Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I

Similar documents
Advanced Microeconomics

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1

Katz and Shapiro (1985)

Interconnection Incentives of a Large Network Facing Multiple Rivals. David A. Malueg Marius Schwartz. Working Paper January 2003

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Answer Key: Problem Set 1

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

Basics of Game Theory

EconS Sequential Competition

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot

Targeted Advertising and Social Status

Technical Appendix for: Complementary Goods: Creating, Capturing and Competing for Value

EconS Vertical Integration

Retailer s product line choice with manufacturer s multi-channel marketing

The Economics of E-commerce and Technology

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Platform Competition under Asymmetric Information preliminary

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

Aftermarket Power and Basic Market Competition

Aftermarket Power and Basic Market Competition

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium

Competitive Equilibrium

x ax 1 2 bx2 a bx =0 x = a b. Hence, a consumer s willingness-to-pay as a function of liters on sale, 1 2 a 2 2b, if l> a. (1)

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Game of Platforms: Strategic Expansion in Two-Sided Markets

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract

COMPETITION IN MARKETS WITH NETWORK EXTERNALITIES. Fatma Busra Gunay

Multiple-Quality Cournot Oligopoly and the Role of Market Size

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information

Strategic Outsourcing under Economies of Scale

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 12 Price discrimination (ch 10)-continue

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

A General Bundling Theory; an Application to Complementary Demand and Separate Sellers

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

October 16, 2018 Notes on Cournot. 1. Teaching Cournot Equilibrium

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

A theory of recommended price dispersion

Excess Liquidity against Predation

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Collusion II

Durable goods monopolist

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias. Web Appendix

Duopoly and Project Uncertainty

Online Appendix to A search model of costly product returns by Vaiva Petrikaitė

Multiple-Quality Cournot Oligopoly and the Role of Market Size

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Systems of Linear Equations in Two Variables. Break Even. Example. 240x x This is when total cost equals total revenue.

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods

Bresnahan, JIE 87: Competition and Collusion in the American Automobile Industry: 1955 Price War

Can Vertical Separation Reduce Non-Price Discrimination and Increase Welfare?

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous?

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005

Vertical Product Differentiation and Credence Goods: Mandatory Labeling and Gains from International Integration

Y j R L divide goods into produced goods (outputs) > 0 output, call its price p < 0 input, call its price ω

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants,

3. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilibrium

s<1/4 p i = 2 3 s s [1/4, 9/16[ p i = p j + 2 s p j 1 if p j < p j p i = 2 3 s if p j p j p i = p j if p j < p j s 9/16

Mergers, investments and demand expansion

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting

Competition in Markets with Network Externalities

Endogenous Games and Mechanisms: Side Payments Among Players

Knowledge licensing in a Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth

THE EXISTENCE OF EQUILIBRIUM IN A DIFFERENTIATED DUOPOLY WITH NETWORK EXTERNALITIES*

Department of Economics, University of California, Davis Ecn 200C Micro Theory Professor Giacomo Bonanno ANSWERS TO PRACTICE PROBLEMS 18

Inert Consumers in Markets with Switching Costs and Price Discrimination

Market Participation under Delegated and. Intrinsic Common Agency Games

Price setting on a network

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana

Credence Goods and Vertical Product Differentiation: The Impact of Labeling Policies* Ian Sheldon (Ohio State University)

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 13: Extensive Form Games

Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

DEMB Working Paper Series N. 39. Limit pricing and secret barriers to entry. Luigi Brighi * Marcello D Amato ** December 2014

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

Perfect Competition in Markets with Adverse Selection

Theory of Auctions. Carlos Hurtado. Jun 23th, Department of Economics University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign

Part I: Exercise of Monopoly Power. Chapter 1: Monopoly. Two assumptions: A1. Quality of goods is known by consumers; A2. No price discrimination.

