cost. The variance 2 for the process is fixed. Recall the definition of relative human capital,. The pair of state variables ( ) is convenient for analyzing the individual s investment problem. Recall from (5) and (17) that the individual s (real) wage rate is proportional to Assume the cost of investment is scaled like the wage, so the cost for an individual with state ( ) whochoosesdrift is ( ) where the function is strictly increasing and strictly convex. Let ( ) denote the expected discounted value of earnings over the rest of this individual s life, if he follows an optimal investment plan. Since grows at the rate and is a geometric Brownian motion with parameters ( ) 2 the HJB 14

equation is ( + ) ( ) = max 1 0 1( 1) ( ) +( ) + 1 2 2 2 + ¾ Again, it is easy to show has the homogeneous form ( ) = so the HJBequationcanbewrittenas 1 ( + ) = max 1( 1) ( ) (30) 0 +( ) + 1 2 2 ( 1) + The FOC for optimal investment is 0 ( )= (31) so is independent of ( ) and using in (30) we find that where = = 1 1 0 1( 1) ( ) ( + ) ( ) ( 1) 2 2 1 0 1( 1) ( ) (32) + 1 ( + ) 1 2 ( 1) 2 (33) We require so expected net earnings are finite. Since wage growth for experienced workers could be faster than overall wage growth. Nevertheless, older workers are retiring at a sufficiently rapid rate so this effect is not contributing to aggregate wage growth. Use (32) in (31) to write the first order condition as 1 0 1( 1) = ( )+( ) 0 ( ) (34) 15

Assume human capital depreciates at a fixed rate 0, if there is no investment. As before, it is convenient to put Inada conditions on. Assumption H: The cost function ( ) is continuously differentiable, strictly increasing, and strictly convex. In addition, ( )=0and 0 ( )=0 where 0 and lim 0 ( )=+ where 0 Under Assumption H the RHS of (34) is a strictly increasing function of taking the value zero at = and diverging as Hence, given there is a unique value satisfying (34). An increase in 1 0 1( 1) the slope of the wage function, increases as does anything that decreases Hence an increase in or increases C. The distribution of relative human capital Since the investment choice is independent of ( ) the human capital of an individual born at date as function of his age is a geometric Brownian motion with parameters ( ). 2 The initial values for each cohort of newborns are lognormally distributed, with a fixed variance 2 and a mean that grows at the constant rate. Thus, ln ( + + 2 2 2 + ) 2 where is the mean of log human capital for new entrants to the workforce at =0 Since average productivity grows at the constant rate relative human capital = + also has a lognormal distribution. Define =ln and 0 ln 0 and 1 2 2 Then () Σ 2 () 16 all

where () = 0 + (35) Σ 2 () = 2 + 2 As with technology, the distribution of in the whole population is a mixture of normals. Since the exit rate is 0 () = Z 0 Φ ; 0 + 2 + 2 (36) where Φ is a normal cdf. The mixed distribution has mean and the variance is finite. = 0 + 1 (37) 5. THE BALANCED GROWTH PATH To complete the description of a BGP, we must impose market clearing for every level of human capital and determine the values for various endogenous constants. a. Market clearing for labor Proposition 1 shows that if the cdf s () and() are the mixtures of normals in (26) and (36), then a constant elasticity wage function clears the market for labor at every human capital level if =1 and the parameters of the stationary distributions conform in a certain sense. The resulting labor demand in (13) is constant across firms. Proposition 1: Suppose the distributions of relative technology and relative human capital (in logs), the cdf s () and() are the mixtures of normals in (26) and (36), and let be the mass of firms and the size (mass) of the workforce. 17

Then the wage function in (5) clears the market for every kind of labor if and =1 (38) 0 = 0 +ln = (39) where is defined in (7). 2 = 2 2 = 2 Proof: For the wage function in (5), a firm with relative productivity chooses labor with relative human capital () = +ln Asshowninsection2D,for =1 every firm demands the same quantity of labor, which in equilibrium must be Hence market clearing for all levels for human capital requires or ( +ln )= Z () all ( +ln )= () all (40) Use (39) and the change of variable = to write as ( +ln )= Z so the required condition holds. 0 Φ ; 0 + 2 + 2 all b. Levels With =1 the constants and 0 in (7) and (9) are determined. The interest rate in (29) depends on the exogenous parameters ˆ and It remains to determine 0 and 18

