Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 4: Production Theory

Similar documents
Technology 1. that describes the (net) output of the L goods of the production process of the firm. By convention,

Chapter 4: Production Theory

Utility Maximization Problem

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

Utility Maximization Problem. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 2

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

EconS Microeconomic Theory I Recitation #5 - Production Theory-I 1

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2: Demand Theory

Microeconomics I. September, c Leopold Sögner

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3)

Math, Stats, and Mathstats Review ECONOMETRICS (ECON 360) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

THE FIRM: OPTIMISATION

Integrating Rational functions by the Method of Partial fraction Decomposition. Antony L. Foster

THE FIRM: DEMAND AND SUPPLY

Microeconomics CHAPTER 2. THE FIRM

Mathematics Ext 2. HSC 2014 Solutions. Suite 403, 410 Elizabeth St, Surry Hills NSW 2010 keystoneeducation.com.

ECON5110: Microeconomics

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Mathematical Foundations II

The Firm: Demand and Supply

Preferences and Utility

Long-run Analysis of Production. Theory of Production

(1) Correspondence of the density matrix to traditional method

Support Vector Machines. CSE 4309 Machine Learning Vassilis Athitsos Computer Science and Engineering Department University of Texas at Arlington

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

The Firm: Optimisation

1 Theory of the Firm: Topics and Exercises

Unit 3: Producer Theory

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008.

Optimization, constrained optimization and applications of integrals.

Rational Expressions and Functions

Worksheets for GCSE Mathematics. Algebraic Expressions. Mr Black 's Maths Resources for Teachers GCSE 1-9. Algebra

Systems of Linear Equations

Math for Economics 1 New York University FINAL EXAM, Fall 2013 VERSION A

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

4.4 The functional distribution of income

The Envelope Theorem

Partial Differentiation

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

Solutions. ams 11b Study Guide 9 econ 11b

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Chapter 4 Differentiation

CS Lecture 8 & 9. Lagrange Multipliers & Varitional Bounds

Exercises - SOLUTIONS UEC Advanced Microeconomics, Fall 2018 Instructor: Dusan Drabik, de Leeuwenborch 2105

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, February 21st, 2018

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Returns-to-Scaleto Marginal product describe the

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index.

A linear operator of a new class of multivalent harmonic functions

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

CHAPTER 1-2: SHADOW PRICES

EconS Cost Structures

Eureka Math. Geometry, Module 5. Student File_B. Contains Exit Ticket and Assessment Materials

Perloff (2014, 3e, GE), Section

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Midterm Exam

Notes on Consumer Theory

Variations. ECE 6540, Lecture 02 Multivariate Random Variables & Linear Algebra

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly.

EconS 301. Math Review. Math Concepts

M.5 Modeling the Effect of Functional Responses

CHAPTER 2 Special Theory of Relativity

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

C02, C32, C43, D24, D42, D92, E01, E22, F11, H44, L51, M40, O47

Polynomials and Polynomial Functions

Constrained optimization.

Advanced Microeconomics

10.1 Three Dimensional Space

10.4 The Cross Product

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Math Review ECON 300: Spring 2014 Benjamin A. Jones MATH/CALCULUS REVIEW

Tutorial 3: Optimisation

Linear Programming and Marginal Analysis

G.6 Function Notation and Evaluating Functions

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

Moving on from the optimum... The Firm: Demand and Supply. The firm as a black box. Overview...

National 5 Mathematics. Practice Paper E. Worked Solutions

TECHNICAL NOTE AUTOMATIC GENERATION OF POINT SPRING SUPPORTS BASED ON DEFINED SOIL PROFILES AND COLUMN-FOOTING PROPERTIES

1 Numbers, Sets, Algebraic Expressions

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Rice University. Answer Key to Mid-Semester Examination Fall ECON 501: Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Part A

Lesson 8: Complex Number Division

PROFIT FUNCTIONS. 1. REPRESENTATION OF TECHNOLOGY 1.1. Technology Sets. The technology set for a given production process is defined as

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Transcription:

Advanced Microeconomic Theory Chapter 4: Production Theory

Outline Production sets and production functions Profit maximization and cost minimization Cost functions Aggregate supply Efficiency (1 st and 2 nd FTWE) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 2

Production Sets and Production Functions Advanced Microeconomic Theory 3

Production Sets Let us define a production vector (or plan) yy = (yy 1, yy 2,, yy LL ) R LL If, for instance, yy 2 > 0, then the firm is producing positive units of good 2 (i.e., good 2 is an output). If, instead, yy 2 < 0, then the firms is producing negative units of good 2 (i.e., good 2 is an input). Production plans that are technologically feasible are represented in the production set YY. YY = yy R LL : FF(yy) 0 where FF(yy) is the transformation function. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 4

Production Sets FF(yy) can also be understood as a production function. Firm uses units of yy 1 as an input in order to produce units of yy 2 as an output. Boundary of the production function is any production plan yy such that FF yy = 0. Also referred to as the transformation frontier. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 5

Production Sets For any production plan yy on the production frontier, such that FF yy = 0, we can totally differentiate FF yy as follows FF yy FF yy ddyy yy kk + ddyy kk yy ll = 0 ll solving ddyy ll ddyy kk = FF yy yy kk FF yy yy ll, where FF yy yy kk FF yy = MMMMMM ll,kk yy yy ll MMMMMM ll,kk yy measures how much the (net) output kk can increase if the firm decreases the (net) output of good ll by one marginal unit. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 6

Production Sets What if we denote input and outputs with different letters? qq = (qq 1, qq 2,, qq MM ) 0 outputs zz = (zz 1, zz 2,, zz LL MM ) 0 inputs where LL MM. In this case, inputs are transformed into outputs by the production function, ff(zz 1, zz 2,, zz LL MM ), i.e., ff: R LL MM R MM. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 7

Production Sets Example: When MM = 1 (one single output), the production set YY can be described as YY = ( zz 1, zz 2,, zz LL 1, qq): qq ff(zz 1, zz 2,, zz LL 1 ) Holding the output level fixed, dddd = 0, totally differentiate production function ff zz ddzz zz kk + ff zz ddzz kk zz ll = 0 ll Advanced Microeconomic Theory 8

Production Sets Example (continued): and rearranging ddzz ll ddzz kk = ff zz zz kk ff zz zz ll, where ff zz zz kk ff zz = MMMMMMMM zz zz ll MMMMMMMM zz measures the additional amount of input kk that must be used when we marginally decrease the amount of input ll, and we want to keep output level at qq = ff zz. MMMMMMMM zz in production theory is analogous to the MMRRSS in consumer theory, where we keep utility constant, dduu = 0. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 9

Production Sets Combinations of (zz 1, zz 2 ) that produce the same total output qq 0, i.e., (zz 1, zz 2 : ff(zz 1, zz 2 ) = qq 0 } is called isoquant. The slope of the isoquant at ( zz 1, zz 2 ) is MMMMMMMM zz. Remember: MMMMMMMMrefers to isoquants (and production function). MMMMMM refers to the transformation function. z 2 Isoquant, Advanced Microeconomic Theory 10 z 1

