Formelsammlung zu Wirtschaftstheorie IV

Similar documents
IS-LM Analysis. Math 202. Brian D. Fitzpatrick. Duke University. February 14, 2018 MATH

The Keynesian Model of Income Determination (revised)

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Pasinetti s notion of a unit of vertically integrated productive capacity : a comment

Impact Analysis of Economic Linkages of South Korea with North Korea Using a CGE Model (draft version)

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

A Summary of Economic Methodology

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

BRITISH VIRGIN ISLANDS SECTORAL GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT MARKET PRICES (current prices) (US$M)

Chapter 4 AD AS. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos. Computational Economics: a concise introduction

Matrices 2. Slide for MA1203 Business Mathematics II Week 4

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

1-6-1, Nishiwaseda, Shinjuku-ku, Tokyo JAPAN

Does Pleasing Export-Oriented Foreign Investors Help Your. Balance of Payments? A General Equilibrium Analysis. (Available on Request Appendix)

Abstract The model developed in this paper has distinctly classical, but also Schumpeterian and Keynesian features. The main analysis is explored in a

KÖZGAZDASÁGI ALAPISMERETEK (ELMÉLETI GAZDASÁGTAN) ANGOL NYELVEN

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

LECTURE 14 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM IN THE CASE OF A SINGLE LABOR SECTOR

Employment and Income Distribution from a Classical-Keynesian point of view. Some tools to ground a normative analysis

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Study Skills in Mathematics. Edited by D. Burkhardt and D. Rutherford. Nottingham: Shell Centre for Mathematical Education (Revised edn 1981).

Relationships between phases of business cycles in two large open economies

Japan Korea Link Input Output Analysis

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants,

DATABASE AND METHODOLOGY

Economics th April 2011

COVENANT UNIVERSITY NIGERIA TUTORIAL KIT OMEGA SEMESTER PROGRAMME: ESTATE MANAGEMENT

Assignment #5. 1 Keynesian Cross. Econ 302: Intermediate Macroeconomics. December 2, 2009

Refutation of the Commodity Exploitation Theorem. Takao Fujimoto. Yukihiko Fujita

Topic 4: Matrices Reading: Jacques: Chapter 7, Section

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Mankiw Chapter 11. Aggregate Demand I. Building the IS-LM Model

Capacity utilization, obsolete machines and effective demand

Housing with overlapping generations

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Housing and the Business Cycle

Final Exam. You may not use calculators, notes, or aids of any kind.

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

Information Bulletin 6/2008

Advanced Macroeconomics

The challenge of globalization for Finland and its regions: The new economic geography perspective

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Problem 1 (30 points)

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

The Whole Economy Approach of the Input-Output Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Advanced Macroeconomics

Formal and Informal Sectors in a Social Accounting Matrix for Brazil. Henrique Morrone

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Matrices, vectors and scalars. Operations. Matrix multiplication. notes linear algebra 1. Consider the following examples. a 11 a 12 a 21 a 22

Two Models of Macroeconomic Equilibrium

Difference in regional productivity and unbalance in regional growth

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

ECONOMICS TRIPOS PART I. Friday 15 June to 12. Paper 3 QUANTITATIVE METHODS IN ECONOMICS

PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) (MACROECONOMICS cl. 15)

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Self-test for applicants M.Sc. Economics

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Capital, Institutions and Urban Growth Systems

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

INTELLIGENT CITIES AND A NEW ECONOMIC STORY CASES FOR HOUSING DUNCAN MACLENNAN UNIVERSITIES OF GLASGOW AND ST ANDREWS

North Dakota Lignite Energy Industry's Contribution to the State Economy for 2002 and Projected for 2003

Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 06-20

22 nd Inforum World Conference 30 August 6 September 2013 Alexandria, Virginia, USA

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

This operation is - associative A + (B + C) = (A + B) + C; - commutative A + B = B + A; - has a neutral element O + A = A, here O is the null matrix

APPENDIX 2 MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION ON THE METHODOLOGY OF CONSTRUCTION OF INPUT OUTPUT TABLES

Scarf Instability and Production: A Simulation

A Growth Cycle. R. M. Goodwin. July 30, Presented at the First World Congress of the Econometric Society, held in Rome, 1965.