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Exclusive Dealing and Vertical Integration in Interlocking Relationships

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Transcription:

Prepared with SEVI S LIDES Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Antonio Cabrales & Massimo Motta May 25, 2005

Summary Some definitions Efficiency reasons for tying Tying as a price discrimination device: Bundling Requirements tying Exclusionary tying Strategic behavior in network industries

Some definitions (1/2) Tie-in sales (tying): Whenever a good is offered under the condition that another good is bought with it. Bundling (or package tie-in): Different goods are sold together in fixed proportions (e.g., shoes and laces, cars and tyres, laptop and OS software and so on.) Mixed-bundling: When the consumer is also given the choice to buy the goods separately. Requirements tying: Whenever two goods are sold together in variable proportions (e.g., copy machine and toner, cell phone and subscription and so on.) 1

Efficiency reasons for tying Consumers save on assembling costs and transaction costs: If they buy the bundle (e.g., shoes and laces, different car parts) rather than separate goods Scale economies due to division of labour: Else, each of us should learn how to assemble a car. Solving problems of asymmetric information: And guaranteeing highest quality, by ensuring that different components work well together (but quality problems might also be solved in other ways, e.g. with quality control, minimum quality standards, certifications.) 2

Tying as a price discrimination device: Bundling (1/3) Bundling might be used to extract more surplus from consumers (especially when preferences for different goods are negatively correlated.) Example: See Table next page. A monopolist obtains higher profits by bundling two products than selling them separately to the two consumers. Ambiguous effects on welfare (same as with price discrimination.) 3

Tying as a price discrimination device: Bundling (2/3) By selling A, B separately, firm earns 4(2)+5(2)=18. By bundling them, it makes 12+12=24. 1 s willingness to pay 2 s willingness to pay Good A 7 4 Good B 5 8 Goods A and B 12 12 4

Requirements tying (1/9) Requirements tying might act as a metering device. If a product can be used with different intensities, a firm would like to charge more to consumers with higher intensity of use (i.e., with higher valuation.) By keeping low price of basic product (e.g. copy machine, cellular handset) and high price of complementary products (toner cartridges, calls), firm charges according to intensity of use. Welfare higher, if under tying more consumers buy. Welfare lower, if all consumers buy absent tying or with it (same effects as with price discrimination.) 5

Requirements tying (2/9) A model of requirements tying A consumer is type i = h, l and buys one unit of good A and q units of B. U i = q q2 2v i Proportion of type l (lower intensity) is λ. Good A is monopolized by firm 1 and market B has several suppliers (including 1.) Constant marginal cost c A, c B < 1. No fixed cost. 6

Requirements tying (3/9) No tying (all buy) Suppose a consumer buys. Then his demand is: q i = v i (1 p B ). He will buy if U i p A p B q i 0, that is, if v i (1 p B ) 2 /2 p A 0. Competition implies p B = c B If firm 1 prices so that all consumers buy: p NT A = v l(1 c B ) 2 2 In this case l consumers have no surplus and h consumers have CS NT h = (v h v l )(1 c B ) 2 /2. Producer surplus is π NT = v l (1 c B ) 2 /2 c A. Welfare is then: W NT = ((1 λ)v h + λv l )(1 c B ) 2 2 c A. 7

Requirements tying (4/9) No tying (Only high types buy) If firm 1 prices so that only h consumers buy: p NT h A = v h(1 c B ) 2 2 In this case all consumers have no surplus CS NT h = 0. Producer surplus is π NT h = (1 λ) ( v h (1 c B ) 2 /2 c A ) = W NT h. This strategy is profitable if π NT h π NT, which is true if: λ (v h v l )(1 c B ) 2 v h (1 c B ) 2 2c A 8

Requirements tying (5/9) Tying If firm 1 requires consumers who want good A also to buy good B from it (and can enforce it.) π = (p B c B )[λv l (1 p B ) + (1 λ)v h (1 p B )] + p A c A. Which implies p T B = (1 λ)(v h v l ) + c B [λv l + (1 λ)v h ] 2v h v l 2λ(v h v l ) Price of A is chosen so that v i (1 p T B )2 /2 p A 0, thus: p T A = (1 c B) 2 v l [λv l + (1 λ)v h ] 2 2[2v h v l 2λ(v h v l )] 2 > c B The price p T A acts like the fixed part of a two-part tariff, and allows to screen between types. 9

Requirements tying (6/9) π T = (1 c B) 2 [λv l + (1 λ)v h ] 2 2[2v h v l 2λ(v h v l )] c A. Consumers of type l have no surplus and: Thus: CS T h = (1 c B) 2 (v h v l )[λv l + (1 λ)v h ] 2 2[2v h v l 2λ(v h v l )] 2 W T = (1 c B) 2 [λv l + (1 λ)v h ] 2 [1 + (1 λ)(v h v l )] 2[2v h v l 2λ(v h v l )] 2 c A 10

