Mathematical Appendix. Ramsey Pricing

Similar documents
Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Pass-Through as an Economic Tool

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Answer Key: Problem Set 1

Price Customization and Targeting in Many-to-Many Matching Markets

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias. Web Appendix

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants,

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital?

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous?

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Monopoly, Pareto and Ramsey Mark-ups

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

STATIC LECTURE 4: CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION II - KUHN TUCKER THEORY

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Controlling versus enabling Online appendix

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Online Appendix for Dynamic Procurement under Uncertainty: Optimal Design and Implications for Incomplete Contracts

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Regional Market Power and Transport Capacity in the Gas Industry

AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES

Supermodular Games. Ichiro Obara. February 6, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Supermodular Games February 6, / 21

Efficiency and Braess Paradox under Pricing

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters

Mathematical Foundations II

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index.

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

Flow Control, Routing, and Performance with a For-profit Service Provider

Designing Optimal Pre-Announced Markdowns in the Presence of Rational Customers with Multi-unit Demands - Online Appendix

Oligopoly. Firm s Profit Maximization Firm i s profit maximization problem: Static oligopoly model with n firms producing homogenous product.

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Assortative Matching in Two-sided Continuum Economies

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility

arxiv: v2 [cs.ni] 13 Jun 2017

A Note of Caution on Using Hotelling Models in Platform Markets

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

Online Appendix to A search model of costly product returns by Vaiva Petrikaitė

Online Supplement for Bounded Rationality in Service Systems

Under-Employment and the Trickle-Down of Unemployment - Online Appendix Not for Publication

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics

Online Appendix for Dynamic Ex Post Equilibrium, Welfare, and Optimal Trading Frequency in Double Auctions

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness

a. This is an inequality constrained maximization problem. The Lagrangian is µ 1 q 1 = 0 µ 2 q 2 = 0 1 (q 1 ) φ φ c 2 (q 2) p 1 c 1(q 1 ) = 0

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

Basics of Game Theory

Part I: Exercise of Monopoly Power. Chapter 1: Monopoly. Two assumptions: A1. Quality of goods is known by consumers; A2. No price discrimination.

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies

Internet Peering, Capacity and Pricing

ONLINE APPENDIX. Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools

Perfect Competition in Markets with Adverse Selection

Prices and Heterogeneous Search Costs

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Answers to Spring 2014 Microeconomics Prelim

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

Do Shareholders Vote Strategically? Voting Behavior, Proposal Screening, and Majority Rules. Supplement

Monotone comparative statics Finite Data and GARP

Game of Platforms: Strategic Expansion in Two-Sided Markets

Social media and the news industry

Optimization, constrained optimization and applications of integrals.

Implementability, Walrasian Equilibria, and Efficient Matchings

Oligopoly with Hyperbolic Demand: ADifferential Game Approach 1

WARWICK ECONOMIC RESEARCH PAPERS

EconS Vertical Integration

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

On the Maximal Domain Theorem

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information

Durable goods monopolist

Cumulative Harm, Products Liability, and Bilateral Care* Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum

Screening and Adverse Selection in Frictional Markets

A Note on Cost Reducing Alliances in Vertically Differentiated Oligopoly. Abstract

Online Appendix for "Auctions in Markets: Common Outside Options and the Continuation Value Effect" Not intended for publication

Cupid s Invisible Hand

Online Appendix for "Affi rmative Action: One Size Does Not. Fit All"

Transcription:

Mathematical Appendix Ramsey Pricing PROOF OF THEOREM : I maximize social welfare V subject to π > K. The Lagrangian is V + κπ K the associated first-order conditions are that for each I + κ P I C I cn J κµ I + b J + κ b J N J = 0 or or letting λ [ ] [ ] P I C I cn J κ µ I κ + b + κ + κ J + b + κ J N J = 0 κ +κ P I = C I + cn J + λµ I [ λ]b J + λ b J N J Then solve for λ by substituting into the desired profit condition π = K : λ µ A N A + µ B N B + [b A + b B b A b ] B N A N B = K + b A + b B c N A N B I now turn to the two alternative forms of the Ramsey problem mentioned in the text. PROPOSITION 8: Interior Ramsey prices maximizing user surplus subject to the constraint that the firm makes a rate of return r on her variable costs must solve A P I = + r C I + cn J N J λ b J + [ λ]b J + λµ I }{{}}{{} cost-plus two-sided classical Ramsey pricing Theorem where λ subsidy in cost-plus terms required for Pigouvian prices { }} { b A + b B [ + r] c N A N B b A + b A b A b B N A N B N A µ A + N B µ B + } {{ } demoninator from Theorem

