The Ins and Outs of UK Unemployment

Similar documents
The Ins and Outs of Unemployment in a Dual Labor Market

Productivity and Job Flows: Heterogeneity of New Hires and Continuing Jobs in the Business Cycle

The Dark Corners of the Labor Market

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Lecture 1: Facts To Be Explained

What Accounts for the Growing Fluctuations in FamilyOECD Income March in the US? / 32

Mortenson Pissarides Model

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Notes on Time Series Modeling

Plant Life Cycle and Aggregate Employment. Dynamics 1

ow variables (sections A1. A3.); 2) state-level average earnings (section A4.) and rents (section

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 4. VARs With Long-Run Restrictions

THE SLOW JOB RECOVERY IN A MACRO MODEL OF SEARCH AND RECRUITING INTENSITY. I. Introduction

Labor-market Volatility in Matching Models with Endogenous Separations

The Dark Corners of the Labor Market

On the extent of job-to-job transitions

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014

Solutions of the Financial Risk Management Examination

Unemployment and Mismatch in the UK

Revisiting Initial Jobless Claims as a Labor Market Indicator. John Carter Braxton May 2013; Revised March 2014 RWP 13-03

Appendix for "Productivity and Unemployment over the Business Cycle" Regis Barnichon October 03, 2009

Nowcasting GDP with Real-time Datasets: An ECM-MIDAS Approach

Decision 411: Class 3

An adaptation of Pissarides (1990) by using random job destruction rate

THE DARK CORNERS OF THE LABOR MARKET

Charting Employment Loss in North Carolina Textiles 1

TIGER: Tracking Indexes for the Global Economic Recovery By Eswar Prasad and Karim Foda

Decision 411: Class 3

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Decision 411: Class 3

Business Cycle Dating Committee of the Centre for Economic Policy Research. 1. The CEPR Business Cycle Dating Committee

A Stock-Flow Theory of Unemployment with Endogenous Match Formation

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

Cross-Sectional Vs. Time Series Benchmarking in Small Area Estimation; Which Approach Should We Use? Danny Pfeffermann

Perceived productivity and the natural rate of interest

Lecture Notes # 1 Tito Boeri

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP Measuring monetary policy deviations from the Taylor rule

Technical note on seasonal adjustment for M0

Measuring Mismatch in the U.S. Labor Market

1 Regression with Time Series Variables

A Diagnostic for Seasonality Based Upon Autoregressive Roots

1.2. Structural VARs

Discussion of "Noisy News in Business Cycle" by Forni, Gambetti, Lippi, and Sala

Errata for the ASM Study Manual for Exam P, Fourth Edition By Dr. Krzysztof M. Ostaszewski, FSA, CFA, MAAA

Daily Welfare Gains from Trade

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

1 The social planner problem

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach

Seasonal Adjustment using X-13ARIMA-SEATS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNEMPLOYMENT AND PRODUCTIVITY IN THE LONG RUN: THE ROLE OF MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY

Working Papers. Elasticities of Labor Supply and Labor Force Participation Flows. WP January 2019

Approximating fixed-horizon forecasts using fixed-event forecasts

1 Correlation between an independent variable and the error

1 The Multiple Regression Model: Freeing Up the Classical Assumptions

Stock Sampling with Interval-Censored Elapsed Duration: A Monte Carlo Analysis

Frictional Wage Dispersion in Search Models: A Quantitative Assessment

Reverse engineering labor market flows (work in progress) Tamás K. Papp Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna.

Aggregate Supply. A Nonvertical AS Curve. implications for unemployment, rms pricing behavior, the real wage and the markup

Consumption Risk Sharing over the Business Cycle: the Role of Small Firms Access to Credit Markets

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Lecture Notes on Measurement Error

Job Search over the Life Cycle

Recessions and the Information Content of Unemployment

Online Appendix: Misclassification Errors and the Underestimation of the U.S. Unemployment Rate

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHERE ARE WE NOW? REAL-TIME ESTIMATES OF THE MACRO ECONOMY. Martin D.D. Evans

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Lecture on State Dependent Government Spending Multipliers

Dependence of evaporation on meteorological variables at di erent time-scales and intercomparison of estimation methods

Source: US. Bureau of Economic Analysis Shaded areas indicate US recessions research.stlouisfed.org

Hansen s basic RBC model

Unemployment Fluctuations, Match Quality, and the Wage Cyclicality of New Hires

Lecture 4: Linear panel models

The Informational Content of Unemployment: Equilibrium Forces and Dynamics

ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES. The Dark Corners of the Labor Market

Chapter 8 - Forecasting

University of Southampton Research Repository eprints Soton

TIGER: Tracking Indexes for the Global Economic Recovery By Eswar Prasad, Karim Foda, and Ethan Wu

The linear regression model: functional form and structural breaks

Equilibrium Unemployment in a General Equilibrium Model 1

Technical note on seasonal adjustment for Capital goods imports

Bayesian Variable Selection for Nowcasting Time Series

This is a repository copy of Estimating Quarterly GDP for the Interwar UK Economy: An Application to the Employment Function.