Production Sets Example: Find themmmmmmmm zz for the Cobb- Douglas production function ff zz 1, zz 2 = zz 1 αα zz 2 ββ, where αα, ββ > 0. The marginal product of input 1 is ff zz 1, zz 2 = ααzz αα 1 ββ zz 1 zz 2 1 and that of input 2 is ff zz 1, zz 2 = ββzz αα ββ 1 zz 1 zz 2 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 11

Production Sets Example (continued): Hence, themmmmmmmm zz is MMMMMMMM zz = ααzz 1 αα 1 ββ zz 2 ββzz αα ββ 1 1 zz = ααzz ββ (ββ 1) 2 αα (αα 1) 2 ββzz = ααzz 2 1 ββzz 1 For instance, for a particular vector zz = zz 1, zz 2 = (2,3), and αα = ββ = 1 2, then MMMMMMMM zz = 3 2 = 1.5 i.e., the slope of the isoquant evaluated at input vector zz = zz 1, = (2,3) is 1.5. zz 2 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 12

Properties of Production Sets 1) Y is nonempty: We have inputs and/or outputs. 2) Y is closed: The production set YY includes its boundary points. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 13

Properties of Production Sets 3) No free lunch: No production with no resources. The firm uses amounts of input yy 1 in order to produce positive amounts of output yy 2. Y y 2 y 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 14

Properties of Production Sets 3) No free lunch: violation The firm produces positive amounts of good 1 and 2 (yy 1 > 0 and yy 2 > 0) without the use of any inputs. Y y 2 2 y Y R + y 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 15

Properties of Production Sets 3) No free lunch: violation The firm produces positive amounts of good 2 (yy 2 > 0) with zero inputs, i.e., yy 1 = 0. Y y 2 2 y Y R + y 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 16

Properties of Production Sets 4) Possibility of inaction Firm can choose to be inactive, using no inputs, and obtaining no output as a result (i.e., 0 YY). Advanced Microeconomic Theory 17

Properties of Production Sets 4) Possibility of inaction y 2 Inaction is still possible when firms face fixed costs (i.e., 0 YY). Set up nonsunk cost Y 0 Y y 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 18

Properties of Production Sets 4) Possibility of inaction y 2 Inaction is NOT possible when firms face sunk costs (i.e., 0 YY). Y Sunk cost 0 Y y 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 19

Properties of Production Sets 5) Free disposal: if yy YY and yy yy, then yy YY. yy is less efficient than yy: Either it produces the same amount of output with more inputs, or less output using the same inputs. Then, yy also belongs to the firm s production set. That is, the producer can use more inputs without the need the reduce his output: The producer can dispose of (or eliminate) this additional inputs at no cost. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 20

Properties of Production Sets 5) Free disposal (continued) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 21

Properties of Production Sets 6) Irreversibility Suppose that yy YY and yy 0. Then, yy YY. y y 2 y 2 No way back -y 1 Y -y 2 y 1 -y Y y 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 22

Properties of Production Sets 7) Non-increasing returns to scale: If yy YY, then αααα YY for any αα 0,1. That is, any feasible vector can be scaled down. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 23

Properties of Production Sets 7) Non-increasing returns to scale The presence of fixed or sunk costs violates non-increasing returns to scale. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 24

Properties of Production Sets 8) Non-decreasing returns to scale: If yy YY, then αααα YY for any αα 1. That is, any feasible vector can be scaled up. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 25

Properties of Production Sets 8) Non-decreasing returns to scale The presence of fixed or sunk costs do NOT violate non-increasing returns to scale. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 26

Properties of Production Sets Returns to scale: When scaling up/down a given production plan yy = yy 1, yy 2 : We connect yy with a ray from the origin. Then, the ratio yy 2 must yy 1 be maintained in all points along the ray. Note that the angle of the ray is exactly this ratio yy 2. yy 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 27

Properties of Production Sets 9) Constant returns to scale (CRS): If yy YY, then αααα YY for any αα 0. CRS is non-increasing and non-decreasing. αy, if α > 1 Y y y 2 αy, if α < 1 y 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 28

Properties of Production Sets Alternative graphical representation of constant returns to scale: Doubling KK and LL doubles output (i.e., proportionally increase in output). K 2 1 1 2 Q=200 Q=100 L Advanced Microeconomic Theory 29

Properties of Production Sets Alternative graphical representation of increasing-returns to scale: Doubling KK and LL increases output more than proportionally. K 2 1 1 2 Q=300 Q=200 Q=100 L Advanced Microeconomic Theory 30

Properties of Production Sets Alternative graphical representation of decreasing-returns to scale: Doubling KK and LL increases output less than proportionally. K 2 1 Q=200 Q=150 Q=100 1 2 L Advanced Microeconomic Theory 31

Properties of Production Sets Example: Let us check returns to scale in the Cobb- Douglas production function ff zz 1, zz 2 = zz 1 αα zz 2 ββ. Increasing all arguments by a common factor λλ, we obtain ff zz 1, zz 2 = (λλzz 1 ) αα (λλzz 2 ) ββ = λλ αα+ββ zz 1 αα zz 2 ββ When αα + ββ = 1, we have constant returns to scale; When αα + ββ > 1, we have increasing returns to scale; When αα + ββ < 1, we have decreasing returns to scale. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 32

Properties of Production Sets Returns to scale in different US industries (Source: Hsieh, 1995): Industry αα + ββ Decreasing returns Tobacco 0.51 Food 0.91 Constant returns Apparel and textile 1.01 Furniture 1.02 Electronics 1.02 Increasing returns Paper products 1.09 Petroleum and coal 1.18 Primary metal 1.24 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 33

Properties of Production Sets Homogeneity of the Production Function KK = 1 KK > 1 KK < 1 Returns to Scale Constant Returns Increasing Returns Decreasing Returns Advanced Microeconomic Theory 34

Properties of Production Sets The linear production function exhibits CRS as increasing all inputs by a common factor tt yields ff tttt, tttt = aaaaaa + bbbbbb = tt aaaa + bbbb tttt(kk, ll) The fixed proportion production function ff kk, ll = min{aaaa, bbbb} also exhibits CRS as ff tttt, tttt = min aattkk, bbbbbb = tt min aaaa, bbbb tttt(kk, ll) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 35

Properties of Production Sets Increasing/decreasing returns to scale can be incorporated into a production function ff(kk, ll) exhibiting CRS by using a transformation function FF( ) FF kk, ll = ff(kk, ll) γγ, where γγ > 0 Indeed, increasing all arguments by a common factor tt, yields by CRS of ff( ) γγ FF ttkk, ttll = ff(ttkk, ttll) γγ = tt ff(kk, ll) = tt γγ ff kk, ll γγ FF kk,ll = tt γγ FF kk, ll Advanced Microeconomic Theory 36

Properties of Production Sets Hence, if γγ > 1, the transformed production function FF kk, ll exhibits increasing returns to scale; if γγ < 1, the transformed production function FF kk, ll exhibits decreasing returns to scale; Advanced Microeconomic Theory 37