2 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2009 PROOF: The Lagrangian is V κπ rκ cn A N B + C A N A + C B N B with corresponding first-order conditions or letting λ κ P I κ + rc I + cn J + κµ I + b J [ κ] b J N J = 0 κ P I = + r C I + cn J + λµ I N J λ b J + [ λ]b J Plugging into the rate-of-return constraint π = rc yields α µ A N A + µ B N B + [b A + b B b A b ] B = b A + b B [ + r]c N A N B which yields the desired solution. Thus user Ramsey pricing with a required rate of return over variable costs is a natural combination of classical cost-plus regulation and the classical two-sided Ramsey pricing of Theorem. Prices mark-up costs by the required rate of return, incorporating two-sided internalization of cross-benefits and market power in the weighted-average fashion of classical Ramsey pricing above. Now that there is no required profit threshold, the weighting is given the amount necessary to offset the subsidy needed to achieve cost-plus Pigouvian pricing while maintaining the required rate of return. As noted earlier, if r = 0 and the platform must simply break even, the solution is identical to the break-even classical OT pricing. PROPOSITION 9: Interior Ramsey prices maximizing social surplus subject to the constraint that the firm makes a rate of return r on her variable costs must solve A 2 P I = + λrc I + cn J N }{{} J λb J + [ λ] b J + λµ I }{{} cost-plus two-sided classical Ramsey pricing Theorem

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE APPENDIX TO A PRICE THEORY OF MULTI-SIDED PLATFORMS 3 target profits Pigouvian subsidy { }}{ r C A N A + C B N B + cn A N B {}} { + b A + b B c N A N B where λ rc A + µ A N A + rc B + µ B N B + b A + b B b A b B + 2rc N A N B } {{ } local profit gain from moving towards rate-of-return maximization PROOF: The Lagrangian is now V + κ π r [C A N A + C B N B + cn A N B] giving first-order conditions + κp I + κ[ + r] C I κµ I + b I + κ b I N J + κ[ + r] cn J Letting λ +κ κ this takes the form in the text. Plugging this back into P A [ + r]c A N A + P B [ + r]c B N B + rcn A N B = 0 yields the definition for λ. The social Ramsey pricing problem with a required rate of return over variable costs is a slight modification of user-optimal Ramsey pricing in Proposition 9. Generalization PROOF OF THEOREM 2: I compute VJ I. By definition V I N = θ I I N ui N; θ I f I θ I dθ I = θ I :u I N;θ I P I N ui N; θ I f I θ I dθ I Because I is the boundary of I, by the Leibnitz Integral Rule VJ I = θ I u I I J N; θ I f I θ I dθ I + θ I I u I [ J N; θ I ] PJ I [N] u I N; θ I f I θ I dθ I = A 3 u I J N J + P I θ I I u I J [N; θ I] PJ I [N] f I θ I dθ I By the implicit function theorem for J I and letting Ñ I Ñ I P I P I J = Ñ I J Ñ I = }{{} The Leibnitz Integral Rule θ I I N ui J N; θ I f I θ I dθ I θ I I N f I θ I dθ I

4 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2009 Thus term second term in A 3 vanishes for I J. On other other hand for I = J by the implicit function theorem PI I = Ñ J I θ = I I N ui J N; θ I f I θ I dθ I θ I I N f I θ I dθ I Ñ I So the second term of A 3 is simply P I as the gross utility of all users in I is P I. Thus the first-order condition that marginal social benefit equal marginal cost becomes VJ I = C I J P I = C I J u J I N J which is the Pigouvian condition reported in the text. PROOF OF THEOREM 3: Here I begin by computing marginal revenues. For J I : while RJ I = PI N N I N J = PJ I N I = θ I I N ui N; θ J I f I θ I dθ I θ I I N f I θ I dθ I where ɛ I Ñ I P I P I Ñ I R I I = PI + P I I N I = P I + ũi I N I PI ɛ I N J = ũi J N J is the price elasticity of participation holding fixed anticipated participation. As usual, let µ I PI be the market power, that is the difference between price and ɛ I classical marginal revenue. Then equating marginal revenue to marginal cost requires P I µ I + J u J I N J = C I which can easily be re-arranged to yield either of the formulae in the theorem. I begin by showing that ρ I = µi Comparative Statics N I 2 π N I2 and that local strict concavity of profits is equivalent to the local version of 2SC, while violation of local weak 2SC implies local non-concavity. Then