Requirements tying (7/9) Comparisons of equilibria 1. First assume that it is optimal to serve all under no tying. Then: π T π NT = (1 c B) 2 (v h v l ) 2 2[2v h v l 2λ(v h v l )] > 0. W NT W T = (1 c B) 2 (1 λ)(v h v h ) 2 [(1 + λ 2λ 2 )v h + 2λ 2 v l ] 2[2v h v l 2λ(v h v l )] 2 > 0. Consumers do not buy any more at marginal cost good B. 11

Requirements tying (8/9) 2. Now assume that it is optimal to serve only the h types under no tying. Simple to see as under no tying consumer surplus is zero and now positive. Profits have to be higher or else it would not be done. 3. To check that tying will indeed be profitable consider c A = c B = 0, v h = 2, v l = 1. Without tying firm 1 will serve only h if λ < 1/2. Then π T π NT h > 0 if λ > 1 3/3. 12

Exclusionary tying (1/15) Whinston, 1990: tying as a commitment to compete aggressively, thus forcing a rival out of the market. Two independent products, A and B. Firm 1 monopolist on A, firms 1 and 2 both sell good B. If 1 commits to bundle A and B, it will price more aggressively, because it knows that every consumer who buys B will not buy A, on which firm 1 has a high margin (A is a monopoly) Fierce competition decrease both firms profits: knowing it, rival exits if cannot cover fixed costs. 13

Exclusionary tying (2/15) A model of exclusionary tying with differentiated goods Consumers uniformly distributed in [0, 1] consume one unit (at most) of A, valued at v > c A and one of B, valued at U Bi = w t i x x Bi p Bi, where w > max(c B1, c B2 ) and x B1 = 0, x B2 = 1. Firm 1first decides whether to bundle A and B 1 (irreversibly.) Then both firms decide whether to enter market B (and if so, pay F.) Then pricing ( p for the bundle if there is one, otherwise p A, p B1 and p B2.) 14

Exclusionary tying (3/15) Independent Pricing (no tying) A consumer will buy B1 rather than B2 if U B1 > U B2 or w t 1 x p B1 w t 2 (1 x) p B2. Both firms sell at equilibrium if: (A1) 0 < v c A < t 2 + 2t 1 + c B1 c B2 (A2) v c A > 2t 2 t 1 + c B1 c B2 x 12 (p B1, p B2 ) t 2 + p B2 p B1 t 2 + t 1. 15

Exclusionary tying (4/15) q B1 = x 12 (p B1, p B2 ), q B2 = 1 x 12 (p B1, p B2 ). π B1 = (p B1 c B1 ) t 2 + p B2 p B1 ; π B2 = (p B2 c B2 ) t 1 + p B1 p B2 t 2 + t 1 t 2 + t 1 Thus R B1 : p B1 = t 2 + c B1 + p B2 ; R B2 : p B1 = 2p B2 c B2 t 1 2 p Bi = t i + 2t j + c Bj + 2c Bi 3 ( ti ; πbi = + 2t j + c Bj + 2c Bi 9(t i + t j ) ) 2 16

Exclusionary tying (5/15) Tying A consumer will buy A/B1 at price p rather than B2 if Ũ > U B2 or v + w t 1 x p w t 2 (1 x) p B2. x 12 ( p, p B2 ) t 2 + p B2 + v p t 2 + t 1. q B1 = x 12 ( p, p B2 ), q B2 = 1 x 12 ( p, p B2 ). π = ( p c A c B1 ) v + t 2 + p B2 p ; π B2 = (p B2 c B2 ) v + t 1 + p p B2 t 2 + t 1 t 2 + t 1 Thus R 1 : p = v + c A + t 2 + c B1 + p B2 ; R 2 : p = 2p B2 c B2 + v t 1 2 p = t 1 + 2t 2 + c B2 + 2c B1 + v + 2c A ; p B2 3 = t 2 + 2t 1 + c B1 + 2c B2 v + c A 3 17

Exclusionary tying (6/15) π 1 = (t 1 + 2t 2 + c B2 c B1 + v c A ) 2 ; π B2 9(t 1 + t 2 ) = (t 2 + 2t 1 + c B1 c B2 v + c A ) 2 9(t 1 + t 2 ) π 1 < π 1 iff v c A < 5t 2 + 7t 1 + 2c B1 2c B2 This is compatible with (A2) as long as 7t 2 + 8t 1 + c B1 c B2 which is true by (A1). 18