Properties of Production Sets Scale elasticity: an alternative measure of returns to scale. It measures the percent increase in output due to a 1% increase in the amounts of all inputs εε qq,tt = ff(tttt, tttt) tt ff(kk, ll) where tt denotes the common increase in all inputs. Practice: Show that, if a function exhibits CRS, then it has a scale elasticity of εε qq,tt =1. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 38

Properties of Production Sets 10) Additivity (or free entry): If yy YY and yy YY, then yy + yy YY. Interpretation: one plant produces yy, while another plant enters the market producing yy. Then, the aggregate production yy + yy is feasible. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 39

Properties of Production Sets 11) Convexity: If yy, yy YY and αα 0,1, then αααα + (1 αα)yy YY. y y 2 αy+ (1 α) y' Y Intuition: balanced input-output combinations are more productive than unbalanced ones. αy+ (1 α) y' y' y' y 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 40

Properties of Production Sets 11) Convexity: violation y y 2 Note: The convexity of the production set maintains a close relationship with the concavity of the production function. α y αy+ (1 α) y' Y y' Y y 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 41

Properties of Production Sets 11) Convexity With fixed costs, convexity is NOT necessarily satisfied; With sunk costs, convexity is satisfied. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 42

Diminishing MRTS The slope of the firm s isoquants is MMMMMMMM ll,kk = dddd dddd, where MMMMMMMM ll,kk = ff ll ff kk Differentiating MMMMMMMM ll,kk with respect to labor yields MMMMMMMM ll,kk ll = ff kk ff llll + ff llkk dddd dddd ff ll ff kk 2 ff kkkk + ff kkkk dddd dddd Advanced Microeconomic Theory 43

Diminishing MRTS Using the fact that dddd dddd = ff ll ff kk along an isoquant and Young s theorem ff llkk = ff kkll, MMMMMMMM ll,kk = = ff kk ff llll ff llll ff ll ff kk ff ll ff kkkk ff kkkk ff ll ff kk ff 2 kk ff kk ff llll ff llll ff ll ff ll ff kkkk + ff kkkk ff ll 2 ff kk 2 ff kk Advanced Microeconomic Theory 44

Diminishing MRTS Multiplying numerator and denominator by ff kk + + + or+ 2 MMMMMMMM ll,kk ff = kk ff llll + ff ffll 2 kkkk 2ff ll ff kk ff llll ff 3 kk Thus, If ff llll > 0 (i.e., kk MMPP ll ), then MMMMMMMM ll,kk If ff llll < 0, then we have ff kk 2 ff llll + ff kkkk ff ll 2 > < 2ff llff kk ff llll MMMMMMMM ll,kk < 0 < > 0 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 45

Diminishing MRTS ff llll > 0 ( kk MMMM ll ), or ff llll < 0 ( kk MMMM ll ) but small in MMMM ll ff llll < 0 ( kk MMMM ll ) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 46

Diminishing MRTS Example: Let us check if the production function ff kk, ll = 600kk 2 ll 2 kk 3 ll 3 yields convex isoquants. Marginal products: MMMM ll = ff ll = 1,200kk 2 ll 3kk 3 ll 2 > 0 iff kkll < 400 MMMM kk = ff kk = 1,200kkll 2 3kk 2 ll 3 > 0 iff kkkk < 400 Decreasing marginal productivity: MMMM ll ll = ff llll = 1,200kk 2 6kk 3 ll < 0 iff kkkk > 200 MMMM kk kk = ff kkkk = 1,200ll 2 6kkll 3 < 0 iff kkkk > 200 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 47

Diminishing MRTS Example (continued): Is 200 < kkkk < 400 then sufficient condition for diminishing MMMMMMMM? No! We need ff kkkk > 0 too in order to guarantee diminishing MMMMMMMM ll,kk. Check the sign of ff llll : ff llll = ff kkll = 2,400kkkk 9kk 2 ll 2 > 0 iff kkkk < 266 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 48

Diminishing MRTS Example (continued): Alternatively, we can represent the above conditions by solving for ll in the above inequalities: MMMM ll > 0 iff ll < 400 kk MMMM kk > 0 iff ll < 400 kk and MMMM ll MMMM kk ff llll > 0 iff ll < 266 kk < 0 iff ll > 200 kk 200 < 0 iff ll > kk Advanced Microeconomic Theory 49

Diminishing MRTS Example (continued): Hence, 200 kk < ll < 266 kk guarantees positive but diminishing marginal products and, in addition, a diminishing MMMMMMMM. Figure: ll = 200 kk is a curve decreasing in kk, never crossing either axes. Similarly for ll = 266 kk. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 50

Constant Returns to Scale If production function ff(kk, ll) exhibits CRS, then increasing all inputs by a common factor tt yields ff kk, ll = tttt kk, ll Hence, ff(kk, ll) is homogenous of degree 1, thus implying that its first-order derivatives ff kk kk, ll and ff ll kk, ll are homogenous of degree zero. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 51

Constant Returns to Scale Therefore, (kk, ll) (tttt, tttt) MMMM ll = = = ff ll kk, ll = ff ll tttt, tttt Setting tt = 1, we obtain ll 1 MMMM ll = ff ll kk, ll = ff ll ll kk, kk kk = ff ll kk ll, 1 Hence, MMMM ll only depends on the ratio kk, but not ll on the absolute levels of kk and ll that firm uses. A similar argument applies to MMMM kk. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 52

Constant Returns to Scale Thus, MMMMMMMM = MMMM ll MMMM kk only depends on the ratio of capital to labor. The slope of a firm s isoquants coincides at any point along a ray from the origin. Firm s production function is, hence, homothetic. K q=2 Ray from the origin Same MRTS l,k q=3 q=4 L Advanced Microeconomic Theory 53

Elasticity of Substitution Advanced Microeconomic Theory 54

Elasticity of Substitution Elasticity of substitution (σσ) measures the proportionate change in the kk/ll ratio relative to the proportionate change in the MMMMMMMM ll,kk along an isoquant: σσ = % (kk/ll) % MMMMMMMM = dd(kk/ll) ddmmmmmmmm MMMMMMMM kk/ll = ln(kk/ll) ln(mmmmmmmm) where σσ > 0 since ratio kk/ll and MMMMMMMM move in the same direction. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 55

Elasticity of Substitution BothMMMMMMMM and kk/ll will change as we move from point AA to point BB. σσ is the ratio of these changes. K A MRTS A B MRTS B q= q 0 σσ measures the curvature of the isoquant. (k/l) B (k/l) A L Advanced Microeconomic Theory 56

Elasticity of Substitution If we define the elasticity of substitution between two inputs to be proportionate change in the ratio of the two inputs to the proportionate change in MMMMMMMM, we need to hold: output constant (so we move along the same isoquant), and the levels of other inputs constant (in case we have more than two inputs). For instance, we fix the amount of other inputs, such as land. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 57

Elasticity of Substitution High elasticity of substitution (σσ): K MMMMMMMM does not change substantially relative to kk/ll. A MRTS A MRTS B Isoquant is relatively flat. (k/l) A B q= q 0 (k/l) B L Advanced Microeconomic Theory 58

