Birmingham MSc International Macro Autumn Lecture 7: Deviations from purchasing power parity explored and explained

Similar documents
Birmingham MSc International Macro Autumn Deviations from purchasing power parity explored and explained

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Wage and price setting. Slides for 26. August 2003 lecture

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Aggregation: A Brief Overview

A Summary of Economic Methodology

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

LECTURE NOTES ON MICROECONOMICS

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

The Real Business Cycle Model

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

Study Skills in Mathematics. Edited by D. Burkhardt and D. Rutherford. Nottingham: Shell Centre for Mathematical Education (Revised edn 1981).

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES

Internation1al Trade

CES functions and Dixit-Stiglitz Formulation

= 2 = 1.5. Figure 4.1: WARP violated

INTRODUCTORY MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS MSCS. LECTURE 3: MULTIVARIABLE FUNCTIONS AND CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. HUW DAVID DIXON CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL.

PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) (MACROECONOMICS cl. 15)

Addendum to: New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?

Gravity Models and the Armington Assumption

Price Index Basics* (pg. 146 of Foundations of Economic Analysis)

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

Chapter 2: Economic Theories, Data, and Graphs

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Eco 200, part 3, Fall 2004 Lars Svensson 12/6/04. Liquidity traps, the zero lower bound for interest rates, and deflation

Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost.

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note

The General Neoclassical Trade Model

CLASS NOTES: BUSINESS CALCULUS

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM: EXCESS DEMAND AND THE RÔLE OF PRICES

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Pricing To Habits and the Law of One Price

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Lecture 1 Introduction and Historical Notes

Answers to questions for The New Introduction to Geographical Economics, 2 nd edition

Topics in Trade: Slides

Notes on Winnie Choi s Paper (Draft: November 4, 2004; Revised: November 9, 2004)

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

6. Open Economy Models

LINEAR ALGEBRA W W L CHEN

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Dynare Class on Heathcote-Perri JME 2002

Lars Svensson 10/2/05. Liquidity traps, the zero lower bound for interest rates, and deflation

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

1 + x 1/2. b) For what values of k is g a quasi-concave function? For what values of k is g a concave function? Explain your answers.

Application of linear systems Linear Algebra with Computer Science Application

EconS 301. Math Review. Math Concepts

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

EC611--Managerial Economics

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Chapter 5 Simplifying Formulas and Solving Equations

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants,

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics ARE 251/Econ 270A, Fall Household Models

Learning, Expectations, and Endogenous Business Cycles

1 Numbers, Sets, Algebraic Expressions

2 Functions and Their

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Does Pleasing Export-Oriented Foreign Investors Help Your. Balance of Payments? A General Equilibrium Analysis. (Available on Request Appendix)

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

Slides to Lecture 3 of Introductory Dynamic Macroeconomics. Linear Dynamic Models (Ch 2 of IDM)

2012 AND ESTIMATE FOR Q1, 2013 GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT FOR NIGERIA

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Oil Stock Discovery and Dutch Disease

Uniform versus Non-Uniform Globalization: A Framework for Thinking About Welfare Effects of IT-Driven Globalization. By Kiminori Matsuyama

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Information Bulletin 6/2008

Relationships between phases of business cycles in two large open economies

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large!

5.2 Algebraic Properties

Extended IS-LM model - construction and analysis of behavior

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

AAEC 6524: Environmental Theory and Policy Analysis. Outline. Theory of Externalities and Public Goods. Klaus Moeltner Spring 2019.

MTH 2032 Semester II

Lecture 1: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Economics 232c Spring 2003 International Macroeconomics. Problem Set 3. May 15, 2003

Information Bulletin 4/2007

Transcription:

Birmingham MSc International Macro Autumn 2015 Lecture 7: Deviations from purchasing power parity explored and explained 1. Some definitions: PPP, LOOP, absolute and relative [hese notes are very heavily derivative of the relevant chapter in the textbook International Macroeconomics by Schmitt-Grohe, Uribe and Woodford [SGUW]. In the May 09 2015 version there are some typos, and I have changed the notation so that S is used to denote the nominal exchange rate throughout. whereas the textbook uses both S and E.] In our lecture on the DMF model, we encountered the idea that the real exchange rate might fluctuate over the short run. In this lecture we dive deeper into related issues using a micofounded treatment, and derive the Balassa- Samuelson effect which characterises and explains long run departures from the law of one price and purchasing power parity. he Law Of One Price, [LOOP] is said to hold when goods cost the same at home or abroad. o state more precisely what this means. Let P be the price of goods at home, P be the price of goods abroad, and S denote how many units of the home currency it takes to buy a unit of foreign currency. Or, since we are in the UK, how many it takes to buy $s, for example. hen LOOP holding means: P = SP If a good is more expensive at home then: P > SP And vice-versa. A now classic, popular, and regularly updated investigation of the validity of the law of one prices is the Economist Big Mac index. Big Macs are hamburgers sold in Macdonalds, and made using identical ingredients, and sold in a wide variety of countries, since Macdonalds has restaurants all over the world. he Big Mac index, formally, is given by: e BigMac = S P BigMac P BigMac LOOP holds for BigMacs if e BigMac = 1. As widely reported, the LOOP fails for BigMacs spectacularly. lifted from SGUW, illustrates. his table, 1