The General Neoclassical Trade Model

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Extended IS-LM model - construction and analysis of behavior

LECTURE 10 ADDITIONAL DISCUSSION OF CYCLE THEORY

Indirect Taxes in Multisectoral Macroeconomic Models

1. Money in the utility function (start)

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

Information Bulletin 4/2007

Lecture 2 Macroeconomic Model of China by Simultaneous Equations

You are permitted to use your own calculator where it has been stamped as approved by the University.

The Solow Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. January 26, Econ520

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting

Information Bulletin 4/2008

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

Economic Benefit Study on Value of Spatial Information Australian Experience

On Returns to Scale Assumption in Endogenous Growth

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Income Distribution in Classical Competition: Equilibrium, Efficiency, and Stability

Simultaneous (and Recursive) Equation Systems. Robert Dixon Department of Economics at the University of Melbourne

The Central Bank of Iceland forecasting record

Transcription:

Keynes and the Classics Notes on the Monetary Theory of Production Formelsammlung zu Wirtschaftstheorie IV Social production, value and distribution (436-445) The starting point is a Leontief price system: pa + w n n d k = p (9.) A is the broadly triangular Leontief coefficient matrix sketched in the preceding section. The coefficients a ij = x ij / X j (9.2) indicate the amount of good i required to produce a unit of good j. p is the (row) price vector. First, we have the prices of primaries or land basics, subsequently the prices of intermediate products which are followed by the prices of final products, i.e. private and public consumption and investment (capital) goods. The expression w n n d k (9.3) denotes value added and its distribution between wages and gross profits. n d is the (row) vector of direct labour per unit of output for all products, primary, intermediate and final, in this order. w n is a scalar denoting the wage rate per unit of simple labour time in terms of money, and k is the mark-up on labour-costs such as to ensure a satisfactory (target or normal) rate of profits on fixed capital and to allow for the depreciation of equipments. Relation (9.) may be rewritten as p (I - A) = w n n d k where I is a unit matrix (the main diagonal is made up of the element "", all other positions of this square matrix are ""). Multiplying on both sides by the Leontief inverse (I - A) - and transposing this matrix as well as the vectors p and n d, which now become column vectors, yields p = w n [(I - A) - ]' n d k (9.4)

where (I - A) - is the Leontif inverse. The relation n = [(I - A) - ]' n d (9.5) indicates that the column vector of vertically integrated labour n is derived from multiplying the column vector of direct labour nd by the transposed Leontief inverse. Combining relations (9.4) and (9.5) yields the Ricardo-Pasinetti prices for final outputs based upon vertical integration. p = w n n k (9.6) [Two simplifying assumptions: Abstracting from specific conditions of production means that for each good (consumption, intermediate or primary good) the corresponding capital good row of the transposed Leontief inverse in the equation system (9.4) must be multiplied by a specific coefficient so as to make the corresponding ratio n ik / n i equal to unity (ratios smaller or greater than unity would also be possible), bearing in mind that the absolute values of n ik and n i may differ widely. To abstract from specific conditions of production means passing from scientific models to metaphysical models (metamodels) embodying principles. If the proportions between circulating and fixed capital were not uniform, the scalar k in relations (9.) and (9.3) would have to be replaced by a square matrix containing the various sectorial mark-ups on the main diagonal with zero positions elsewhere. Or, when the economy is not vertically integrated, the mark-up would be on wages and intermediates and primaries: the price system (9.) would become [pa + w n n d ]k = p. The model would become immensely complicated while the conclusions would only be quantitatively modified, not qualitatively altered] The macroeconomic counterpart of the sectorial price system obains if we, first, premultiply in relation (9.6) the column vectors p and n by the quantitiy (row) vector q: Y = w n N k (9.6A) Here Y is the nominal gross national product N the number of workers and employees in the profit sector if we interpret w n as the average wage rate. In the second place, p c, the money price of a bundle of necessary consumption goods, is selected as a numéraire. This implies that the real social product is Q = Y/ p c, a certain number of bundles of 2