Elasticity of Substitution Low elasticity of substitution (σσ): MMMMMMMM changes substantially relative to kk/ll. K A MRTS A MRTS B Isoquant is relatively sharply curved. (k/l) A B q= q 0 (k/l) B L Advanced Microeconomic Theory 59

Elasticity of Substitution: Linear Production Function Suppose that the production function is qq = ff kk, ll = aaaa + bbbb This production function exhibits constant returns to scale ff ttkk, ttll = aaaaaa + bbbbbb = tt aaaa + bbbb = tttt(kk, ll) Solving for kk in qq, we get kk = ff All isoquants are straight lines kk and ll are perfect substitutes kk,ll aa bb aa ll. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 60

Elasticity of Substitution: Linear Production Function MMMMMMMM (slope of the isoquant) is constant as kk/ll changes. σσ = % (kk/ll) % MMMMMMMM 0 = This production function satisfies homotheticity. K q 1 Slope=-b/a q 2 q 3 L Advanced Microeconomic Theory 61

Elasticity of Substitution: Fixed Proportions Production Function Suppose that the production function is qq = min aakk, bbll aa, bb > 0 Capital and labor must always be used in a fixed ratio No substitution between kk and ll The firm will always operate along a ray where kk/ll is constant (i.e., at the kink!). Because kk/ll is constant (bb/aa), σσ = % (kk/ll) % MMMMMMMM = 0 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 62

Elasticity of Substitution: Fixed Proportions Production Function MMMMMMMM = for ll before the kink of the isoquant. K MMMMMMMM = 0 for ll after the kink. q 3 /a q 3 This production function also satisfies homotheticity. q 3 /b q 1 q 2 L Advanced Microeconomic Theory 63

Elasticity of Substitution: Cobb-Douglas Production Function Suppose that the production function is qq = ff kk, ll = AAkk aa ll bb where AA, aa, bb > 0 This production function can exhibit any returns to scale ff ttkk, ttll = AA(tttt) aa (tttt) bb = AAtt aa+bb kk aa ll bb = tt aa+bb ff(kk, ll) If aa + bb = 1 constant returns to scale If aa + bb > 1 increasing returns to scale If aa + bb < 1 decreasing returns to scale Advanced Microeconomic Theory 64

Elasticity of Substitution: Cobb-Douglas Production Function The Cobb-Douglass production function is linear in logarithms ln qq = ln AA + aa ln kk + bb ln ll aa is the elasticity of output with respect to kk εε qq,kk = ln(qq) ln(kk) bb is the elasticity of output with respect to ll εε qq,ll = ln(qq) ln(ll) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 65

Elasticity of Substitution: Cobb-Douglas Production Function The elasticity of substitution (σσ) for the Cobb- Douglas production function: First, MMMMMMMM = MMMM ll MMMM kk = Hence, ll kk = bbbbkkaa ll bb 1 aaaakk aa 1 ll bb = bb aa kk ll ln(mmmmmmmm) = ln bb aa + ln kk ll Advanced Microeconomic Theory 66

Elasticity of Substitution: Cobb-Douglas Production Function Solving for ln kk ll, ln kk ll = ln MMMMMMMM ln bb aa Therefore, the elasticity of substitution between kk and ll is dd ln kk ll σσ = dd ln MMMMMMMM = 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 67

Elasticity of Substitution: CES Production Function Suppose that the production function is qq = ff kk, ll = kk ρρ ρρ γγ/ρρ + ll where ρρ 1, ρρ 0, γγ > 0 γγ = 1 constant returns to scale γγ > 1 increasing returns to scale γγ < 1 decreasing returns to scale Alternative representation of the CES function σσ 1 σσ ff kk, ll = aakk σσ 1 σσ + bbll σσ 1 σσ where σσ is the elasticity of substitution. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 68

Elasticity of Substitution: CES Production Function The elasticity of substitution (σσ) for the CES production function: First, MMMMMMMM = MMMM ll MMMM kk = ρρ 1 1 ρρ = γγ ρρ kkρρ + ll ρρ γγ ρρ kkρρ + ll ρρ γγ ρρ 1 ρρll ρρ 1 γγ ρρ 1 ρρkk ρρ 1 = ll kk = kk ll Advanced Microeconomic Theory 69

Hence, Elasticity of Substitution: CES Production Function ln(mmmmmmmm) = ρρ 1 ln kk ll Solving for ln kk, ll ln kk = 1 ln MMMMMMMM ll ρρ 1 Therefore, the elasticity of substitution between kk and ll is σσ = dd ln kk ll dd ln MMMMMMMM = 1 ρρ 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 70

Elasticity of Substitution: CES Production Function Elasticity of Substitution in German Industries (Source: Kemfert, 1998): Industry σσ Food 0.66 Iron 0.50 Chemicals 0.37 Motor Vehicles 0.10 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 71

Elasticity of Substitution The elasticity of substitution σσ between kk and ll is decreasing in scale (i.e., as qq increases). qq 0 and qq 1 have very high σσ K q 6 q 4 q 5 q 3 qq 5 and qq 6 have very low σσ q 0 q 1 q 2 L Advanced Microeconomic Theory 72

Elasticity of Substitution The elasticity of substitution σσ between kk and ll is increasing in scale (i.e., as qq increases). qq 0 and qq 1 have very low σσ qq 2 and qq 3 have very high σσ Advanced Microeconomic Theory 73

Profit Maximization Advanced Microeconomic Theory 74

Profit Maximization Assumptions: Firms are price takers: the production plans of an individual firm do not alter price levels pp = pp 1, pp 2,, pp LL 0. The production set satisfies: non-emptiness, closedness, and free-disposal. Profit maximization problem (PMP): max pp yy yy s.t. yy YY, or alternatively, FF(yy) 0 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 75

Profit Maximization Profit function ππ(pp) associates to every pp the highest amount of profits (i.e., ππ(pp) is the value function of the PMP) ππ pp = max yy pp yy: yy YY And the supply correspondence yy(pp) is the argmax of the PMP, yy pp = yy YY: pp yy = ππ pp where positive components in the vector yy pp is output supplied by the firm to the market, while negative components are inputs in its production process. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 76

Profit Maximization Isoprofit line: combinations of inputs and output for which the firm obtains a given level of profits. Note that ππ 0 = pp 2 yy 2 pp 1 yy 1 Solving for yy 2 yy 2 = ππ 0 pp 2 intercept pp 1 yy pp 1 2 { y: F( y) 0} y = Increasing profit slope Advanced Microeconomic Theory 77 y 2 F( y) y(p) Supply correspondence slope = MRT ( ) 1,2 y y 1 py py π 2 2 1 1 = '' py 2 2 py 1 1 = π '

Profit Maximization We can rewrite the PMP as max yy FF(yy) pp yy with associated Lagrangian LL = pp yy λλff(yy) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 78

Profit Maximization Taking FOCs with respect to every yy kk, we obtain pp kk λλ (yy ) yy kk 0 where FF(yy ) is evaluated at the optimum, i.e., FF yy = FF(yy(pp)). For interior solutions, pp kk = λλ (yy ), or in matrix yy kk notation pp = λλ yy FF(yy ) that is, the price vector and the gradient vector are proportional. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 79

