Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 29 September 2004.

Similar documents
Econ 101A Problem Set 1 Solution

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, February 21st, 2018

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm Suggested Solutions 2/8/ (a) The equation of the indifference curve is given by,

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

Econ Slides from Lecture 14

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy.

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Dynamic Problem Set 1 Solutions

Preferences and Utility

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12

Partial Differentiation

Introduction to General Equilibrium

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014

Properties of Walrasian Demand

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics

The Real Business Cycle Model

Constrained optimization.

Applications I: consumer theory

Econ 110: Introduction to Economic Theory. 8th Class 2/7/11

Tutorial 3: Optimisation

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Homework 3 Suggested Answers

x 1 1 and p 1 1 Two points if you just talk about monotonicity (u (c) > 0).

Monotone comparative statics Finite Data and GARP

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 3: Preferences and Choice. Today s Aims. The Story So Far. A Short Diversion: Proofs

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Exercises for Chapter 7

INTRODUCTORY MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS MSCS. LECTURE 3: MULTIVARIABLE FUNCTIONS AND CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. HUW DAVID DIXON CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL.

Sometimes the domains X and Z will be the same, so this might be written:

Utility Maximization Problem

Math for Economics 1 New York University FINAL EXAM, Fall 2013 VERSION A

Microeconomic Theory I Midterm October 2017

Revealed Preferences and Utility Functions

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics

Econ 101A Midterm 2 Th 8 April 2009.

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

Solutions for Assignment #2 for Environmental and Resource Economics Economics 359M, Spring 2017

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists Problem set 4: Classical programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

CHAPTER 3: OPTIMIZATION

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

EE290O / IEOR 290 Lecture 05

Answers to Problem Set 3

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Preferences and Utility

1 General Equilibrium

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions

Queen s University. Department of Economics. Instructor: Kevin Andrew

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

3 Intertemporal Risk Aversion

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem

arxiv:physics/ v2 [physics.gen-ph] 2 Jun 2003

Tvestlanka Karagyozova University of Connecticut

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION


Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

Solutions to Macro Final 2006

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

Mathematical Foundations II

Growth Theory: Review

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Econ 58 Gary Smith Spring Final Exam Answers

Notes on Alvarez and Jermann, "Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 2000

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 1 September Q1. Are the preferences described below transitive? Strictly monotonic? Convex?

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly.

The Necessity of the Transversality Condition at Infinity: A (Very) Special Case

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Consumption. Consider a consumer with utility. v(c τ )e ρ(τ t) dτ.

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

Intertemporal Risk Aversion, Stationarity, and Discounting

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Professor: Alan G. Isaac These notes are very rough. Suggestions welcome. Samuelson (1938, p.71) introduced revealed preference theory hoping

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Microeconomics II Lecture 4. Marshallian and Hicksian demands for goods with an endowment (Labour supply)

First Welfare Theorem

Transcription:

Econ 0A Midterm Th 29 September 2004. You have approximately hour 20 minutes to answer the questions in the midterm. I will collect the exams at 2.30 sharp. Show your work, good luck! Problem. Utility maximization. (57 points) In class, we have considered the case of maximization of utility with Cobb-Douglas utility function with goods x (baseball) y (cupcakes) as arguments. We have also considered the case of intertemporal maximization of utility with consumption of goods today, c 0, inthefuture,c. This problem asks you to combine the two elements reconsider some of the properties we had found in the two separate cases. Consider a consumer with utility function u(x 0,,x,y )(x 0 ) α ( ) β + +δ (x ) α (y ) β () where x t is the quantity of baseball x consumed at time t 0,. Similarly, y t is the quantity of cupcakes y consumed at time t 0,. For reasons that we will see below, we will assume α + β<, so do not substitute β α. As usual, α>0 β>0 also hold.. What is the interpretation of δ in the utility function? Interpret in particular the special cases δ 0 δ. (6 points) 2. Explain the procedure to determine if u(x 0,,x,y ) is concave in (x 0,,x,y ). Youshouldnotdo the computations. (4 points) 3. We now consider the budget constraint. Both in period 0 in period the price of music x is p x the price of cupcakes y is p y. We denote income at time 0 by M 0 income at time as M. Consumers can borrow across periods 0 at interest rate r. Show that this implies that the (intertemporal) budget constraint is: (6 points) p x x 0 + p y + +r (p xx + p y y ) M 0 + +r M. (2) 4. The consumer maximizes utility () with respect to the four consumption variables (x 0,,x,y ), subject to budget constraint (2). Assume that the budget constraint is satisfied with equality (it is) write the Lagrangean function. Derive the set of first order conditions. (5 points). 5. Show that the first order conditions with respect to (x 0,,x,y ) lead to the familiar conditions α (3) β x 0 p y α y. (4) β x p y Give an economic interpretation of these conditions. Are you surprised that the same conditions that hold in the one-period Cobb-Douglas utility maximization also hold in the 2-period one? (5 points) 6. [Harder] If you can, show that the first order conditions imply y (α+β) x x 0 (α+β) +r +δ (5) (You may want to leave this for last you can continue answering the rest of Problem without solving this point) (0 points)