necessary consumption goods. We now obtain the Kalecki-Weintraub price equation put to use in Bortis (997): p c = w n n k = w n (/A) k (9.7) The effort made to produce good i starts with the production of primaries, with value added being n ip, and, passing through intermediate products (value added is n ii ), terminates with the final products, with direct labour in the last stage of production being n id. Hence and n i = n ip + n ii + n id (9.8) n = n P + n I + n d (9.9) for all final goods if the n in (9.9) are conceived of as vectors and for the economy as a whole, in relation with the social product, if the n in (9.9) are seen as scalars. Combining (9.9) with (9.7) yields: p c = w n (n P + n I + n d ) k (9.) This relation implies that with vertical integration of the social process of production value added in primary and intermediate goods is also variable capital in Marx's sense, which greatly simplifies the presentation of price formation. The price equation for a consumption good can be written as follows: or and p ic = w n n ic + r (w n n ik k) p ic = w n n ic [ + (r w n n ik k) / (w n n ic )] p ic = w n n ic [ + (r n ik k) / n ic ] (9.) Since we abstract from the differing conditions of production the expression in square brackets of relation (9.) equals k which allows us to bring out the economic meaning of the mark-up more precisely for the case that property incomes consist of profits only: k = + (r n ik k) / (n i ) k = n i / (n i - r n ik ) (9.2) /k = (n i - r n ik ) / n i = - r (n ik / n i ) (9.3) 3

and for the economy as a whole /k = (n - r n K ) / n = - r (n K / n) (9.4) The price equations for the capital goods entering the production of consumption goods, primary and intermediate goods have exactly the same structure as the price equations for the consumption goods represented by relation (9.): pik = wn nik [ + (r nik* k) / nik] (9.5) There is one important difference, however. In producing the capital goods required to produce consumption goods, labour is assisted by a specific capital good, i.e. machine tools or machines to make machines (Lowe 976). In (9.5) this specific capital good is marked with a star. However, machine tools are also assist labour to produce machine tools. Hence we have a final fundamental equation p ik * = w n n ik * [ + (r n ik ** k) / n ik *] (9.6) This relation fixes the proportion between the value of fixed and of circulating capital which must hold in all price equations, i.e. n ik ** / n ik *. Proportions and scale - classical and Keynesian macroeconomics The essential feature of a monetary production economy is neatly represented at the outset of the second volume of Marx's Kapital (p. 3): M - C... P... C' - M' (9.7) In the first stage, producers dispose of money and finance M (G in orig.) and buy means of production, i.e. commodities and labour force, C (W in original). These are transformed into final products C' (W') in the vertically integrated labour view of the social process of production P which implies the horizontal land aspect of production. The final goods C' are transformed into money M' (G'). At this second stage of circulation M' effective demand in money terms - governs C', the amount of final goods that may be exchanged against money. 4

The proportions aspect of classical-keynesian political economy Incomes are formed simultaneously with prices. This leads to monetary flows associated with the formation and the spending of incomes. These aspects of the process of production are exhibited by the price system (9.): c c 2 c m n n n 2 m p p2 pm w k n (9.8) The number of final goods produced in an economy is m; these are for private and state consumption and investment; some of the goods may be exported, and imports may be equal to, fall short of or exceed exports. The p,..., p m represent the corresponding prices of production; the average nominal income produced by a person active in the profit sector is w nk which equals nominal average labour productivity pa; w n is the money wage rate and k the mark-up over prime costs at normal capacity utilization; in a vertically integrated economy wage costs equal prime costs since labour comprises direct and indirect labour; p = p c is the money price of a bundle of necessary consumption goods and stands, as such, for the general price level; A = Q/N is labour productivity in real terms; the size of the social product Q is expressed by the number of bundles of necessary consumptions goods and N is the labour force in the profit sector ; in this sector a qualitative and quantitative surplus over wages occurs which, in nominal terms, equals w n (k-) and accrues to capital in the form of profits and to land owners and to specially skilled or organized labour in the form of rents. Since working time is assumed to be given, N stands, either, for the number of workers and employees, or, for working time measured in hours, in months or in years. The n i (= N i /Q if ) are the vertically integrated labour coefficients comprising direct and indirect labour time N i, e.g. man years, in relation to the full employment output (Q if ) of good i; the indirect part of N i is embodied in primary and intermediate products; the c i (= Q if /N f ) represent demand coefficients which indicate how the average nominal income, w nk, or total income in real terms, N f, i.e. in terms of labour time, is spent. Part of income is consumed, and part is paid in taxes and saved. Since saving equals investment in long-period equilibrium (Bortis 997, pp. 8-89), the demand coefficients c i relate to the demand for private and public consumption and investment goods. The price equations contained in system (9.8) are all based on vertical integration and, therefore, correspond to the equation system (9.6) above: p i = w n n i k = w n (/A i ) k; (i =, 2, m) (9.9) 5