Exclusionary tying (7/15) Intuition Let p = v + p B1 R 1 : p B1 = t 2 + c B1 + p B2 (v c A ) ; R 2 : p B1 = 2p B2 c B2 t 1 2 19

Exclusionary tying (8/15) Entry Entry for 2 without tying but no entry with tying if: π B2 F > π B2. Bundling decision Not necessarily true that 2 will be excluded: monopoly bundling profits π m must be bigger than duopoly under no bundling π 1. To find π m note that a consumer buys the bundle rather than nothing if U m > 0 or v + w t 1 x p m 0. x m = (v + w p m )/t 1. Two cases depending on x m 1 or x m < 1. q m = 1, if p m v + w t 1 v+w p m t 1, if p m > v + w t 1 20

Exclusionary tying (9/15) π m = p m c A c B1, if p m v + w t 1 ( p m c A c B1 ) v+w p m t 1, if p m > v + w t 1 Optimal interior price is p m = (v + w + c A + c B1 )/2 and it applies only if v + w < c A + c B1 + 2t 1 (otherwise p m v + w t 1.) π m = v + w t 1 c A c B1, if v + w c A + c B1 + 2t 1 ( v+w c A c B1 ) 2 4t 1, if v + w < c A + c B1 + 2t 1 Suppose c A = c B1 = c B2 = t 2 = 0 and v + w < 2t 1 π m π 1 = (v + w)2 4t 1 t 1 9 v. So for high enough t 1 bundling will not be chosen. 21

Exclusionary tying (10/15) Suppose c A = c B1 = c B2 = t 2 = 0 but v + w 2t 1 π m π 1 = t 1 t 1 9 + w. So for low t 1 or high w exclusion is profitable. Exclusion leads to higher profits in B but some consumers stop buying from A so monopoly may not be profitable. 22

Exclusionary tying (11/15) Welfare Under exclusion, consumers have less variety and prices increase, but fixed costs are avoided. Overall lower consumer welfare and likely lower total welfare. 23

Exclusionary tying (12/15) Exclusionary tying with complementary goods When products are complementary, exclusionary bundling is less likely to be profitable, since it reduces sales of the tied good. Example: as above, but A and B are complements in fixed proportions, and A is necessary product In this example, by bundling A and B firm 1 would trivially exclude firm 2. But, would it be profitable? The following shows that by bundling firm 1 would have (weakly) lower profits. 24

Exclusionary tying (13/15) A model with complementary goods Let p m optimal price of monopoly bundle, as before. If no bundle, suppose: p A = p m c B ; p B = c B. Two cases: 1. Firm 2 not active: this pricing does as well as bundling (p A +p B = p m.) 2. Firm 2 active if 1 does not bundle. Two effects from firm 2: (a) Some consumers would switch to firm 2, but firm 1 s profits are the same (same number of sales from A, and no lost profits on B1, since p B = c B.) (b) Some consumers previously not buying now buy B2: firm 1 s profits rise, as demand for A increases. 25

Exclusionary tying (14/15) Summary and practice Possible efficiency effects from tying. Ambiguous welfare effects (even absent efficiency effects) if tying as price discrimination device. Two-part test for tying practices: 1. If firm is not dominant, tying should be allowed. 2. If firm is dominant, then full investigation: (a) Negatives: possible anti-competitive effects (less likely when products are complementary, and when bundling is reversible.) (b) Positives: Efficiency reasons for tying (also, risk of tampering with product design and innovations!) 26

Strategic behavior in network industries (1/10) Network industries are fertile grounds for anti-competitive behaviour: externalities due to a strong customer base make life difficult for entrants. Network inter-operability main problem. By denying access to its customer base (i.e., by denying inter-operability) an incumbent might prevent entry of a competing network product. Denying inter-operability is not optimal if access to two compatible networks has so strong externalities that many new consumers are attracted (better share a large market than be monopolist of a small one). 27

Strategic behavior in network industries (2/10) Compatibility Why not to force incumbents to grant compatibility (i.e., access to competing networks)? Under incompatible products, very fierce competition (and low prices) at early industry stages: imposing compatibility deprives successful firm of its reward (competition for the market, not in the market.) However, a more interventionist policy makes sense when the incumbent enjoys strong position due to previous legal monopoly. 28

