The Solow Model in Discrete Time Allan Drazen October 2017

Similar documents
Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Economic Growth

Lecture 3 - Solow Model

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

14.05: Section Handout #1 Solow Model

Department of Economics Queen s University. ECON435/835: Development Economics Professor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models

Endogenous Growth Theory

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

From Difference to Differential Equations I

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Economics 2: Growth (Growth in the Solow Model)

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

EC9A2 Advanced Macro Analysis - Class #1

The Solow Growth Model

THE SOLOW-SWAN MODEL WITH A NEGATIVE LABOR GROWTH RATE

The Solow Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. January 26, Econ520

Balanced Growth Despite Uzawa

Economics 202A Lecture Outline #3 (version 1.0)

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

The Ramsey/Cass-Koopmans (RCK) Model

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

"Solow Model" and Its' Linkage with "Harrod-Domar"

Factor Substitution, Income Distribution, and Growth in a Generalized Neoclassical Model

Econ 7110 slides Growth models: Solow, Diamond, Malthus. January 8, 2017

ECON607 Fall 2010 University of Hawaii Professor Hui He TA: Xiaodong Sun Assignment 2

Factor-Eliminating Technical Change

EC744 Lecture Notes: Economic Dynamics. Prof. Jianjun Miao

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

Neoclassical Models of Endogenous Growth

Chapter 2. The Solow Growth Model

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

On the Dynamic Implications of the Cobb- Douglas Production Function

Problem 1 (30 points)

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

Overlapping Generations Model

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions)

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

On Returns to Scale Assumption in Endogenous Growth

Existence, uniqueness and stability of equilibria in an OLG model with persistent inherited habits

Lecture 1: The Classical Optimal Growth Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

1 The social planner problem

Non-convex Aggregate Technology and Optimal Economic Growth

4.4 The functional distribution of income

Neoclassical Growth Model / Cake Eating Problem

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Environmental Policy under Imperfect Information: Incentives and Moral hazard. A. Xepapadeas (1991)

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Lecture notes on modern growth theories

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Lecture notes on modern growth theories

Generic Analysis of Endogenous Growth Models

Growth Theory: Review

The Quest for Status and Endogenous Labor Supply: the Relative Wealth Framework

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Oil Stock Discovery and Dutch Disease

Modeling Economic Growth Using Differential Equations

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Solution to Homework 2 - Exogeneous Growth Models

Economic Growth: Lectures 10 and 11, Endogenous Technological Change

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

Population growth and technological progress in the optimal growth model

Problem Set 2. E. Charlie Nusbaum Econ 204A October 12, 2015

Lecture 9: The monetary theory of the exchange rate

Econ 8106 MACROECONOMIC THEORY Prof. L. Jones. Class Notes: Parts III and IV

1. Money in the utility function (start)

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

External Economies of Scale and International Trade: Further Analysis

Growth Theory: Review

Another Proof for the Stability of a Modified Solow Model

Growth. Growth Theory. Mark Huggett 1. 1 Georgetown. January 26, 2018

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

a = (a 1; :::a i )

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

Addendum to: New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

MathII at SU and SSE. John Hassler IIES, Stockholm University

Analysis of the speed of convergence

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Internation1al Trade

XLVIII Reunión Anual. Noviembre de 2013

the growth rate in the labour force. fk () = F(,1): fk () and strictly concave, with positive marginal productivities. Given that the Inadaconditions

The Real Business Cycle Model

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 2, Review of Endogenous Growth: Expanding Variety Models

Chapter 9 Solow. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos. Computational Economics: a concise introduction

Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks

Advanced Macroeconomics

Transcription:

The Solow Model in Discrete Time Allan Drazen October 2017 1 Technology There is a single good Y t produced by means of two factors of production capital K t in place at the beginning of the period and labor according to a production function Y t = F (K t ; ) (1) We mae the following assumptions on F (K; L): 1) twice continuously di erentiable, with positive rst derivatives and negative second partial derivatives; 2) homogeneous of degree one (that is, F (K; L) = F (K; L) for any constant ); 3) each input is strictly necessary (that is, F (0; L) = F (K; 0) = 0); 4) Inada conditions on F (K; 1), that is, lim F K(K; 1) = 1 and lim F K(K; 1) = 0, where the notation F K (K; 1) refers to the K!0 K!1 partial derivative of F (K; 1) with respect to K. To begin, assume there is no technical progress, that is, the production function F (K; L) does not shift up over time. 2 Inputs Labor supply grows exponentially at exogenous rate n, the rate of population growth. That is, labor is supplied inelastically: +1 = (1 + n) (2) Gross investment is the change in the capital stoc plus capital depreciation, that is, I t K t+1 K t + K t (3) where the rate of depreciation is ; where 0 < < 1: Net investment is gross investment minus depreciation, that is, the net change in the capital stoc K t+1 K t : Gross investment equals aggregate saving, meaning capital is also supplied inelastically. The ey assumption is that saving is a xed fraction s of gross output, where 0 < s < 1; that is I t = sy t (4) Y t. Hence, Solow based this assumption on stylized fact about economies, rather than on optimizing. It is equivalent to assuming a constant marginal propensity to consume (MPC). Combining the above two equations, capital evolves according to: 3 Evolution of the Economy K t+1 = sy t + (1 ) K t (5) The ey question is Given initial values of capital and labor (denoted K 0 and L 0 ), how does this economy evolve? That is, how do Y t ; K t ; and evolve? We now the answer for 1

labor from (2). Dividing (5) through by we may write K t+1 +1 +1 = s Y t + (1 ) K t De ne a new variable, the capital-labor ratio t = K t =. If we now how it evolves, we can multiply by at any date to nd how K t evolves. Using (2), we have: t+1 = s Y t + 1 1 + n 1 + n t (6) Using the rst-degree homogeneity of the production function, we may write: Y t = F (K t; ) Kt = F ; 1 = F ( t ; 1) f ( t ) (7) where the last equality indicates the de nition of a new function, which taes on the properties of as assumed in assumptions 1), 3), and 4) in section 1 above. Hence, f (0) = 0, f 0 () = F K (K; 1) > 0, f 00 () < 0, and so on. (You should demonstrate this.) One may then write a dynamic equation in a single state variable t that completely describes the evolution of the economy: t+1 = s 1 + n f ( t) + 1 1 + n t g ( t ) (8) State variables are a set of variables that fully describe at each point in time the state of the system, that is the value of all the system s variables, given the exogenous variables. (As in this case, there may be only one variable). Generally, one has the goal of reducing a system to the minimal level of state variables. (8) is a basic rst-order di erence equation. To solve it one needs a single boundary condition, which here is simply the starting point, namely 0 = K 0 =L 0. The evolution of all variables in this economy can be found once we now the evolution of the state variable t. One can analyze this in a discrete time phase diagram, plotting t+1 = g ( t ) in t t+1 space, and using the 45 line in this space (that is, the line t = t+1 ) to derive the dynamics and the stationary or rest point, that is, the steady state. From (8), we have g 0 s ( t ) = 1 + n f 0 ( t ) + 1 1 + n > 0 (9a) g 00 s ( t ) = 1 + n f 00 ( t ) < 0 (9b) so that g () is an increasing, strictly concave function. Figure 1 presents the phase diagram. 2

Figure 1: Dynamics in the Solow Model 4 Characteristics of the Steady State A steady state is a value = t = t+1, that is a solution to = g () from (8). This is termed a balanced growth path, with all extensive variables K t ; ; and Y t growing at the same rate n: 4.1 Existence of a steady state Using the characteristic f(0) = 0, one steady state, that is, solution to = g (), is obviously = 0. Another (unique) solution is a value of such that: f () = n + (10) s This is the Harrod-Domar condition, where pre-solovian growth theory was seen as arguing that: 1) that it was unliely to be satis ed (that is, a steady state was unliely to exist, implying that steady state or balanced growth was unliely); 1 and 2) if it were satis ed, it would not be stable. 1 On existence, Domar was seen as arguing that with a xed-proportions or Leontief prodction function the capital-output ratio (the inverse of the left-hand side of (10)) was technologically xed and thus unliely to be equal to the exogenous ratio f() on the right-hand side of (10). (Domar argued, it seems correctly, that his article was misinterpreted and never made this claim, and he quicly disowned this interpretation of the Harrod-Domar condition. Harrod roughly argued that even though the output-capital ratio is not technologically xed, the monetary side of the economy xes the interest rate, which then determines f(). 3