Purchasing power parity [PPP] generalises the LOOP for a basket of many goods. Letting P now denote the number of units of currency it takes to buy a common basket of goods: e = S P P = 1 For PPP to hold. In words PPP literally means: the purchasing power of a unit of currency in terms of the amount of goods it can by, has parity across countries. his is actually what we would refer to as absolute PPP. In practice, it s often tough to measure this for a whole economy, over many periods. Statistics offi ces usually report measures of price changes, and the price level is an index. In this case, one can instead study relative PPP. Relative PPP is when e = 0. 2. Using index theory to assess non-traded goods LOOP failure as a proximate cause of the failure of PPP 2

Many goods are not traded. It s a common thing to approximate those that aren t by services. But that is not accurate. Many services are traded (like education - some students reading these notes pay fees that count as UK exports) and many manufactured goods (like perishable fresh foods) are not traded. Define price indices for traded and non traded goods as P,. Suppose the LOOP holds for traded goods. hat is: P = SP Yet it fails for non-traded goods, ie: SP N Let an aggregate price index P that sums traded and non trade prices be given by: P = φ(p, ) Let φ be homogenous of degree 1, namely: λφ(p, ) = φ(λp, λ ) Intuitively, this property would mean that if each price went up by x% then the aggregate price index would also rise by x%. wo examples of index functions that possess this property are: A simple average: Or a geometric average: P = (P + )/2 P = (P ) α ( ) Now substitute our definition of the price index into the definition of the real exchange rate. his is going to allow us to diagnose the proximate causes of PPP failures. e = S P P = S φ(p, P N ) φ(p, ) Now multiply and divide the numerator by P and the denominator by P. e = S. φ(1, P N /P ).P φ(1, /P ).P Note that here we invoke the homogeneity property of the price index function φ without which the dividing through inside the function bracket would not cancel with the multiplcation outside of it. 3

Since we have assumed that the LOOP holds for traded goods prices, ie P = SP...our equation for e the real exchange rate, can be written simply as: From this it becomes clear that: e = φ(1, P N /P ) φ(1, /P ) [1] e > 1 P N/P > /P In words, the real exchange rate will differ from 1 if the ratio of non-traded to traded goods prices in two different countries differs. [Again, this inference invokes the homogeneity property of the price index]. 3. A simple static model of the Balassa-Samuelson failure of PPP Having diagnosed a proximate cause of the failure of PPP as a potential failure of the LOOP in the non-traded sector, we turn now to a simple presenation of the Balassa-Samuelson model, which explains how productivity differentials in traded goods sectors in countries leads to differences in the real exchange rate through just this route, differences in non-traded goods prices. So, imagine a two sector economy divided into a homogenous traded goods sector and a homogenous non-traded goods sector. Suppose that production in the two sectors occurs as follows: Q = α L Q N = α N L N Where Q is output, α determines productivity in the two sectors, and L measures the labour input. Profits of firms in both industries are given by the difference between total revenues and total labour costs: Π = P i Q i wl i We assume that there is perfect competition and free entry in both sectors. We also assume that labour can move freely across sectors, so there is a common wage paid per effective unit of labour, hence there is no subscript to differentiate wage by sector. Perfect competition implies zero profits. And eliminating Q by substituting in our equation for the production function, we can therefore learn that: 0 = P i Q i wl i P i α i L i = wl i P i α i = w 4