Profit Maximization Solving for λλ, we obtain λλ = pp kk (yy ) yy kk for every good kk ppkk which can also be expressed as pp kk pp ll = (yy ) yy kk (yy ) yy ll (= MMMMMM kk,ll (yy )) yy kk yy ll (yy ) = ppll (yy ) Graphically, the slope of the transformation frontier (at the profit maximization production plan yy ), MMMMMM kk,ll (yy ), coincides with the price ratio, pp kk pp ll. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 80

Profit Maximization Are there PMPs with no supply correspondence yy pp, i.e., there is no well defined profit maximizing vector? Yes. Example: qq = ff zz = zz (i.e., every unit of input zz is transformed into a unit of output qq) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 81

Profit Maximization: Single Output Production function, qq = ff zz, produces a single output from a vector zz of inputs. pppp zz wwww max zz 0 The first-order conditions are pp ff(yy ) ww zz kk or pp MMMM zzkk ww kk kk For interior solutions, the market value of the marginal product obtained form using additional units of this input kk, pp (yy ), must coincide with zz kk the price of this input, ww kk. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 82

Profit Maximization: Single Output Note that for any two input, this implies Hence, or ww kk ww ll = pp = (zz ) zz kk (zz ) zz ll ww kk (yy ) zz kk for every good kk = MMMMzzkk MMMM zzll (= MMMMMMSS zzkk,zz ll (zz )) MMMM zzkk = MMMM zz ll ww zzkk ww zzll Intuition: Marginal productivity per dollar spent on input zz kk is equal to that spent on input zz ll. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 83

Profit Maximization Example : Are there PMPs with no supply correspondence yy(pp), i.e., there is no well defined profit maximizing vector? Yes. If the input price pp zz satisfies pp zz pp, then qq = 0 and ππ pp = 0. If the input price pp zz satisfies pp zz < pp, then qq = + and ππ pp = +. In this case, the supply correspondence is not well defined, since you can always increase input usage, thus increasing profits. Exception: if input usage is constrained in the interval 0, zz, then yy pp is at the corner solution yy pp = zz, thus implying that the PMP is well defined. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 84

Profit Maximization Example (continued): f(z)=q q=f(z) Increasing profit f(z)=q q=f(z) Increasing profit y(p)=0 z z z If pp zz < pp, the firm can qq and ππ. If pp zz > pp, the firm chooses qq = yy pp = 0 with ππ pp = 0. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 85

Profit Maximization: Single Output When are these FOCs also sufficient? When the production set YY is convex! Let s see. Isocost line for the firm is ww 1 zz 1 + ww 2 zz 2 = Solving for zz 2 zz2 = cc ww 2 intercept cc ww 1 zz ww 1 2 slope Advanced Microeconomic Theory 86

Profit Maximization: Single Output Convex production set The FOCs (necessary) of MMRRRRRR = ww 1 ww 2 are also sufficient. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 87

Profit Maximization: Single Output Non-convex production set the FOCs are NOT sufficient for a combination of (zz 1, zz 2 ) that maximize profits. the profit-maximizing vector (zz 1, zz 2 ) is at a corner solution, where the firm uses zz 2 alone. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 88

Profit Maximization: Single Output Example: Cobb-Douglas production function On your own: Solve PMP (differentiating with respect to zz 1 and zz 2. Find optimal input usage zz 1 (ww, qq) and zz 2 (ww, qq). These are referred to as conditional factor demand correspondences Plug them into the production function to obtain the value function, i.e., the output that arises when the firm uses its profit-maximizing input combination. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 89

Properties of Profit Function Assume that the production set YY is closed and satisfies the free disposal property. 1) Homog(1) in prices ππ λλλλ = λλππ pp Increasing the prices of all inputs and outputs by a common factor λλ produces a proportional increase in the firm s profits. ππ pp = pppp ww 1 zz 1 ww nn zz nn Scaling all prices by a common factor, we obtain ππ λλλλ = λλλλλλ λλww 1 zz 1 λλww nn zz nn = λλ pppp ww 1 zz 1 ww nn zz nn = λλππ pp Advanced Microeconomic Theory 90

Properties of Profit Function 2) Convex in output prices Intuition: the firm obtains more profits from balanced inputoutput combinations, than from unbalanced combinations. q=f(z) y(p ) Y y( p) q y(p) z Price vector Production plan Profits pp yy(pp) ππ pp pp yy(pp ) ππ pp pp yy( pp) ππ pp = αααα pp + 1 αα ππ pp Advanced Microeconomic Theory 91

Properties of Profit Function 3) If the production set YY is convex, then YY = yy R LL : pp yy ππ pp for all pp 0 Intuition: the production set YY can be represented by this dual set. This dual set specifies that, for any given prices pp, all production vectors yy generate less profits pp yy, than the optimal production plan yy(pp) in the profit function ππ pp = pp yy(pp). Advanced Microeconomic Theory 92

Properties of Profit Function All production plans zz, qq below the isoprofit line yield a lower profit level: pppp wwww ππ pp The isoprofit line ππ pp = pppp wwww can be expressed as q=f(z) π = p q w z y(p) Y q { y 2 : p q w z π ( p) } qq = ππ pp + ww pp zz If ww is constant ππ z pp is convex. What if it is not constant? Let s see next. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 93

Properties of Profit Function a) Input prices are a function of input usage, i.e., ww = ff(zz), where ff (zz) 0. Then, either i. ff zz < 0, and the firm gets a price discount per unit of input from suppliers when ordering large amounts of inputs (e.g., loans) ii. ff zz > 0, and the firm has to pay more per unit of input when ordering large amounts of inputs (e.g., scarce qualified labor) b) Output prices are a function of production, i.e., pp = gg(qq), where gg (qq) 0. Then, either i. ggg(qq) < 0, and the firm offers price discounts to its customers. ii. ggg(qq) > 0, and the firm applies price surcharges to its customers. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 94

Properties of Profit Function If ff zz < 0, then we have strictly convex isoprofit curves. If ff zz > 0, then we have strictly concave isoprofit curves. If ff zz = 0, then we have straight isoprofit curves. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 95

Remarks on Profit Function Remark 1: the profit function is a value function, measuring firm profits only for the profitmaximizing vector yy. Remark 2: the profit function can be understood as a support function. Take negative of the production set YY, i.e., YY Then, the support function of YY set is μμ YY pp = min pp yy : yy YY yy That is, take the profits resulting form all production vectors yy YY, pp yy, then take the negative of all these profits, pp yy, and then choose the smallest one. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 96

Remarks on Profit Function Of course, this is the same as maximizing the (positive) value of the profits resulting from all production vector yy YY, pp yy. Therefore, the profit function, ππ(pp), is the support of the negative production set, YY, ππ pp = μμ YY pp Advanced Microeconomic Theory 97