where A i is sectorial labour productivity Q i /N i. The labour value principle gives rise to a distributional issue associated with the notion of distributive justice. This emerges from the set of relative prices that can be derived from the absolute prices (9.9): p i / p j = n i / n j (9.9A) The classical theory of value and distribution implies the creation of incomes in the social process of production and their subsequent distribution. This emerges from the system of equations (9.9) which are derived from system (9.8). The last equation of this system c p + c 2 p 2 +... + c m p m = w n k (9.2) indicates in what proportions incomes are spent on the various goods. The c i coefficients (defined by relation 9.26 below) represent the fractions of real income - measured in terms of labour time, man-years N f for example spent for a certain quantity of each good i (if N f is interpreted as a number of workers and employees the c i would represent per capita demand for a specific good). The c i p i coefficients are expenditures in money terms on the various goods and services per person employed in the profit-sector, indicating the way in which average money income w n k is spent. This becomes immediately evident if in relation (9.2) the definition of c i (relation 9.26 below) is taken into account: c i p i = (Q if /N f ) pi = w n k (9.2) As such, equations (9.2 and 9.2) picture yet another part of the flows of money and goods and services in a monetary production economy. The average income w n k is consumed, paid in taxes and saved and subsequently spent on private and public consumption goods and on investment goods, whereby both consumption and investment may be financed in part by the financial sector with saving passively adjusting. In this process, the enterprise sector delivers goods and provides services, and receives the sales receipts. In these processes proportions between sectors are established. The economic meaning of relation (9.2) emerges more clearly if the equations for the various pi (the system 9.9 above) are taken into account: (N i /N f ) w n k = w n k (9.22) (N i /N f ) w n k N f = w n k N f = Y (9.23) 6

(N i /N f ) = (9.24) These definitions together with definition (9.2) tell us that the spending of average income (relation 9.22) or total income (relation 9.23) governs the distribution of the labour force across the various sectors of production (relation 9.24). The quantity flows of a monetary production economy are captured by the equation system (9.25). Since this section deals with proportions the scale of activity is arbitrary. In accordance with Pasinetti (98) we assume that full employment prevails. This assumption will be given up in the next section where Keynes's principle of effective demand comes in to determine the long-period scale of economic activity. n n 2 n m c c c 2 m Q Q Q N f 2 f mf f (9.25) Here N f represents the full employment labour force active in the profit sector. The (full employment) quantity of profit sector labour (N f ) represents the pivot of the quantity system. N seen as labour time has, in fact, two aspects. On the one hand, N f, is labour commanded, measures the value of output or the level of incomes. The spending coefficients c i indicate how full employment (real) income N f is spent and thus determines the full employment quantities Q if of private and public consumption and investment goods, that is the structure of production which also a matter of proportions: Q if = c i N f ; (i =, 2,, m) (9.26) These equations imply that in a monetary production economy goods valued at labour time (Q if ) are, ultimately, exchanged against labour time (real income measured in labour time), not against other goods as is the case in the neoclassical exchange model. On the other hand, N f represents labour embodied in the quantities of the various goods produced and, consequently, in the social product. The vertically integrated coefficients of direct and indirect labour (n i ) and the quantities demanded (determined by relations 9.2) govern the distribution of labour between the different sectors of production: n Q f + n 2 Q 2f +... + n m Q im = N i = N f (V.) where the n i = N i /Q if (V.) 7

represent the labour coefficients, that is the amount of direct and indirect labour required to produce a unit of output. As such, labour embodied represents the social effort required to produce the final goods and hence the social product. Mathematically, the dependence of one equation on the others implies that the determinant of the equation systems (9.8) and (9.25) is zero: c n + c 2 n 2 +... + c m n m - = (9.29) If account is taken of the definition of the c i and n i coefficients (definitions 9.26 and 9.28), this condition indicates, once again, the distribution of labour across the vertically integrated sectors of production: N /N f + N 2 /N f +... + N m /N f = (9.3) The sectorial distribution of profit sector labour emerges as the basic element of socioeconomic structure and of the proportions aspect of classical-keynesian political economy. According to condition (9.23) this distribution depends upon demand (c i ) and upon direct and indirect labour requirements ( n i ). The scale aspect of classical-keynesian political economy If the quantity vector in system (9.25) is multiplied by a scalar smaller than unity, -u say, - u being the ratio of involuntary unemployment to the productive full employment labour force - all the quantities are reduced correspondingly and a permanent involuntary unemployment of percent would come into being, while all the formal properties of the quantity system would be preserved. The coefficient matrix of the quantity system (9.25) would remain formally unchanged and that the vector of normal quantities would now be given by [Q, Q 2,..., Q m, N] (9.3) with N < N f (9.32) N stands for profit sector employment. The employment scalar (-u) or, conversely, the long-period unemployment rate (u) are defined as follows: -u = N/N f (9.33) u = (N f - N)/N f (9.34) 8