7. Keep assuming α + β < consider equation (5). How does relative consumption in period compared to period 0 (y / x /x 0 )varyasr increases? Explain intuitively why an increase in the interest rate increase consumption in the future. Similarly, how does relative consumption in period compared to period 0 (y / x /x 0 )varyasδ increases? Provide intuition. (6 points) 8. What does equation (5) imply about y / for r δ? Provide intuition on why at the optimum the agent smooths consumption of goods x y across periods. (6 points) Extra credit: Why is it crucial for this answer that α + β<? 9. For r δ, solve for the optimal value of x 0. Hint: use the budget constraint equation (3). (5 points) 0. Use the expression for x 0 that you obtained in point 9. Differentiate x 0 with respect to M 0, that is, compute x 0/ M 0. Is music x a normal good (for all levels of price income)? (4 points) Solution to Problem.. Parameter δ has the interpretation of psychological discount rate. It indicates how much the individual discounts future utility as of the present. The higher δ, the more impatient the individual is, the less she value the future. Special case δ 0: in this case the individual gives equal weight to consumption of baseball (or cupcakes) in the present or in the future. Special case δ : the individual is myopic, does not give any weight to future utility. 2. To determine whether the utility function u is concave in (x 0,,x,y ) we should set up the matrix: x 0, x 0 x 0, x x 0, x 0, y H x, x 0 x, x x, x, y, x 0, x,, y y, x 0 y, x y, y, y The condition for concavity is that the first subdeterminant be negative or equal to zero, the second be positive (or equal to zero), the third be negative (or equal to zero), the fourth (the whole matrix) be positive (or equal to zero). Importantly, these conditions have to hold for all (x 0,,x,y ) in R + 4. 3. In period 0 the consumer can spend income M 0 on good x 0 or on good. The savings in period 0 s 0 M 0 (p x x 0 + p y ) canbesavedforperiodearninterestrater. Notice that s 0 can be negative, that is, the individual may wish to borrow from period. In period 2 the individual can spend M +( + r) s 0 M +( + r)[m 0 (p x x 0 + p y )]. The budget constraint in period therefore can be written as p x x + p y y M +(+r)[m 0 (p x x 0 + p y )]. By rearranging terms, we obtain ( + r)(p x x 0 + p y )+(p x x + p y y ) M +(+r) M 0, which is equivalent to (2) (just divide by ( + r)). 4. The consumer maximizes max (x 0) α ( ) β + (x 0,,x,y ) +δ (x ) α (y ) β s.t. p x x 0 + p y + +r (p xx + p y y ) M 0 + +r M This is equivalent to maximizing the Lagrangean L(x 0,,x,y,λ) (x 0 ) α ( ) β + +δ (x ) α (y ) β λ p x x 0 + p y + +r (p xx + p y y ) M 0 + +r M. 2