Remarks on Profit Function Alternatively, the argmax of any objective function yy 1 = arg max yy ff(xx) coincides with the argmin of the negative of this objective function yy 2 = arg max yy where yy 1 = yy 2. ff(xx) q = f( z) { y: p y π ( p) } y(p) y 2 y(p ) y 1 { y: p' y π ( p') } Advanced Microeconomic Theory 98

Properties of Supply Correspondence 1) If YY is weakly convex, then yy(pp) is a convex set for all pp. y 2 YY has a flat surface yy(pp) is NOT single valued. y(p),straight segment of Y y 1 { y: p y =π ( p) } Advanced Microeconomic Theory 99

Properties of Supply Correspondence 1) (continued) If YY is strictly convex, then yy(pp) is single-valued (if nonempty). q = f( z) y 2 Unique y(p) y 1 { y: p y =π ( p) } Advanced Microeconomic Theory 100

Properties of Supply Correspondence 2) Hotelling s Lemma: If yy( pp) consists of a single point, then ππ( ) is differentiable at pp. Moreover, pp ππ pp = yy( pp). This is an application of the duality theorem from consumer theory. If yy( ) is a function differentiable at pp, then DD pp yy( pp) = DD 2 pp ππ pp is a symmetric and positive semidefinite matrix, with DD pp ππ pp pp = 0. This is a direct consequence of the law of supply. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 101

Properties of Supply Correspondence Since DD pp ππ pp pp = 0, DD pp yy( pp) must satisfy: Own substitution effects (main diagonal elements in DD pp yy( pp)) are non-negative, i.e., yy kk (pp) pp kk 0 for all kk Cross substitution effects (off diagonal elements in DD pp yy( pp)) are symmetric, i.e., yy ll (pp) pp kk = yy kk(pp) pp ll for all ll and kk Advanced Microeconomic Theory 102

Properties of Supply Correspondence yy kk(pp) pp kk 0, which implies that quantities and prices move in the same direction, (pp ppp)(yy yyy) 0 The law of supply holds! Advanced Microeconomic Theory 103

Properties of Supply Correspondence Since there is no budget constraint, there is no wealth compensation requirement (as opposed to Demand theory). This implies that there no income effects, only substitution effects. Alternatively, from a revealed preference argument, the law of supply can be expressed as pp pp yy yy = ppyy ppyy + pp yy pp yy 0 where yy yy(pp) and yy yy(pp ). Advanced Microeconomic Theory 104

Cost Minimization Advanced Microeconomic Theory 105

Cost Minimization We focus on the single output case, where zz is the input vector ff(zz) is the production function qq are the units of the (single) output ww 0 is the vector of input prices The cost minimization problem (CMP) is min ww zz zz 0 s. t. ff(zz) qq Advanced Microeconomic Theory 106

Cost Minimization The optimal vector of input (or factor) choices is zz(ww, qq), and is known as the conditional factor demand correspondence. If single-valued, zz ww, qq is a function (not a correspondence) Why conditional? Because it represents the firm s demand for inputs, conditional on reaching output level qq. The value function of this CMP cc ww, qq is the cost function. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 107

Cost Minimization z 2 Cost minimization w slope = w 1 2 zwq (, ) { z: w z cwq (, )} Isoquant f(z)=q = { z: w z> cwq (, )} z 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 108

Cost Minimization Graphically, For a given isoquant ff zz = qq, choose the isocost line associated with the lowest cost ww zz. The tangency point is zz ww, qq. The isocost line associated with that combination of inputs is zz: ww zz = cc ww, qq where the cost function cc ww, qq represents the lowest cost of producing output level qq when input prices are ww. Other isocost lines are associated with either: output levels higher than qq (with costs exceeding cc ww, qq ), or output levels lower than qq (with costs below cc ww, qq ). Advanced Microeconomic Theory 109

Cost Minimization The Lagrangian of the CMP is L zz; λλ = wwww + λλ[qq ff zz ] Differentiating with respect to zz kk ww kk λλ (zz ) zz kk 0 (= 0 if interior solution, zz kk ) or in matrix notation ww λλ ff(zz ) 0 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 110

Cost Minimization From the above FOCs, ww kk (zz ) zz kk Alternatively, = λλ ww kk ww ll = zz zz kk zz zz kk zz zz ll (= MMRRRRRR(zz )) zz zz ll ww ll = ww kk at the cost-minimizing input combination, the marginal product per dollar spent on input kk must be equal that of input ll. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 111

Cost Minimization Sufficiency: If the production set is convex, then the FOCs are also sufficient. A non-convex production set: The input combinations satisfying the FOCs are NOT a cost-minimizing input combination zz(ww, qq). The cost-minimizing combination of inputs zz(ww, qq) occurs at the corner. z 2 Cost-minimizing, z(w,q) Isoprofit line z: w z= cˆ, where cˆ > cwq (, ) { z: w z= cwq (, )} { } Advanced Microeconomic Theory 112 ẑ z 1

Cost Minimization Lagrange multiplier: λλ can be interpreted as the cost increase that the firm experiences when it needs to produce a higher level qq. Recall that, generally, the Lagrange multiplier represents the variation in the objective function that we obtain if we relax the constraint (e.g., wealth in UMP, utility level we must reach in the EMP). Therefore, λλ is the marginal cost of production: the marginal increase in the firm s costs form producing additional units. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 113

Cost Minimization: SE and OE Effects Comparative statics of zz(ww, qq): Let us analyze the effects of an input price change. Consider two inputs, e.g., labor and capital. When the price of labor, ww, falls, two effects occur: Substitution effect: if output is held constant, there will be a tendency for the firm to substitute ll for kk. Output effect: a reduction in firm s costs allows it to produce larger amounts of output (i.e., higher isoquant), which entails the use of more units of ll for kk. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 114

Cost Minimization: SE and OE Effects Substitution effect: zz 0 (ww, qq) solves CMP at the initial prices. in wages isocost line pivots outwards. To reach qq, push the new isocost inwards in a parallel fashion. zz 1 (ww, qq) solves CMP at the new input prices (for output level qq). At zz 1 (ww, qq), firm uses more ll and less kk. K z 0 (w,q) z 1 (w,q) Substitution effect 2 nd step w 1 st step f(z)=q, isoquant L Advanced Microeconomic Theory 115

Cost Minimization: SE and OE Effects Substitution effect (SE): increase in labor demand from LL AA to LL BB. same output as before the input price change. Output effect (OE): increase in labor demand from LL BB to LL CC. output level increases, total cost is the same as before the input price change. K TC r K A K B K C A L A L B TC L C 0 w TE OE SE (2 nd step) (1 st step) f(z)=q 0, isoquant Advanced Microeconomic Theory 116 B 3 rd step C TC w w 1 f(z)=q 1, where q 1 >q 0 L

Cost Minimization: Own-Price Effect We have two concepts of demand for any input the conditional demand for labor, ll cc (rr, ww, qq) ll cc (rr, ww, qq) solves the CMP the unconditional demand for labor, ll(pp, rr, ww) ll(pp, rr, ww) solves the PMP At the profit-maximizing level of output, i.e., qq(pp, rr, ww), the two must coincide ll pp, rr, ww = ll cc rr, ww, qq = ll cc (rr, ww, qq(pp, rr, ww)) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 117