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE APPENDIX TO A PRICE THEORY OF MULTI-SIDED PLATFORMS 5 taking these facts as given, I establish Theorem 4. ρ I d PI dc I N J = P I d N I dc I N J = µi N I 2 π N I2 Thus ρ I > 0 2 π 2 N I2 < 0 and 2 π N A2 2 π N > 2 π 2 B2 N A N B µa µ B N A N B > ρa ρ B χ 2 which shows that strict local 2SC implies local concavity by the classical Hessian test and weak 2SC is necessary for local concavity. Based on these, Theorem 4 is easy to establish. Two-sided contraction PROOF OF THEOREM 4: The forward direction of the proof follows directly from above: global concavity of profits which is equivalent to the negative definiteness of profits, which is 2SC in N A, N B is independent of C A, C B by inspection. For the converse, suppose that 2SC were violated at some pair of participation rates Ñ A, Ñ B. Let be evaluated at Ñ A, Ñ B C I P I µ I + b J N J cn J CA, C B has a solution at. Then clearly equation 2 given costs Ñ A, Ñ B. However because 2SC is violated here, this must be a local minimum or saddle-point of the firm s profits. Therefore it cannot be the optimal participation pair. In the Armstrong case, from equation 2 χ = b A + b B so 2SC becomes µ A µ B N A N B > ρa ρ B b A + b B 2 In the special case of linear demand that is typically analyzed, µi N I = φ I 2 P I P I b I N J where φ I is the constant slope of demand. If we parameterize demand by N I P I, N J = QI 2 P I so that Q I demand at price 0 and P I is the optimal price when there is no two-sidedness and

6 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2009 C I = 0 then σ I = QI 2 P I so the condition simplifies, after a bit of algebra, to b A + b B Q A Q B Q A QB P A P B 4 < 8 which is that the surplus generated by two-sidedness at zero price should not be more than 8 times the geometric mean of optimal profits on the two sides if there were no two-sidedness, as optimal profits for linear demand with this parameterization are Pigouvian second-order conditions QI P I 2. Now I derive the second-order conditions for the Pigouvian problem. The first derivative of social welfare V with respect to participation on side I is P I C I cn J + b J N J Taking the derivative with respect to N I yields P I + bj 2N J = µi N I + P J N J,N I b J N I b J f J B J, b J d B J db J N I = µi b N I + J b J b J f I P J [N J, N I ] b J N I, b J db J = µi N I + N J bj 2 µ J b J 2 = µi N I + N J 2 bj 2 µ J b J Thus the own-second derivative condition for concavity is that on both sides I µ A µ B N A N B > σ I where σ I is the variance of interaction benefits among marginal users on side I. The cross partial is then P A 2 c + b B N B N B = b A c + P B N B,N A b B N A b B f B B B, b B d B B db B N B = b A c + µb bb f I P B [N B, N A ] b B N A, b B db B N B = b A + b B c

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE APPENDIX TO A PRICE THEORY OF MULTI-SIDED PLATFORMS 7 So the positive determinant condition requires A 4 µ A µ B N A N B > ba + b B c 2 N A N B σ A N A N B σ B µ A µ B µ A µ B If imposed globally, just as with 2SC, these ensure sufficiency of first-order conditions. By the same argument as in Section III for 2SC, these conditions are weak in the sense of Theorem 4. In the RT2003 case, heterogeneity is unidimensional so all marginal users have the same preferences and σ A = σ B = 0. Therefore inequality A 4 becomes m A m B > 2 p A + p B c as p I = b I as there are only interaction values. By the first-order condition for the Pigouvian problem in the RT2003 case p A + p B c = s A = S B so this becomes m A m B > s A s B = ρ A ρ B m A m A > ρ A ρ B which is my social second-order condition from E. Glen Weyl 2009. In the Armstrong case µ A µ B N A N B > b A + b B 2 In the linear case, when ρ I = 2 this is exactly the private 2SC, except four times stronger. Positive comparative statics PROOF OF THEOREM 5: Letting R I N I, N J P I N I, N J N I be revenue on side I the cross partial is χ = R A 2 + RB 2 c = M RA N B + M RB N A c = P A + P AN A N B + P B + P B N B N A c = P A 2 + PA 2 N A + P B 2 + PB 2 N B c = b A + b A N A + b B + b B N B c = b A + b B c µã b N B µb b N A where M R I is the classical marginal revenue on side I. Thus there are substitutes complements