One of Solow s ey contribution in light of growth theory at the time was to show that given the above assumptions on the production function (that is, on the nature of production), balanced growth was possible and that the balanced growth solution was stable. Speci cally, one may show that the Inada conditions imply that f() approaches 0 as approaches in nity and that f() approaches in nity as approaches 0, that is, that f() can tae any value between 0 and 1. (See the Appendix for a proof.) Since n+s also lies between 0 and 1, for any value of the right-hand side of (10), there is a at least one value of such that (10) is satis ed. Since f () is continuous and concave in, this interior value, call it SS, is unique. Note that the ratio of net output, y t t, to t is also constant along a balanced growth path (see Krusell and Smith, 2015). We return to this later in the term when we evaluate the controversy over Pietty s wor on the evolution of the capital output ratio over time. 4.2 Convergence (Stability of steady state) In the phase diagram, we see that t is increasing to the left of SS, where g ( t ) > t, and decreasing to the left of SS, where g ( t ) < t. We cannot prove convergence from a diagram, but we can use the diagrams to gain intuition about what we need to prove. From a phase diagram, one can see that a necessary and su cient condition for convergence/stability is that at the rest point SS, g( t ) cut the 45 line from above, that is, g 0 SS < 1, or, using (9a), f 0 SS < n + (11) s at SS. Since n+s = f(ss ) from (10), (11) becomes SS f 0 SS < f SS SS (12) which is guaranteed by the strict concavity of f (). 4.3 Extensive Growth In steady state the capital stoc K t and total output Y t are growing at rate n; while t and y t are constant. So there is extensive growth, but not intensive (per-capita) growth. The marginal products of labor and capital are also constant. If these are equal to the wage and the net interest rate (net of depreciation, that is, r t = f 0 ( t ) ), as would be true with factor payments determined competitively, these will be constant as well along a balanced growth path. 5 Technical Progress Suppose that there is technical progress, so that the production function is shifting up over time, that is, Y t = F (K t ; ; t) ; where @F () =@t > 0: Balanced growth requires a constant 4

rate of technical progress, but it requires more. In addition, for there to be a balanced growth path either technical progress must be purely labor augmenting or the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor (as in the Cobb-Douglas case) must be unity. (To thin about the case where this elasticity is below one, as much evidence may suggest, see Grossman, Helpman, Ober eld, and Sampson [2017]. 2 ) Labor-augmenting technical progress means that the e ect of technical progress can be mathematically represented as if each physical worer s productivity is being increased or augmented by a factro each period. That is, we can write the production function inclusive of technical progress as F (K t ; ; t) = F (K t ; A t ) where A t are e ective labor units at time t. Note that labor-augmenting technical progress does not refer to the way technical progress maes factors more productive, i.e., better-trained worers, etc.) but only the mathematical e ect of technical progress. For there to be a balanced growth path, the rate of labor-augmenting technical progress must be constant, say A t+1 = (1 + a) A t ; where a is a constant. Then, along a balanced growth path, output Y t will be growing at rate ; where = (1 + a) (1 + n) 1 a + n: Dividing equation (5) by Y t and using K t+1 Y t+1 Harrod-Domar condition (10) can be written K t = Kt Y t along a balanced growth path, the = s (13) Y t + that is, with replacing n: Since labor grows at rate n but output grows at rate > n: there is intensive growth, with Yt growing over time. The interest rate r t will be constant, while the wage per unit of labor will grow at rate : APPENDIX: The Behavior of f() in the Limit We want to show that f() 2 (0; 1). f() L a) K lim!1 = K lim L!0 K F K L ; 1 = lim L!0 F (K; L) = F (K; 0) = 0. f() f() f(0) b) lim!0 = lim!0 = f 0 (0) = lim F K (K; 1) = 1. K!0 2 Grossman, G., E. Helpman. E. Ober eld, and T. Sampson (2017), Balanced Growth Despite Uzawa, American Economic Review 107(4), 1293 1312. 5