The Solow Growth Model

Similar documents
Growth. Growth Theory. Mark Huggett 1. 1 Georgetown. January 26, 2018

The Solow Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. January 26, Econ520

Economics 2: Growth (Growth in the Solow Model)

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 4

Chapter 9 Solow. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos. Computational Economics: a concise introduction

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L2: Economic growth II

The Solow Growth Model

14.05: Section Handout #1 Solow Model

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Analysis of the speed of convergence

Lecture 2: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn Lars Calmfors

From Difference to Differential Equations I

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Growth: Facts and Theories

Modeling Economic Growth Using Differential Equations

Generic Analysis of Endogenous Growth Models

Exam 1. Econ520. Fall 2013

Equating output per worker to GDP per capita, the growth rate of GDP per capita

A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth

Advanced Macroeconomics

Lecture 2: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn Lars Calmfors

One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Solow Growth Model. Sang Yoon (Tim) Lee. Jan 9-16, last updated: January 20, Toulouse School of Economics

The Romer Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. February 7, Econ520

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Lecture 3 - Solow Model

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2015 P. Gourinchas/D. Romer MIDTERM EXAM

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 8 : Empirical studies of convergence

Growth Theory: Review

Endogenous Growth Theory

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Lecture 15 Real Business Cycle Model. Noah Williams

Economic Growth

Lecture 4 Economic Growth: Foundations

Growth Theory: Review

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Third Edition

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

General motivation behind the augmented Solow model

Economics 202A Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 5

Introduction to Real Business Cycles: The Solow Model and Dynamic Optimization

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

Econ 204A: Section 3

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PS 5, preliminary version

On the Dynamic Implications of the Cobb- Douglas Production Function

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 2 : Balance Growth Paths

"Solow Model" and Its' Linkage with "Harrod-Domar"

3 GROWTH AND CAPITAL ACCUMULATION: THE SOLOW MODEL

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L1: Economic growth I

Lecture notes on modern growth theories

Lecture 5 Dynamics of the Growth Model. Noah Williams

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models

Problem Set 2. E. Charlie Nusbaum Econ 204A October 12, 2015

Chapter 2. The Solow Growth Model

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

Lectures 7: Growth Model and the Data

Aggregate Production Function. Production. Mark Huggett. Georgetown University. January 11, 2018

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Problem Set #2: Overlapping Generations Models Suggested Solutions - Q2 revised

Exploring the World of Growth and Development

Endogenous Growth. Lecture 17 & 18. Topics in Macroeconomics. December 8 & 9, 2008

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

Topic 3. RBCs

Lecture notes on modern growth theories

Solution to Homework 2 - Exogeneous Growth Models

THE SOLOW-SWAN MODEL WITH A NEGATIVE LABOR GROWTH RATE

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Foundation of (virtually) all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model) is Solow growth model

How much should the nation save?

EC9A2 Advanced Macro Analysis - Class #1

Exploring the World of Growth and Development

On Returns to Scale Assumption in Endogenous Growth

Economics 202A Lecture Outline #3 (version 1.0)

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Advanced Macroeconomics

Department of Economics Queen s University. ECON435/835: Development Economics Professor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Population growth and technological progress in the optimal growth model

TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions)

Notes on Econ 102 Sect. 2, Fall 2005

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

1. Basic Neoclassical Model (Solow Model) (April 14, 2014)

Convergence behaviour in exogenous growth models

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

14.452: Introduction to Economic Growth Problem Set 4

On the dynamics of basic growth models: Ratio stability versus convergence and divergence in state space

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Bubbles and Credit Constraints

Chapter 5. The Engine of Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

( ) (, ) F K L = F, Y K N N N N. 8. Economic growth 8.1. Production function: Capital as production factor

Transcription:

The Solow Growth Model 1. Set-Up 2. Dynamics, Simulations and Steady-States 3. Comparative Dynamics 4. Golden Rule 5. Convergence 1

Set-Up Closed economy, single good produced each period, Yt. Discrete time (in contrast to the Romer text). There are two factors of production, labor, Nt and Kt. Total factor productivity, A, is a constant. There is a constant returns-to-scale production function. In particular, we are going to assume that the production function is Cobb-Douglas: Yt = AF (Kt, Nt) = AK t 1 α N t α We have the standard expenditure identity for a closed economy without government: Yt = Ct + It. 2

The law of motion for capital is: for a given K0. Kt+1 = (1 δ)kt + It Let s be the fraction of income that is saved (invested) each period. so and It = syt Ct = (1 s)yt. So the law of motion of capital can be written as: Kt+1 = (1 δ)kt + syt. 3

Assume N grows over time: Nt+1 = (1 + n)nt Let yt = per capital output. So yt Y t. Nt yt = AF (K t, Nt) Nt = AF ( 1 Nt = AF ( K t Nt Kt, 1 NtNt), 1) = AF (kt, 1) = AF (kt) where kt is the capital-to-labor ratio. In the case of a Cobb-Douglas production function: yt = Y t = Nt 1 = A Nt = Ak α t AK t α N t 1 α K t α N t α N t 1 α N t 1 α 4

The law of motion for the capital-to-labor ratio, kt: kt+1 = K t+1 Nt+1 = (1 δ)k t + It (1 + n)nt = (1 δ)k t + syt (1 + n)nt = (1 δ)k t + sak t α N 1 α (1 + n)nt = = (1 δ) (1 + n) Kt Nt (1 δ) (1 + n) k t + + sa (1 + n) K t α N t α s (1 + n) Akα t 5