Under Assumption X, the FOC (24) has a unique solution () with lim 0 () = lim () = and 0 () = 2 1 0 2+1( 1) 1 () 00 ( ()) 0 (41) The normalized value of the firm in (22) then depends on directly and also indirectly, through Call this value () () 1 0 Use the envelop theorem to find that 0 () 2 1 1 ( 2)( 1) [ ()] (42) () 0 2+1( 1) () Recall from (16) that 1 = E =E and use (26) to find that E is increasing in both 0 and () For any let 0 () denotethevalueforwhich E =1 (This can be thought of as determining 0 )Since () is a decreasing function, 0 () is increasing. Moreover, since () takes values in a bounded set, so does 0 () Use (), 0 () and the expressions for (0) and Σ 2 (0) in (25) to write the free entry condition (28) as = ()exp 0 ()+ 1 2 2 2 (43) For 2 the term ( 2)( 1) in diverges to + as 0 and converges to 0 as + while the other terms in (43) have finite ranges. Hence there is at least one solution. Moreover, for 2 () is a decreasing function. Therefore, unless 0 () is strongly increasing over some range, the solution is unique. Given the values for, 0 and are determined. Then use (39) to determine and The definitions of and imply that = + + 1 2 2 19

or 1 ( ) = 1 ( ) (44) Thus, the requirement ( ) puts bounds on the allowable range for Assuming the required condition holds, the cost function must be reverse engineered so that the FOC (34) holds. The normalized value of the wage stream is then given by (32). Clearing in the final goods market determines the level of consumption, as a residual: output minus investment by incumbent firms, entrants, and workers, () = () () () () (45) = 0 1( 1) ( )E ( )E () 0 () all Hence consumption grows like at rate Uniqueness Suppose = = 0 and both cost functions are quadratic: ( )= 0 2 2 and ( )= 0 2 2 Then the FOC for in (24) requires µ 0 1+1( 1) = + 1 2 0 or 1 2 2 + 0 0 1+1( 1) =0 The roots of this quadratic are real and of opposite sign, q () = ± 2 +2 0 1+1( 1) 0 The negative root violates the lower bound on so only the positive root is of interest. That root is less than if q 2 2 +2 0 1+1( 1) 0 20

or 2 2 3 0 1+1( 1) which holds if 0 is large enough. [What can be said about 0 ()?] 0 Use () and the quadratic cost function in (43) to determine whichinturn gives () Use (44) to determined andthendeterminethecoefficient 0 for the second quadratic from the FOC (34), 1 2 2 0 +( ) 0 = 1 0 1( 1) or and 0 = 1 0 1( 1) ( 2) µ = 1 0 1( 1) 1 2 = 1 0 1( 1) 2 [To be completed.] 6. EFFICIENCY A. Allocation of labor The allocation of labor at each date is efficient. Since the labor market is perfectly competitive and labor is supplied inelastically, this conclusion is not surprising. Each producer has an incentive to reduce output, to exploit his market power, tending to reduce labor demand and wages. But since labor is inelastically supplied, wages fall enough to ensure full employment. 21

To see that allocation of labor across producers is efficient, firstnotethatbecause better technologies and higher human capital are complements in production, efficiency clearly requires assortative matching. Given the distribution functions ()and() for relative productivity and human capital, and the total masses and of labor and firms, function allocating () units of labor to firm leads to the mapping ˆ( ) if Z ()() = (()) all or ()() =(()) 0 () all (46) An efficient allocation of labor chooses () or equivalently 0 () to maximize total output Thus, it solves the calculus of variations problem Z [(())()] () s.t. (46), max {()} or, since and are fixed, Z Z max [(())(()) 0 ()] (()) 1 max Ω [ () 0 ()] The usual Euler equation Ω = here implies µ ( 0 ) () 1 + 0 Ω 0 all = h () () 1 ( 0 ) 1i or or µ µ 0 + 0 = 0 + µ + 0 0 0 +(1 ) 00 00 + 0 + 0 0 0 = 1 all (47) 22