Labor Market Frictions and Aggregate Employment

Analysis of climate-crop yield relationships in Canada with Distance Correlation

Housing and the Business Cycle

Job Search Behavior over the Business Cycle

Wage Di erentials in the Presence of Unobserved Worker, Firm, and Match Heterogeneity

Appendix to The Life-Cycle and the Business-Cycle of Wage Risk - Cross-Country Comparisons

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

Introduction to Macroeconomics

On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables

The Superiority of Greenbook Forecasts and the Role of Recessions

Business Failure and Labour Market Fluctuations

Euro-indicators Working Group

Data Matrix User Guide

Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction

Outline. Nature of the Problem. Nature of the Problem. Basic Econometrics in Transportation. Autocorrelation

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Incorporating a Simple DMP Version of the Labor Market and Rediscovering the Shimer Puzzle

Transcription:

University of Warwick 9 July 2009

I Do in ows or out ows drive unemployment dynamics? I Spate of recent US work inspired by Hall (2005) and Shimer (2005, 2007) s claim that job nding dominates and separations have no cyclical impact. I Fujita and Ramey (2009), Davis, Faberman, Haltiwanger and Rucker (2008), Elsby, Michaels and Solon (2009): in ow rate not constant, indeed leads changes unemployment and accounts for just under half of unemployment variance. I Should search/matching models have a constant separation rate? I Shimer s work inspired much theoretical development (Blanchard and Gali, 2008; Gertler and Trigari, 2006).

I BHPS present great opportunity to study UK. I Allow 3-state model including those not in employment E or unemployment U: "inactive" I. I Two recent studies Petrongolo and Pissarides (2008) and Gomes (2009) rely on LFS: bigger, but shorter and quarterly. Elsby, Hobijn and Sahin (2008) use annual OECD-LFS data. I Quarterly data miss a lot of transitions through time aggregation (Shimer, 2007). I Measuring U Q1! E Q2 wrongly omits those who go U Q1! E! (U Q2 or I Q2 ) and wrongly adds those who go U Q1! I! E Q2. I Missed transitions might well be cyclical, so cyclicality will be wrongly measured.

Data Issues Method Status, transitions and transition rates I BHPS data are annual, but in principle capture all spells through recalled job history. I In addition to the 1990-2007 intra-panel spells (Waves A to Q) there are also the (largely) pre-panel labour market/job histories recorded in Waves B and C.

Data Issues Method Status, transitions and transition rates I Recall error. I Elias (1996), Paull (2002), Jürges (2007). I Misclassi cation error. I Poterba and Summers (1986), Fujita and Ramey (2006). I Margin error. I Abowd and Zellner (1985), Poterba and Summers (1986), Fujita and Ramey (2006). I Dependent interviewing. I Jäckle and Lynn (2007), Nagypàl (2007), Fallick and Fleischman (2004).

Data Issues Method Status, transitions and transition rates Create monthly dataset. I Use Paull (2002) method of reconciling data inconsistencies between Waves. I Include all age 16 and above. I 127,920 spells across 30,731 individuals are allocated to months (September 1912 to March 2008). I 27.12 million month-individual cells. I Status classi ed as E, U or I: 4.09 million individual-month observations. I Within the panel (Sep 90 - Aug 97): 2.99 million E, U or I individual-month observations, 1.74 million with non-zero weight.

Data Issues Method Status, transitions and transition rates E 63.9% U 3.7% I 32.4% U (E + U) 5.5% Status proportions (weighted) Transitions between months are summed (using weights) to give the various (weighted) ows. I 1,469,945 total ows; I 1,454,547 excluding missing status but including those where status stays the same; I 20,612 ow transitions involving a change of status between E, U or I.

BHPS LFS q BD EU 0.31 0.4 0.9 UE 0.33 0.5 1.0 EI 0.34 0.5 1.7 IE 0.27 0.4 2.0 UI 0.09 0.3 0.9 IU 0.07 0.4 0.9 Total 1.40 2.5 7.4 Data Issues Method Status, transitions and transition rates I As is well known, ows are smaller in the UK than the US. I The BHPS-LFS di erence may re ect the di erent sample populations or time aggregation. Monthly ows as proportion of population BHPS gures are gross ows divided by sample population, for all individuals aged 16 and over during September 1990 to August 2007. LFS source: Gomes (2009); calculation based on time aggregation correction of quarterly data for working-age individuals, 1996-2008. BD are calculated from Blanchard and Diamond (1990, Figure 1); gross ows divided by population, from CPS January 1968 to May 1986 (without Abowd-Zellner adjustment).