8 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2009 if bn A N B > <µ b. But by equation 7, µi = P I C I bj + c N J thus µ = 2 bn A N B BA + C A N A + BB C B N B = π + bn A N B Clearly µ, π > 0 so dividing through there are substitutes complements if bn A N B π + bn A N B < >µ b µ If µ B bn A N B µ b π + bn A > < N B µ π π + bn A N B > <µ B µ < 0 then we clearly have substitutes. Otherwise this is equivalent to π + bn A N B π µ b + µ B < > µ B bn A N B π < > µ b µ B Normative comparative statics PROOF OF THEOREM 6: By implicit differentiation of equation d N I dc J = N I ρ I χ µ I d N J dc J So dv I dc J = V I d N I dc J d N J dc J d N I dc J + V I 2 N I ρ I χ = µ I d N J dc J N I ρ I χ + b I b I where the constant of proportionality is positive by concavity of profits. Clearly the effect of an exogenous increase in side J participation, driven by cost, is the opposite of the effect of an increase in cost in sign, which is all I am concerned with.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE APPENDIX TO A PRICE THEORY OF MULTI-SIDED PLATFORMS 9 The Scale-Income Model In the SI model bi I = β I Bi I. I therefore index a user s type by her membership benefit Bi I. A user i on side I will participate if B I i + β I B I i N J > P I that is if Bi I P > I +β I N = νi N J P I if νi is positive and if B I J β I β I i < νi N J P I if νi is negative. Intuitively, ν I roughly represents the fraction of heterogeneity that is along the β I β I interaction dimension; if ν I is negative, then as prices rise interaction values tend to fall. Dividing by β I converts this into membership benefits. It may be either the large or small scale users that participate and they may have either positive or negative membership benefits. In what follows, I derive everything from first principles, as in unidimensional models my assumption of smoothness of f I fails. All the results would follow identically from directly specializing my more general results, as they did in the RT2003 and Armstrong cases; however, for expositional purposes it is useful to show how direct analysis of a unidimensional model leads to the same results as specializing general results from the RT2006 model. N I P I, N J = F I ν I[ N J ] P I if νi > 0 and N I = F I if νi β I β I β I < 0 where F I is the c.d.f. of membership values. Let D I B I F I or F I as appropriate. Then N I = νi β f I, where f I = F I I, and N2 I = ν I ν I P I f I. By the definition, ν β I β I I = ν I 2, yielding N2 I = ν I P I ν I 2 β I β I = ν I P I ν I β I Letting P I N I, N J be the inverse of N I with respect to its first argument, by the inverse and implicit function theorems we have P I = µi where µ I N I β I N I f I ν and P I I 2 = ν I P I = b I = β I D I N I = β I b I. Surplus on side I is ν I [ N J ] β I ν I [N J ] β I ν I [N J ]P I β I B I + β I B I N J P I f I B I d B I Using the change of variables φ I = BI β I V I ν I = β I P I ν I this becomes φ I P I f I ν I φ I β I dφ I = D I P I ν I φ I β I dφ I