We can therefore equate versions of this equation for both traded and nontraded sectors, to state that: P α = w = α N P = α N [2] α Some intuition: if productivity in the traded sector rises [denominator, RHS], this lowers the cost of producing traded goods, and that drags down the relative price of tradables [LHS]. Since this relation holds for the home economy, it also holds for the foreign economy, by assumption: P PN = α N α Putting [1], [2] and [3] together, we get: [3] e = φ(1, α α ) N φ(1, α α ) [1] N his is our formal statement of the Balassa-Samuelson effect, that fluctuations in the real exchange rate are driven by the ratio of productivity between trade and non-traded sectors as compared across countries. It s common to think that in fact productivity does not differ in the nontraded sectors by all that much, and simplify this relation to suggest that the real exchange rate is determined by the relative productivity of the tradables sector in each economy. 3. Microfoundations of price indices Our account is incomplete in modelling and practical terms because we have not said much about the nature of the price index function φ on which some of these observations about the causes of real exchange rate fluctuations depend. o be consistent with our general modelling approach, this index should be related to the microeconomics of consumer behaviour. o explain what we mean by this, we go through a simple example in this next section. Consumers derive pleasure from consumption, as normal, via a utility function: U = u(c) Note that pleasure comes from consuming the aggregate. We assume that this aggregate is built from non-traded and traded goods, in the same way that the Big Mac is built from beef and real estate: C = C α C N 5

Another way of looking at this aggregator function is that is just part of a hiearchical, indirect utility function. Note that the α here is a separate object from the same symbol used to denote productivity in the earlier section, and used here just to match the source notes by Uribe from which this lecture is lifted. Now define P as the minimum units of money needed to by one unit of the aggregate consumption good. We find P by solving a minimisation problem, therefore: P = min C,C N {P C + C N } his minimisation is subject to the constraint that our single unit of the aggregate is built from the traded and non traded components in the way that we assumed above: s.t. 1 = C α C N We turn this static, constrained minimisation into a static, unconstrained minimisation by choosing one of the choice variables in the objective function, and using the constraint to substitute out for it. hus, for example, we can use the constraint to find an expression for C N in terms of C : C N = C α [Agebra here is an exercise for you to confirm]. We now substitute out for C N the objective function: P = P C + C α And differentiate wrt C and find the first order condition by setting the result to zero. his leads to an equation for C : C = [ PN P ] α [1] 1 α [An exercise for you to confirm this is correct]. We now use this expression to get an expression for C N, consumption of non-traded goods at the optimum: [ ] α P 1 α C N = α [Confirm this is correct in an exercise]. We now substitute expressions for C and C N into the unconstrained objective function, to get an expression for the aggregate price index at the optimum, P : Recall that this is: 6

So substituting in we have: P = P [ PN P his can be shown to be: P = P C + C N ] [ ] α α P 1 α + 1 α α P = (P ) α ( ) A A = α α (1 α) α 1 [You are asked to confirm that this is true in an exercise]. Economics often produces the exclamation you can t compare apples and oranges, but, in fact, if one theorises from utility maxisation, one can, in fact, compare apples and oranges, and we have seen how to do so. In the real world, however, one has the practical problem of knowing α. Neuroeconomists have set about studying whether there is a utility function encoded in the brains of humans. But until the controversies they have uncovered are settled, it would seem problematic not knowing α. However, in fact one can infer them from patterns of consumer expenditure, provided consumers are behaving optimally, and on the supposition that all the details of our model are right. Recall that earlier, we had that: C N = C α Multiply both sides of this equation by P C C N = P C C α P C Collecting terms on the RHS in C we get: C N = C 1 P C P to get: Now if we substitute in for C on the RHS only, using [1] above, we get: C N = 1 α P C α [An exercise for you to confirm this]. And, we can therefore solve for α to obtain: [Also an exercise to confirm this]. P C α = P C + C N 7

his equation says that α, which remember is the exponent weight in the price index that we want to use in our analysis, P = (P ) α ( ) A is given by the proportion of total expenditure that is made on traded goods. his is something readily observable using expenditure surveys, and in fact this is how most developed country statistical offi ces construct price indices. Related algebra crops up in other contexts. For example, if one assumes that production is Cobb-Douglas [the price index above was C-D], then we can use national accounts measures of the share of labour in factor income to infer the exponent in the C-D production function, for the same reasons as here. his concludes our lecture introducing and exploring PPP, LOOP and deviations from it. Along the way we presented a simple Balassa-Samuelson model, and discussed how to construct price indices that accorded with the theory we use to model real exchange rates. his theory, obviously is relevant in other contexts too. For example, national accounts aggregates, and price indices used for other purposes like measuring changes in the domestic cost of living are also typically based on this kind of theory, though there are lively debates amongst statisticians and economists about exactly the best way to proceed. 8