Let s do some simulations Assign values to δ, s, n, A, and α. Given a starting value for k we can simulate this economy. Let s use 1959 as a starting value. Use data from Economic Report of the President and BEA So k1959 = K 1959 N1959 = 411.7 115.3 = 3.57 Set A = T F P1959 = 2.87. Set δ = 0.08, s =.10, n = 0.015, and α = 0.36 Just to make sure you understand what we are doing we are setting k0 = 3.57 and using the law of motion for kt we just derived to compute values for k1, k2, k3,... 6

Experiment After about 75 years the capital-to-labor ratio stops growing. Forget above doubling every 30. This model does not predict continued growth in per capita output. We do get sustained growth in total output. But we are way off from the data. 7

What s going on here? Go back to our law of motion for kt. kt+1 = (1 δ) (1 + n) k t + sa (1 + n) kα t Note that when kt = 0, kt+1 = 0. Take a derivative: dkt+1 dkt = (1 δ) (1 + n) + saα 1 + n kα 1 t Since 1 α < 0, we know when kt = 0, dkt+1/dkt = Also since 1 α < 0, when kt =, k t α 1 = 0. Therefore dkt+1/dkt = (1 δ)/(1 + n) < 1. 8

Steady-state To compute the steady state capital-to-labor ratio we need to do a little algebra: k (1 δ) = 1 + n k + sa 1 + n k α (1 + n)k = (1 δ)k + sak α (n + δ)k = sak α Figure 1.2 in Romer plots the RHS and LHS of this last equation. (n + δ)k = sak α n + δ sa = k α 1 Let get the exponent positive k = n + δ sa 1 α 1 k = Growth does occur while kt < k. sa But eventually growth slows to zero. n + δ 1 1 α 9

Comparative statics/dynamics A change in s. A change in δ A change in n A one-time change in A Natural and unnatural disasters Growth effects versus level effects 10

Growth in A So neither growth in capital nor growth in labor can sustain output growth over a long period time. What s left? A. At this point you should be thinking there are decreasing marginal benefits to increasing capital and labor but not A. So it is going to turn out that growth in A can get us sustained growth in output per worker. But what the heck is A? We just computed it as a residual. 11

Saving and the Golden Rule What determines the saving rate, s? We assumed: and It = syt Ct = (1 s)yt. So what is the optimal s? Suppose we want to maximize steady-state consumption. c = (1 s)y = (1 s)ak α = (1 s)a sa n + δ α 1 α 12

Easier question: What steady-state level of the capital-to-labor ratio, k, maximizes steady-state consumption per worker. Define two more variables. ct Ct/Nt. So ct denotes consumption per worker. i It/Nt. So it denotes investment per worker. Then we can write the expenditure identity as: So in steady-state: Yt = Ct + It Yt Nt = C t Nt + I t Nt yt = ct + it y = c + i 13

We can get the law-of-motion for Kt in per-worker (lower case terms) as well. You can fill in the intermediate steps... So in steady-state: Kt+1 = (1 δ)kt + It. (1 + n)kt+1 = (1 δ)kt + it (1 + n)k = (1 δ)k + i Solving for i yields: i = (n + δ)k If we substitute in for y and i are per-worker expenditure identity becomes: Ak α = c + (n + δ)k or c = Ak α (n + δ)k 14

Now remember why did all this algebra. We wanted to find the k that maximizes c. So we want take the derivative of the above equation with respect to k. So the k that maximizes c is the k that satisfies: αak α 1 δ = n or MPK δ = n. Graphically, this k is the capital-to-labor ratio that maximizes the difference between the production function and steady-state investment line. 15

s k y δk c MPK MPK - δ 0 0 0 0 0 0.1 54.9 52.2 4.4 47.0 0.2850 0.2050 0.2 147.8 70.2 11.8 56.2 0.1425 0.0625 0.3 263.9 83.6 21.1 58.5 0.0950 0.0150 0.4 398.0 94.5 31.8 56.7 0.0713-0.0087 0.5 547.4 104.0 43.8 52.0 0.0570-0.0230 0.6 710.2 112.5 56.8 45.0 0.0475-0.0325 0.7 885.2 120.1 70.8 36.0 0.0407-0.0393 0.8 1071.3 127.2 85.7 25.4 0.0356-0.0444 0.9 1267.6 133.8 101.4 13.4 0.0317-0.0483 1.0 1473.5 140.0 117.9 0 0.0285-0.0515 Table 1: A Numerical Comparison of Steady-States Why should we poor people make sacrifices for those who will in any case live in luxury in the future? Robert Solow 16

Convergence Unconditional convergence: Poor countries should eventually catch up to rich countries. This should occur if saving rates, population growth rates, and production functions are the same everywhere. This really hinges on whether there is free flowing international borrowing and lending. Why isn t all new investment occurring in the Third World? Is there too little capital mobility in the world? Conditional convergence: Living standards will converge in countries with similar characteristics: s, n, δ, α. There would be convergence except different countries have different parameters in the Solow model. 17

Evidence of Convergence In the case of Post-WW2 Japan, Germany, and England, much capital was destroyed in the war so reasonable to think of them being far away from steady-state so high GDP growth in decades following war partially explained as transitioning to steady-state. For developed countries, Solow model predicts we would already be at or near steady state. If one does not account for differing population growth rates and saving rates, there is simply no evidence for convergence. If one accounts for differing saving and population growth rates, convergence might be occurring, although there is a small sample problem. The theory predicts that countries like Japan and Germany in 1950 will have higher growth rates than US. US states also seem to be converging. (Poor states grow faster than rich ones.) Right now the South is growing faster than the North. Evidence of conditional convergence since the U.S. states have similar characteristics. After the Civil War, average per capita income in South was 40% of the average per capita income in North. Now it is about the same. 18