0 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2009 by the standard integration by parts for surplus. Therefore V I = µi and V I 2 = ν I φ I P I β I ν I β I f I dφ I ν I P I N I = ν I φ I ν I P I β I f I dφ I ν I P I N I = ν I V I By E. Glen Weyl and Michal Fabinger s 2009 s Theorem 3, V I = N I µ I ρ I where µ I is the inverse hazard rate of D I with respect to φ at φ = P I and ρ I is an average of µ I N I P I φ > P I. Therefore to establish the formulae given in the text, I must show that, in fact, µ I = µ I and ρ I = ρ I. µ I N I = = D I φ φ I I =P I N I f I β I ν I = µi For the equivalence of ρ I to an average of ρ I, let me calculate ρ I. over ρ I = µi N I 2 π N I2 µ I = N I P I = ρ I µi Following a similar logic therefore χ = P A 2 + νb N B P B + νb P B µ I 2 c = νa P A + ν B P B c ν B N B µb N B µi 2 N I β I µ I 2 = f I N I ν I [N J ] N J χ = = N I β I f I I=A,B β I + N J N J ν I [ P I µ I] c = ν I N I β I f I = ν I µ I Because the natural analogs of the naïve simplifications from above are now apparent, I revert to directly using these, but direct derivations are available on request.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE APPENDIX TO A PRICE THEORY OF MULTI-SIDED PLATFORMS The sign of equilibrium network effects from side I to side J are now determined by ν J µ J ρ J + ρ J [ ] ν K P K µ K c K =A,B K =A,B As stated in the text, if the second term is positive as in the newspaper case and the first term also is as on the advertiser side, because ν B > 0 then clearly equilibrium externalities from readers to advertisers are positive. On the reader s side the second term is positive, but the first is negative as ν A < 0. The equilibrium network effect will tend to be positive when complementarity is large relative to reader-side market power and when pass-through is decreasing, so that inframarginal harms are small relative to the pass-through of marginal cost changes. The own-side cost-welfare effect on side I µ A µ B + [ ] ν K P K µ K c ρ J ν I µ I ρ I N A N B µ J + ν I ρ J ρ I N A N B [ ] ν K P K µ K c K =A,B For advertisers this is clearly negative as both terms are. For readers this is again ambiguous: while they lose from the higher prices the gain from resulting reduction in the Spence distortion and therefore advertising. Thus it is not clear that readers will be worse off as the newspaper business becomes less competitive, because on both sides of the market reduced competition is likely to lead to higher advertising rates and this may improve reader welfare. Applications In this appendix I describe formally the GASH model of duopoly, derive equilibrium conditions for it and use these to state formally and prove the results I referred to in Subsection VI.C. Armstrong only considers a linear demand, product differentiated model where all users must choose one platform in the spirit of Harold Hotelling 929, making it impossible to compare monopoly to competition as under monopoly the platform would charge infinite prices. Demand Users on each side I have a usage benefit b I which depends only on which side of the market they are on, not which platform they use nor their identity. users have a membership benefit for

2 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2009 each platform and 2, B I, i and B I,2 i respectively, drawn from a symmetric density function g I : R 2 R. Given a vector, consisting of a pair of side I prices and a pair of participation levels on side J, P I,i, P I, i, N J,i, N J, i, we can write the number of side I agents that choose to participate on platform i. Let us call this N I,i, where N I,i P I,i, P I, i, N J,i, N J, i = B I,i +b I N J,i P I,i +P I, i b I N J, i P I,i b I N J,i g I B I,i, B I, i d B I, i d B I,i. Let R I,i b I N J,i P I,i be the payoff an agent on side I receives from joining platform i, net of membership benefits. We can then express the number of side I agents that participate of platform i as N I,i = N I,i P I,i, N J,i, R I, i, where N I,i P I,i, N J,i, R I, i = P I,i b I N J,i B I,i +b I N J,i P I,i R I, i g I B I,i, B I, i d B I, i d B I,i. Note that as N I,i is strictly decreasing in it s first argument, it can be inverted, yielding a well defined inverse demand P I,i N I,i, N J,i, R I, i. Duopoly equilibrium Supposing that both firm and firm 2 offer insulating tariffs on both sides of the market; that is, P I,i P J,i = b I N J,i + h I,i for some chosen h I,i as the insulating tariff for the Armstrong model is just full insurance. We can the consider each firm i to choose participation levels on each side, taking as given R A, i and R B, i. Thus, in equilibrium, each firm maximizes, with respect to N I,i, I = A, B, A 5 [P A,i N A,i, N B,i, R A, i C A ]N A,i + [P B,i N B,i, N A,i, R B, i C B ]N B,i The first-order condition for maximization of A 5, with respect to N I,i, is A 6 P I,i C I + P I,i N I,i + P J,i 2 N J,i = 0