The resource constraint (46) for the labor market implies 0 () () + 0 = 0 0 + 00 0 all Usethisfactin(47)toget 0 () () = 1 1 0 all (48) Consider linear allocation functions, () = Since ( 1) ( 1) = 1 (1 ) the term on the right in (48) vanishes for the value = defined in (7), and (48) holds for any uniform labor allocation, () = The required level is determined by (46), which agrees with (19). Note that normalized output is = () = = all " Z # ( ) 1 () = 1 0 E 1 = 0 1( 1) (49) where the last line uses (16). B. Investment To ask whether investment is efficient, consider a joint perturbation to investments in technology and human capital that preserves the constant elasticity wage function. Under such a perturbation (40) must hold at every date. To this end, we will fix a small perturbation 0to for all firms at all dates, and choose the perturbations to human capital so that (40) holds. 23

Consider the perturbed distributions e (; ) = f(; ) = Z 0 Z 0 Φ ; 0 + + (; ) 2 + 2 Φ ; 0 + + (; ) 2 + 2 all where (; ) and (; ) denote the cumulative perturbations to growth for the cohorts of firms of age and workers with experience both at date Use (39) and the change of variable = to write e as Z µ µ e (; ) = Φ ; 0 ln + + ; 2 + 2 0 Then e ( ln ; ) = (; f ), all if µ (; ) = ; all 0 (50) Since the perturbation to technology growth is constant across firms and over time, the cumulative perturbation for a firm of age at date is and (50) holds if and only if ( ) = min { } (; ) = min { } all 0 (51) Since is the integral of flow perturbations, clearly (51) holds for =0or =0 Suppose 1 which is the empirically relevant case. Then the required (flow) perturbations to human capital growth are (; ) = if otherwise. At any date sufficiently old workers, those with age get the perturbation = while all others get the perturbation = If 1 reverse the roles of and in the argument. 24 (52)

In the long run the two perturbations are proportional, with a ratio equal to the ratio of the exit rates, If 1 the perturbation to human capital growth must initially be larger for older cohorts, to compensate for the fact that the inflow of new labor is slower than the inflow of new firms. Note that the perturbation does not affect the long run growth rate What is the effect of these changes on output and investment costs? Since are unchanged, and the labor allocation across technologies still satisfies = we can use (18) to find that the change in output is () = () () () where is the change in On the perturbed path, the total cost of investment in technology at is e () =( + )() where we have used the fact that (16) continues to hold on the perturbed path. Hence the increase is 0 ( ) () ( ) + () all Similarly, the increases in the cost of investment in human capital and entry costs are () 0 ( ) ( ) () () + 1 all + () where the first line uses the fact that is the fraction of the workforce that gets the larger perturbation at date. Hence the net gain from the perturbation is Z ½ [ () () () ()] () 0 () µ 0 ( ) + 0 ( ) + 1 ¾ ( ) ( ) 25 (53)

Recall from (45) that the term in brackets in the first line of (53) is simply consumption, () = 0 0 Hence the first line in (53) is Recall that on the original BGP 1 = 0 0 Z 0 [()] =E () ( ) (54) Let e () denote the perturbed technology and let e() = e ()() denotetheperturbed technology relative to () Then on the perturbed path h i ½ h i ¾ n e() =E e() =E [e()] o () all 0 Hence on the perturbed path " # () e = () Z 0 n E [e( )] o all where the expression on the right uses the linearity of the expectation operator. For each age cohort and each date e( ) is lognormally distributed, with parameters [ ()+ min { } Σ 2 ()] Recall that for a lognormally distributed random variable with parameters ( 2 ) E =exp{ + 2 2 2} Hence E[e( )] = exp ()+ min { } + 2 Σ 2 ()2 = E[()] min{} The integral above is then " # () e = () Z E[()] 0 Z + E[()] all Hence 26