Cost Minimization: Own-Price Effect Differentiating with respect to ww yields pp, rr, ww = llcc rr, ww, qq SSSS ( ) (+) + llcc (rr, ww, qq) TTTT ( ) OOOO ( ) ( ) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 118

Cost Minimization: Own-Price Effect Since TTTT > SSSS, the unconditional labor demand is flatter than the conditional labor demand. Both SSSS and OOOO are negative. Giffen paradox from consumer theory cannot arise in production theory. w l c (v,w,q 1 ) l c (v,w,q 2 ) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 119 A SE B OE TE C z

Cost Minimization: Cross-Price Effect No definite statement can be made about crossprice (CP) effects. A fall in the wage will lead the firm to substitute away from capital. The output effect will cause more capital to be demanded as the firm expands production. pp, rr, ww CCCC TTTT + or ( ) = kkcc rr, ww, qq CCCC SSSS (+) (+) + kkcc (rr, ww, qq) CCCC OOOO ( ) ( ) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 120

Cost Minimization: Cross-Price Effect The + cross-price OE completely offsets the cross-price SE, leading to a positive cross-price TE. w w w w 1 B (,, ) c c k rwq1 k rwq2 A C (,, ) k( prw,, ) SE OE TE K Advanced Microeconomic Theory 121

Cost Minimization: Cross-Price Effect The + cross-price OE only partially offsets the crossprice SE, leading to a negative cross-price TE. w w w w 1 B c k A C (, rwq, ) 1 c k (, rwq, ) 2 k( prw,, ) SE OE TE K Advanced Microeconomic Theory 122

Properties of Cost Function Assume that the production set YY is closed and satisfies the free disposal property. 1) cc(ww, qq) is Homog(1) in ww That is, increasing all input prices by a common factor λλ yields a proportional increase in the minimal costs of production: cc λλww, qq = λλcc(ww, qq) since cc(ww, qq) represents the minimal cost of producing a given output qq at input prices ww. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 123

Properties of Cost Function An increase in all input prices (w 1, w 2 ) by the same proportion λ, produces a parallel downward shift in the firm's isocost line. z 2 c( λwq, ) cwq (, ) = λw w 2 2 w 2 cwq (, ) λw 2 zwq (, ) f(z)=q cwq (, ) λw 1 w 1 c( λwq, ) cwq (, ) = λw w 1 1 z 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 124

Properties of Cost Function 2) cc(ww, qq) is non-decreasing in qq. Producing higher output levels implies a weakly higher minimal cost of production z 2 cwq (, 1) w 2 If qq 1 > qq 0, then it must be cc(ww, qq 1 ) > cc(ww, qq 0 ) cwq (, 0) w 2 zwq (, 0) zwq (, 1) f(z)=q 0 f(z)=q 1 cwq (, 0) w 1 cwq (, 1) w 1 z 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 125

Properties of Cost Function 3) If the set zz 0: ff(zz) qq is convex for every qq, then the production set can be described as YY = zz, qq : ww zz cc ww, qq for every ww 0 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 126

Properties of Cost Function Take ff zz = qq. For input prices ww = (ww 1, ww 2 ), find cc(ww, qq) by solving CMP. For input prices ww = (ww 1, ww 2 ), find cc(ww, qq) by solving CMP. The intersection of more costly input combinations ww zz cc ww, qq, for every input prices ww 0, describes set ff zz qq. z 2 w1 slope = w 2 z(w,q) { z: w z= cwq (, )} z(w,q) w1 ' slope = w ' 2 f(z)=q 0 { z: w' z= cw ( ', q) } z 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 127

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence 1) zz(ww, qq) is Homog(0) in ww. That is, increasing input prices by the same factor λλ does not alter the firm s demand for inputs at all, zz λλww, qq = zz(ww, qq) z 2 cwq (, ) w Isocost curve 2 cwq (, ) λw 2 { z 0: f( z) q} cwq (, ) λw 1 z(w,q)=(z 1 (w,q),z 2 (w,q)) cwq (, ) w 1 Isoquant f(z)=q z 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 128

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence 2) If the set { zz 0: ff(zz) qq} is strictly convex, then the firm's demand correspondence zz(ww, qq) is single valued. z 2 Isocost curve Unique z(w,q) { z 0: f( z) q} Isoquant f(z)=q z 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 129

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence 2) (continued) If the set { zz 0: ff(zz) qq} is weakly convex, then the demand correspondence zz(ww, qq) is not a single-valued, but a convex set. z 2 Isocost curve Set of z(w,q) { z 0: f( z) q} Isoquant f(z)=q z 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 130

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence 3) Shepard s lemma: If zz( ww,qq) consists of a single point, then cc(ww, qq) is differentiable with respect to ww at, ww, and ww cc ww,qq = zz( ww,qq) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 131

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence 4) If zz(ww, qq) is differentiable at ww, then DD 2 ww cc ww, qq = DD ww zz ww, qq is a symmetric and negative semidefinite matrix, with DD ww zz ww, qq ww = 0. DD ww zz ww, qq is a matrix representing how the firm s demand for every unit responds to changes in the price of such input, or in the price of the other inputs. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 132

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence 4) (continued) Own substitution effects are non-positive, zz kk (ww,qq) ww kk 0 for every input kk i.e., if the price of input kk increases, the firm s factor demand for this input decreases. Cross substitution effects are symmetric, zz kk (ww,qq) ww ll = zz ll(ww,qq) ww kk for all inputs kk and ll Advanced Microeconomic Theory 133

Properties of Production Function 1) If ff(zz) is Homog(1) (i.e., if ff(zz) exhibits constant returns to scale), then cc(ww, qq) and zz(ww, qq) are Homog(1) in qq. Intuitively, if ff(zz) exhibits CRS, then an increase in the output level we seek to reach induces an increase of the same proportion in the cost function and in the demand for inputs. That is, cc ww, λλqq = λλcc(ww, qq) and zz ww, λλqq = λλzz(ww, qq) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 134

Properties of Production Function λλ = 2 implies that demand for inputs doubles zz ww, 2qq = 2zz(ww, qq) and that minimal costs also double cc ww, 2qq = 2cc ww, qq λ=2 z 2 2 1 z(w,q )=2z(w,q) q'=20units z(w,q) q=10units 1 2 c(w,q) λ=2 z 1 c(w,q')=2c(w,q) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 135

Properties of Production Function 2) If ff(zz) is concave, then cc(ww, qq) is convex function of qq (i.e., marginal costs are nondecreasing in qq). More compactly, 2 cc(ww, qq) qq 2 0 or, in other words, marginal costs cc(ww,qq) qq are weakly increasing in qq. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 136

Properties of Production Function 2) (continued) Firm uses more inputs when raising output from qq 2 to qq 3 than from qq 1 to qq 2. Hence, cc(ww, qq 3 ) cc(ww, qq 2 ) > cc(ww, qq 2 ) cc(ww, qq 1 ) This reflects the convexity of the cost function cc(ww, qq) with respect to qq. z 2 3 z 2 2 z 2 1 z 2 1 z 1 z(w,q 1 ) z(w,q 2 ) 2 z 1 q 1 =10units c(w,q 1 ) z(w,q 3 ) 3 z 1 q 2 =20units c(w,q 2 ) q 3 =30units c(w,q 3 ) z 1 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 137