This yields the following five first order conditions: f.o.c. x 0 : α (x 0 ) α ( ) β λp x 0 f.o.c. : β (x 0 ) α ( ) β λp y 0 f.o.c. x : ³α β (x ) α (y ) +δ f.o.c. y : +δ f.o.c. λ : 5. First order conditions 2 lead to ³β (x ) α (y ) β λ λ +r p x 0 +r p y 0 p x x 0 + p y + +r (p xx + p y y ) α (x 0 ) α ( ) β λp x β (x 0 ) α ( ) β λp y M 0 + +r M 0 Taking the ratio of these two equalities, we obtain α. (6) β x 0 p y Similarly, the ratio of first order conditions 3 4 lead to α y. (7) β x p y These conditions indicates the Marginal Rate of Substitution between goods x y in period 0 equate the ratio of the prices, similarly so for goods x y in period. The condition MSRratio of prices that denotes the tangency of indifference curve budget set, therefore, extends to the 2-period case. 6. First order conditions 3 lead to α (x 0 ) α ( ) β λp x ³α β (x ) α (y ) +δ λ +r p x. Taking the ratio of these two equalities, we obtain α β x0 y0 +r x y +δ. (8) Note now that (6) (7) can be combined to yield x 0. y x We label R y0 y x0 x the ratio of consumption in period 0. Then (8) implies (α+β) (α+β) R α+β y x +r +δ 7. As r increases, the right-h side of the equality increases. This implies that the left-h side must increase as well. Given α + β<, this implies that y / x /x 0 must increase. Intuitively, as the interest rate increases, it becomes more expensive to consume in period 0 more advantageous to consume in the later period, period. The opposite effect applies when impatience increases. The right-h side decreases, y / x /x 0 must decrease as well. Intuitively, if individuals become more impatient they consume more in the present. x 0 3

8. For r δ, we obtain y y 0 y x x 0 x, that is, the consumer consumes the same quantity of baseball (cupcakes) in each of the periods. The reason for this is that the utility function is concave in the amount of consumption in each period. This implies that marginal utility is decreasing in the amount of consumption in each period. The consumer prefers to consume equal amounts rather than consuming a lot one period very little the next. 9. Under the assumption r δ, we know that y y 0 y x x 0 x. Further, equation (3) implies p y y (β/α) p x x. We substitute into the budget constraint to get or or p x x +(β/α) p x x + +r (p xx +(β/α) p x x )M 0 + +r M p x x α + β α + M 0 + +r +r M x +r α M 0 + +r M. (9) 2+r α + β p x 0. The derivative of (9) with respect to M 0 is x 0 +r M 0 2+r α α + β The good is a normal good since increases in income M 0 induce an increase in the quantity consumed x 0 for all levels of p x r. p x. 4

Problem 2. (8 points). Consider the maximization problem max f (x, p) x where both x p are real numbers (that is, not vectors). This leads to the first order condition f 0 x (x,p)0. Use the implicit function theorem to give an expression for dx /dp. Argue that, as long as x is a maximum, the sign of dx /dp is given by fx,p 00 (x,p). (8 points) 2. Consider a consumer with preferences over two goods, music x cupcakes y, with x 0 y 0. The consumer is addicted to cupcakes y is loss averse to consuming less than Y > 0 units of cupcakes. Here are the preferences of the consumer. A bundle (x, y) is weakly preferred (%) toa bundle (x 0, ) if only if the following is true: (y Y )+x ( Y )+x 0 for y Y Y 2(y Y )+x ( Y )+x 0 for y<y Y (y Y )+x 2( Y )+x 0 for y Y <Y 2(y Y )+x 2( Y )+x 0 for y<y <Y Can you provide a utility function that represents these preferences? Plot some of the indifference curves. Why could these indifference curves capture an aspect of addiction? (0 points) Solution to Problem 2.. Using the implicit function theorem we have dx dp (f 0 x (x,p)) p (f 0 x (x,p)) x f x,p 00 (x,p) fx,x 00 (x,p). Since in a point of maximum the second order condition guarantees fx,p 00 (x,p) < 0, we can conclude that the sign of dx /dp is equal to the sign of the numerator, that is, to the sign of fx,p 00 (x,p). 2. A utility function that represents the preferences in the problem is u (x, y) x +(y Y ) if y Y x +2(y Y ) if y<y See the Figure for indifference curves. The consumer has the same preferences for x y as long as y is at least as large as Y. That is, she is willing to trade one unit of music for one unit of cupcake. If y falls below the minimum level Y, though, the preferences of the consumer change. For y below Y, the consumer wants two units of cupcake in exchange for one unit of music. Intuitively, this captures the existence of a reference point with respect to which the consumer is loss averse: the relative preference for good y increases when y falls below the reference point. This may capture a feature of addiction insofar as falling below the addictive level Y makes the consumer desire y more. 5