For the second line in (53), recall that aggregate investments in the two kinds of capital are () = ( )()E and recall from (16), (21) and (31) that () = ( )()E all E =1 E = 0 ( )= 0 ( )= Since () grows at the rate use these facts and (52) to find that the second term in (53) is Z µ 2 0 ½ ( ) + + 1 ¾ 0 = ½ 0 + + µ 1 ¾ + = 0 + + (55) + Hence the perturbation is welfare improving if and only it Z 0 ( ) ( ) + + + 0 The term on the right is the annualized income flow from technology and human capital, multiplied by =1 1, one minus the markup. If the stated inequality holds, a positive perturbation raises welfare, and if the inequality runs the other way, a negative perturbation raises welfare. Investment is efficient if and only if the two terms are equal, and there doesn t seem to be any reason why they would be. [Add a numerical example.] 7. CONCLUSIONS [To be completed] 27

REFERENCES [1] Alvarez, Fernando E., Francisco J. Buera, and Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 2013. Idea flows, economic growth, and trade, NBER Working Paper 19667, National Bureau of Economic Research, November. [2] Alvarez, Fernando E., Francisco J. Buera, and Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 2008. Models of idea flows, NBER Working Paper 14135, National Bureau of Economic Research, June. [3] Atkeson, Andrew, and Ariel Burstein. 2010. Innovation, firm dynamics, and international trade, Journal of Political Economy, 118(June): 433-484. [4] Bailey, Martin Neil, Charles Hulten, David Campbell, Timothy Bresnahan, and Richard Caves. 1992. Productivity dynamics in manufacturing plants, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Microeconomics, 187-267. [5] Bartelsman, Eric J. and Mark Doms. 2000. Understanding productivity: lessons from longitudinal microdata, Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3): 569-594. [6] Deaton, Angus, and Christina Paxson. 1994. Intertemporal choice and inequality, Journal of Political Economy, 102(3): 437-467. [7] Dunne, Timothy, Mark J. Roberts, and Larry Samuelson. 1989. The growth and failure of U.S. manufacturing plants, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(4): 671-698. [8] Foster, Lucia, John Haltiwanger, and Chad Syverson. 2008. Reallocation, firm turnover, and efficiency: selection on productivity or profitability? American Economic Review, 98(1): 394-425. 28

[9] Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence F. Katz. 2008. The Race between Education and Technology, Harvard University Press. [10] Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Peter J. Klenow. 2014. The life cycle of plants in India and Mexico, Quarterly Journal of Economics, forthcoming. [11] Jovanovic, Boyan. 1998. Vintage capital and inequality. Review of Economic Dynamics, 1: 497-530. [12] Klette, Tor Jakob, and Samuel Kortum. 2004. Innovating firms and aggregate innovation, Journal of Political Economy, 112: 986-1018. [13] Lagakos, David, Benjamin Moll, Tommaso Porzio, and Nancy Qian. 2013. Experience matters: human capital and development accounting, working paper. [14] Lucas, Robert E. 1988. On the mechanics of economic development, Journal of Monetary Economics, 22: 3-42. [15] Lucas, Robert E. 2009. Ideas and growth, Econometrica, 76: 1-19. [16] Lucas, Robert E., and Benjamin Moll. 2011. Knowledge growth and the allocation of time, NBER Working Paper 17495, National Bureau of Economic Research. [17] Luttmer, Erzo J.G. 2007. Selection, growth and the size distribution of firms, Quarterly Journal of Economics 122(3) 1103 44. [18] Neal, Derek, and Sherwin Rosen. 2000. Theories of the distribution of earnings, Chapter 7. Handbook of Income Distribution, ed. by A.B. Atkinson and F. Bourguignon, Elsevier Science. [19] Perla, Jesse, and Chris Tonetti. 2014. Equilibrium imitation and growth, Journal of Political Economy, 122(1): 52-76. 29

[20] Perla, Jesse, Chris Tonetti, and Michael Waugh. 2014. Equilibrium technology diffusion, trade, and growth, working paper, U. of British Columbia. [21] Rossi-Hansberg, Esteban, and Mark L. J. Wright. 2007. Establishment size dynamics in the aggregate economy, American Economic Review 97(5): 1639-1666. 30

2.2 output and expenditure isoquants, = 0.5, = 0.5 2 o X 1 = 0.5 1.8 X 2 = 1 1.6 quantity, n 1.4 1.2 Y 2 = 1 1 o o 0.8 0.6 Y 1 = 0.5 0.4 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 quality, h o