Alternative Representation of PMP Advanced Microeconomic Theory 138

Alternative Representation of PMP Using the cost function cc(ww, qq), we write the PMP as follows max ppqq cc(ww, qq) qq 0 This is useful if we have information about the cost function, but we don t about the production function qq = ff zz. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 139

Alternative Representation of PMP Let us now solve this alternative PMP ppqq cc(ww, qq) max qq 0 FOCs for qq to be profit maximizing are pp (ww, qq ) 0 qq and in interior solutions ww, qq pp = 0 That is, at the interior optimum qq, price equals ww,qq marginal cost,. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 140

Firm s Expansion Path The expansion path is the locus of cost-minimizing tangencies. (Analogous to the wealth expansion path in consumer theory) The curve shows how inputs increase as output increases. Expansion path is positively sloped. Both kk and ll are normal goods, i.e., kk cc (ww,qq) 0, llcc (ww,qq) 0 K c k2 c k1 c k0 c l0 1 c l l c(w,q 0 ) c 2 q 0 q 1 c(w,q 1 ) Expansion path q 2 c(w,q 2 ) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 141 L

Firm s Expansion Path If the firm s expansion path is a straight line: All inputs must increase at a constant proportion as firm increases its output. The firm s production function exhibits constant returns to scale and it is, hence, homothetic. If the expansion path is straight and coincides with the 45-degree line, then the firm increases all inputs by the same proportion as output increases. The expansion path does not have to be a straight line. The use of some inputs may increase faster than others as output expands Depends on the shape of the isoquants. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 142

Firm s Expansion Path The expansion path does not have to be upward sloping. If the use of an input falls as output expands, that input is an inferior input. kk is normal kk cc (ww, qq) 0 but ll is inferior (at higher levels of output) ll cc (ww, qq) < 0 Advanced Microeconomic Theory 143

Firm s Expansion Path Are there inferior inputs out there? We can identify inferior inputs if the list of inputs used by the firms is relatively disaggregated. For instance, we can identify following categories: CEOs, executives, managers, accountants, secretaries, janitors, etc. These inputs do not increase at a constant rate as the firm increases output (i.e., expansion path would not be a straight line for all increases in qq). After reaching a certain scale, the firm might buy a powerful computer with which accounting can be done using fewer accountants. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 144

Cost and Supply: Single Output Let us assume a given vector of input prices ww 0. Then, cc( ww, qq) can be reduced to CC(qq). Then, average and marginal costs are AACC qq = CC(qq) qq and MMMM = CC qq = (qq) Hence, the FOCs of the PMP can be expressed as pp CCC qq, and in interior solutions pp = CCC qq i.e., all output combinations such that pp = CCC qq are the (optimal) supply correspondence of the firm qq pp. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 145

Cost and Supply: Single Output We showed that the cost function cc(ww, qq) is homogenous of degree 1 in input prices, ww. Can we extend this property to the AC and MC? Yes! For average cost function, AAAA tttt, qq = = tt AAAA tttt, qq CC(tttt, qq) qq = tt CC(ww, qq) qq Advanced Microeconomic Theory 146

Cost and Supply: Single Output For marginal cost function, (tttt, qq) tt (ww, qq) MMMM tttt, qq = = = tt MMMM tttt, qq Isn t this result violating Euler s theorem? No! The above result states that cc(ww, qq) is homog(1) in inputs prices, and that MMMM ww, qq is also = (ww,qq) homog(1) in input prices. Euler s theorem would say that: If cc(ww, qq) is homog(1) in inputs prices, then its derivate with respect to input prices, (ww,qq), must be homog(0). ww Advanced Microeconomic Theory 147

Graphical Analysis of Total Cost With constant returns to scale, total costs are proportional to output. TTTT(qq) = cc qq Hence, Total cost c TC output AAAA(qq) = TTTT(qq) = cc qq MMCC(qq) = TTTT(qq) = cc qq AAAA(qq) = MMMM(qq) Advanced Microeconomic Theory 148

Cost and Supply: Single Output Suppose that TC starts out as concave and then becomes convex as output increases. TC no longer exhibits constant returns to scale. One possible explanation for this is that there is a third factor of production that is fixed as capital and labor usage expands (e.g., entrepreneurial skills). TC begins rising rapidly after diminishing returns set in. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 149

Cost and Supply: Single Output TC initially grows very rapidly, then becomes relatively flat, and for high production levels increases rapidly again. TC A $1,500 B 0 50 C TC(q) q MC is the slope of the TC curve. AC MC $30 A MC(q) AC(q) $10 A 0 50 q Advanced Microeconomic Theory 150

Cost and Supply: Single Output AC MC MC(Q) AC(Q) min AC TC becomes flatter TC becomes steeper q Advanced Microeconomic Theory 151

Cost and Supply: Single Output Remark 1: AC=MC at qq = 0. Note that we cannot compute AAAA 0 = TTTT 0 0 We can still apply l Hopital s rule TTTT(qq) lim AAAA(qq) = lim qq 0 qq 0 qq = lim qq 0 = 0 0 TTTT(qq) qq qq qq = lim qq 0 MMCC(qq) Hence, AC=MC at qq = 0, i.e., AC(0)=MC(0). Advanced Microeconomic Theory 152

Cost and Supply: Single Output Remark 2: When MC<AC, the AC curve decreases, and when MC>AC, the AC curve increases. Intuition: using example of grades If the new exam score raises your average grade, it must be that such new grade is better than your average grade thus far. If, in contrast, the new exam score lowers your average grade, it must be that such new grade is than your average grade thus far. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 153

Cost and Supply: Single Output Remark 3: AC and MC curves cross (AC=MC) at exactly the minimum of the AC curve. Let us first find the minimum of the AC curve AACC(qq) qq = = TTCC(qq) qq qq = qq TTCC(qq) TTTT(qq) 1 qq 2 qq MMMM(qq) TTTT(qq) qq 2 = 0 The output that minimizes AC must satisfy qq MMMM qq TTTT qq = 0 MMMM qq = TTTT qq Hence, MMMM = AAAA at the minimum of AACC. qq AAAA qq Advanced Microeconomic Theory 154

Cost and Supply: Single Output Decreasing returns to scale: an increase in the use of inputs produces a less-thanproportional increase in output. production set is strictly convex TC function is convex MC and AC are increasing q C(q) p Y ˆq slope = C '( qˆ ) slope = AC( qˆ ) Heavy trace is supply locus q(p) C (q) AC(q) (a) z -z (b) ˆq q (c) q Advanced Microeconomic Theory 155

Cost and Supply: Single Output Constant returns to scale: an increase in input usage produces a proportional increase in output. production set is weakly convex linear TC function constant AC and MC functions q C(q) p Y q(p) No sales for p < MC(q) AC(q) = C (q) (a) -z (b) q (c) q Advanced Microeconomic Theory 156