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE APPENDIX TO A PRICE THEORY OF MULTI-SIDED PLATFORMS 3 Note that, by the inverse function theorem, P I,i =, and that by the implicit function theorem, P I,i 2 = N I,i 2 N J,i. Calculating N I,i, we find N I,i N I,i R I, i = g I P I,i N J,i b I N j,i, B I, i d B I, i }{{} market expansion g I B I,i, B I,i + b I N J,i P I,i N J,i R I,i d B I,i. P I,i N J,i b I N } J,i {{} cannibalization Calculating N I,i 2, we find R I, i N I,i 2 = + b I g I P I,i N J,i b I N j,i, B I, i d B I, i P I,i N J,i b I N J,i b I g I B I,i, B I,i + b I N J,i P I,i N J,i R I,i d B I,i = b I N I,i Thus, A 6 can be rewritten A 7 P I,i C I + b J N J,i = N I,i N I,i µ I,i o where µ I,i o is firm i s own-price market power on side I. Equation A 7 can be thought of as governing firm i s best-response to firm i s choices of R I, i. Thus the conditions for a symmetric-across-firms SAF equilibrium in insulting tariffs, what I call an symmetric insulated equilibrium SIE, it must be the case that for I = A, B and i =, 2 A 8 P I C I + b J N J 2 = µi o where P I is the SIE price on side I, N J is the total market participation on side J and µ I o is the SAF own-price market power on side I.

4 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2009 Monopoly Suppose firms i and i can act, via merger or some other means, in such a way so as to maximize joint profits. Then, assuming the platforms choose a SAF strategy, they solve max N I,m { 2 I [ P I,m N I,m, N J,m C I] N I,m } where P I,m N I,m, N J,m is the inverse, with respect to the first argument, of N I,m P I,m, N J,m, the number of side I agents who join any one of the two symmetric platforms B I,m N I,m P I,m N J,m, N J,m = g I B I,m, B I, m d B I, m d B I,m P I,m N J,m b I N J,m The first-order condition of the platforms is P I C I + b J N J where µ I is the joint market power and 2 = N I,m N I,m µ I P I,m N I,m b I N J,m = g I P I,m b I N J,m, B I, m d B I m Note that µ I N I, N J > µ I o N I, N J for any pair of participation rates N I, N J as the denominator of µ I does not include the strictly positive cannibalization term of µ I o. Merger effects PROPOSITION 0: Assume 2SC for the Armstrong model applied to the monopoly optimum in this context: ρ I > 0 for both I and µa µ B > ρ A ρ B b A + b B 2 N A N. Then participation and B welfare are higher on both sides of the market under duopoly than under monopoly. PROOF: Rewrite condition A8 as P I C I + b J N J = µ I µ I MI o M I

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE APPENDIX TO A PRICE THEORY OF MULTI-SIDED PLATFORMS 5 Let G I N I, N J = MI o and let the value of G I at SIE participation rates N M I A, N B be G I. Note that G I, G I > 0 as noted above. Inthe monopoly problem costs are given by C I tg I for t [0, ]. Clearly for t = 0 the solution is the same as the SAF monopoly optimum which is unique by the assumed second-order conditions. For t =, the allocation must be the same as at the SIE equilibrium. But by my reasoning in Section III.A, participation rates on the two sides of the markets are complements, so a fall in either cost raises both participation rates. Thus an increase in t must raise both participation rates. Therefore participation on both sides of the market is higher under the SIE equilibrium than under the SAF monopoly optimum. Furthermore in the Armstrong model welfare on each side of the market depends directly only on participation on that side as there is no Spence distortion, so both groups of users must be better off. Finally, because participation rates are below their optimal level for any amount of market power on both sides, the resulting increase in participation on both sides must be social welfare enhancing. Thus a merger without efficiencies from a SIE equilibrium is harmful to participation, both groups of users welfare and overall social welfare. This result contrasts significantly with the RT2003 model, where competition can easily harm one or even both groups of users. Of course the result depends on a particular assumption about tariffs, namely that firms use insulating tariffs. In a previous version of this paper I proved that this result was significantly more robust and holds in a very wide range of reasonable cases with non-insulating tariffs. Those results, omitted for the sake of brevity and clarity, are available on request. REFERENCES Hotelling, Harold. 929. Stability in Competition. Economic Journal, 3953: 4 57. Weyl, E. Glen. 2009. Monopoly, Ramsey and Lindahl in Rochet and Tirole 2003. Economics Letters, 032: 99 00. Weyl, E. Glen, and Michal Fabinger. 2009. Pass-Through as an Economic Tool. http://www.fas.harvard.edu/ weyl/research.htm.