Strategic behavior in network industries (3/10) Other comments Exclusionary behaviour less likely to occur when complementary products are at issue (same arguments as for tying.) Suppose incumbent firm 1 has monopoly of product A and duopolist of product B. By making A incompatible to B2, 1 would exclude firm 2, but this is likely to reduce its profits (some people who would buy A with B2 would stop doing so.) Predatory pricing, exclusive contracts, and false announcements might also persuade consumers not to switch to entrants. 29

Strategic behavior in network industries (4/10) A model of interoperability in networks (Crémer, Rey, Tirole 2000) Two firms. β 2 = 0. One has a installed base β 1 > 0 and another firm has Consumers uniformly distributed in [0, 1]. A consumer in T [0, 1] attaches a net benefit to the network: S i = T + s i p i, where s i = v[β i + q i + θ(β j + q j )]. v < 1/2 is the importance of externalities, and θ is the quality of interoperability. For both firms to get customers we must have: p 1 s 1 = p 2 s 2 = p. 30

Strategic behavior in network industries (5/10) The consumer indifferent between joining or not has: S i = T +s i p i = T p = 0, so a consumer will buy if T p, thuṡ q 1 + q 2 = 1 p Thus p i = p + s i and p i = 1 q i q j + s i and p i = 1 + v[β i + θβ j ] (1 v)q i (1 vθ)q j.

Strategic behavior in network industries (6/10) Equilibrium with product market competition π i = ( p i (q i, q j ) c ) q i. R 1 : q 1 = 1 c + vβ 1 (1 vθ)q 2 ; R 2 : q 1 = 1 c + vθβ 1 2(1 v)q 2 2(1 v) 1 vθ q i = 1 2 ( 2(1 c) + v(1 + θ)(βi + β j ) 2(1 v) + (1 vθ) + (1 θ)v(β ) i β j ) 2(1 v) (1 vθ) Note that this is Fulfilled expectations Cournot equilibrium and q 1 q 2 = (1 θ)vβ 1 2(1 v) (1 vθ) > 0 if θ < 1 32

Strategic behavior in network industries (7/10) Equilibrium with tipping to the firm with installed base q 2 = 0 π m 1 = (1 + vβ 1 (1 v)q 1 c) q 1 and optimal quantity is q m 1 = 1 c + vβ 1 2(1 v). This is an equilibrium provided p 2 (q m 1, 0) c, or 1 + vθβ 1 (1 vθ) 1 c + vβ 1 2(1 v) c 0. For θ = 0 this is equivalent to (and compatible with v < 1/2): v 1 c 2(1 c) + β 1 33

Strategic behavior in network industries (8/10) Equilibrium with tipping to the entrant q 1 = 0, π m 2 = (1 + vθβ 1 (1 v)q 2 c) q 2 and optimal quantity is q2 m = 1 c + vθβ 1. 2(1 v) This is an equilibrium provided p 1 (0, q m 2 ) c, or 1 + vβ 1 (1 vθ) 1 c + vθβ 1 2(1 v) c 0. This is easier if θ is small. For θ = 0 this is equivalent to: c 1 + 2β 1v(1 v) 1 2v which never happens since q2 m 0 requires c < 1 (entrant tipping can happen with more than two firms.) 34

Strategic behavior in network industries (9/10) Interoperability as a choice Let θ = min(θ1, θ 2 ). The optimal choice depends on the equilibrium For tipping equilibria θ = 0 is best for firm 1. For interior equilibria note π i = (1 v) (q i )2. Assume θ = 0 or θ = 1 only (wlog by Crémer and Tirole), and c = 0 q 1 (θ = 1) q 1 (θ = 0) = v(1 2v β 1(3 4v + 2v 2 )) 3(1 v)(3 8v + 4v 2 ) which holds if β 1 < (1 2v)/(3 4v + 2v 2 ) > 0, q 2 (θ = 1) q 2 (θ = 0) = v(1 2v β 1(6 11v + 2v 2 )) 3(1 v)(3 2v)(1 2v) > 0 In general inter-operability eliminates incumbents advantage, but increases demand of new customers. 35

Prepared with SEVI S LIDES Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Antonio Cabrales & Massimo Motta May 25, 2005