where N is the institutionally governed long-period employment equilibrium to which corresponds a long-period equilibrium output Q smaller than the full employment output Q f. Since N is linked to Q through labour productivity at any moment of time: Q = AN, these definitions could also be written in terms of Q. The determinants of N and Q emerge from a macroeconomic equilibrium condition in which the various demand components govern normal output Q, i.e. supply, and hence normal employment N: AN = Q = wn + c s (P+R) + I + G + X tm (9.35) Q is real output - the social product - measured in terms of a bundle of necessary consumption goods; Q is made up of private and public consumption and investment goods, i.e. of the same goods which are listed in the output vector of the quantity system (9.25); N is labour employed in the profit sector, A is labour productivity (Q/N), w is the real wage rate w n /p (w n stands for the money wage rate and p for the normal price of a bundle of necessary consumption goods); the wage sum wn is entirely consumed; c s is the fraction of the social surplus P+R consumed (P represents profits, including interest, and R represents rents accruing to landowners and to labour on account of special skills or social arrangements, e.g. corporative organisations), I is gross investment, G represents government expenditures, X stands for exports, M for imports and t indicates the terms of trade. Imports M are of two broad types both of which are related to economic activity, i.e. to output Q or to income Y (with Q=Y in principle): M = b Q = M + M 2, with M = b Q and M 2 = b 2 Q; hence M = b Q = M + M 2 = b Q + b 2 Q = (b + b 2 ) Q (9.36) M are necessary imports required in the process of production. These goods are land basics, labour basics and labour-land basics (machine tools, and the various capital goods produced with machine tools and labour). Necessary imports are, then, part of the necessary goods entering directly or indirectly as inputs in the production of all goods; necessary consumption goods, raw materials and machines to make machines are the cases in point. M 2 are nonnecessary imports related to consumption out of the social surplus. The macroeconomic Kalecki-Weintraub price equation implied in relation (9.35) is analogous to the sectorial price equations (9.6) and (9.9) and equals (9.7) as derived from combining the interindustry and vertically integrated approach to social production: p = (w n /A) k (9.37) 9

This very simple price equation has two important properties which have already been alluded to. First, it is based on vertical integration which implies that all the costs of production ultimately become labour costs. Second, this simple mark-up equation is directly linked with the surplus principle of income distribution, the wage and property shares being: W/Y = /k and (P+R)/Y = -(/k) (9.38) Given technology, as synthesised by overall labour productivity (A), the regulation of distribution - the determination of the money wage rate wn and of the mark-up k - must logically precede price formation. Hence, given A, the price p is determined once w n and k are fixed. The determination of the wage and property shares in income is a social problem because part-whole relationships are involved. Normal or trend gross investment is directly associated with the maintenance and expansion of the normal capital stock K required for the production of the normal output Q: I = (g+d)v Q (9.39) where g is the trend growth rate of the economic system, a weighted average of the trend rates of growth of the autonomous variables, i.e. normal government expenditures G and normal exports X (see relation VI. below and Bortis 997, p. 55); d represents the fraction of the normal capital stock which is annually replaced and v stands for the normal capital coefficient K/Q. Normal investment is thus related to the functioning of the entire social system, encompassing technology and institutions. Therefore, investment, which is autonomous in the short run, represents derived demand in the long run. Taking account of relations (9.35) to (9.39) above yields a relation for long-period (normal, trend) output Q, and, since Q = AN, for the long-period (normal, trend) level of employment N (Bortis 997, pp. 42-24): G + X Q = (9.4) z s [ (/ k)] + t (b + b2) (g + d)v where z s = c s = s s + t s. (9.4) The leakage coefficient z s indicates the fraction of the surplus over ordinary wages which is not consumed, the fraction consumed being c s. Consequently, the leakage coefficient is the sum of the fractions of the surplus paid for taxes (t s ) and saved (s s ). Since the long-period consumption coefficient c s and the long-period tax coefficient t s are both determined by institutions - consumption habits and tax laws -, the long-period

saving propensity s s is a pure residual varying with the normal level of output and employment (Bortis 997, pp. 66-68). This is perfectly analogous to Keynes's shortperiod theory of saving.