BHPS LFS q BD EU 0.31 0.4 0.9 UE 0.33 0.5 1.0 EI 0.34 0.5 1.7 IE 0.27 0.4 2.0 UI 0.09 0.3 0.9 IU 0.07 0.4 0.9 Total 1.40 2.5 7.4 Data Issues Method Status, transitions and transition rates BHPS EE 59.57 UU 3.19 II 34.79 Total 97.55 Monthly ows as proportion of population BHPS gures are gross ows divided by sample population, for all individuals aged 16 and over during September 1990 to August 2007. LFS source: Gomes (2009); calculation based on time aggregation correction of quarterly data for working-age individuals, 1996-2008. BD are calculated from Blanchard and Diamond (1990, Figure 1); gross ows divided by population, from CPS January 1968 to May 1986 (without Abowd-Zellner adjustment).

BHPS LFS q BD EU 0.31 0.4 0.9 UE 0.33 0.5 1.0 EI 0.34 0.5 1.7 IE 0.27 0.4 2.0 UI 0.09 0.3 0.9 IU 0.07 0.4 0.9 Total 1.40 2.5 7.4 Data Issues Method Status, transitions and transition rates BHPS EE 59.57 UU 3.19 II 34.79 Total 97.55 Monthly ows as proportion of population BHPS EM 0.42 ME 0.16 UM 0.05 MU 0.05 IM 0.32 MI 0.05 Total 1.05 BHPS gures are gross ows divided by sample population, for all individuals aged 16 and over during September 1990 to August 2007. LFS source: Gomes (2009); calculation based on time aggregation correction of quarterly data for working-age individuals, 1996-2008. BD are calculated from Blanchard and Diamond (1990, Figure 1); gross ows divided by population, from CPS January 1968 to May 1986 (without Abowd-Zellner adjustment).

Data Issues Method Status, transitions and transition rates Monthly ow rates are calculated; e.g. UE t /U t U t 1 UE t + UI t + UU t + UM t. 1 - where I If a discrete time model is correct, these ow rates represent transition probabilities Λ UE t since then UE t = Λ UE t U t 1. I Flow rates are individually seasonally adjusted using the Census Bureau s X12 program. Assuming transition probabilities follow a Poisson distribution, transition probability and transition rate are related as follows: Λ UE t 1 exp λue t I so the transition rate for job nding is λ UE t ln 1 Λ UE t. I assume that transition rates are constant within months.

Data Issues Method Status, transitions and transition rates Contributions of the various ows to the dynamics of the unemployment rate are calculated: I rst assuming that actual unemployment is very close to its steady state level. I then allowing past ow rates to a ect current unemployment.

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment The dynamics of unemployment are such that: U t = U t 1 + EU t UE t + IU t UI t (1) U t = U t 1 + Λ EU t E t 1 Λ UE t U t 1 + Λ IU t I t 1 Λ UI t U t 1 where (if the discrete-time model is correct) Λ EU t is the separation probability, Λ UE t is the job nding probability, and Λ IU t and Λ UI t denote the probabilities of moves between inactivity and unemployment and in the reverse direction. I If it is not possible to make more than one transition per month, transition rates can be read directly from the ows data since then UE t = 1 exp λue t U t 1.

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment But if individuals can both nd and lose a job within a month: in a 3-statemodel, the measured UE ow over t UE t = 1 exp λue t U t 1 I will include - wrongly in e ect of time aggregation z } { Z 1 + 1 terms of obtaining the exp λie t (1 τ) UI t+τ dτ continuous-time transition 0 rate λ UE t - those who e ect of time aggregation z } { Z 1 1 went U! I! E. exp (λeu t +λ EI t )(1 τ) I UE t+τ dτ will exclude - again 0 wrongly in terms of obtaining λ UE t - those where τ =[0,1) is the time elapsed since the last who went U! E! U or U! E! I. data observation at discrete intervals t={0,1,2,...}. The above is one equation from the total of three two-equation systems each involving all 6 transition rates. There is no analytical solution but the system can be solved numerically.

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment Does time aggregation matter? I BHPS data show that, in the UK, intra-month transitions are rare: weighted total 370.09 (unweighted 533) (during panel Sep 90 to Apr 08). I This is 1.8% of the 20,612 weighted total E-U-I transitions during the period. I Petrongolo and Pissarides (2008) report little di erence in results even with (two-state) quarterly UK LFS I but this presumably refers to contributions to unemployment dynamics rather than transition rate estimates.

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment Can calculate whether intra-quarter ows are important using BHPS data. The following charts show ow rates: I Quarterly average of monthly ow rates (SA) forms the basis for later analysis. 1 3 3 m=1 (UE m /U m 1 ) = 1 3 3 m=1 (Pr [E m j U m 1 ] U m 1 ) U m 1. I Quarterly ow rates sum monthly ows over the quarter and divide by the base status at the start of the quarter. 3 m=1 UE m U0 = 3 m=1 Pr [E m j U m 1 ] U m 1 U0. I LFS quarterly ow rates just capture the di erence in status between start and end of quarter. I I omitting relevant transitions that are not maintained until the end of the quarter; and mistakenly adding status changes that actually result from two other transitions. (Pr ( E 3 j U 0 ) U 0 ) U 0.

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment Separations: EU flow rates Job finding: UE flow rates 0.005.01.015.02.025 0.1.2.3.4 1989q1 1993q3 1998q1 2002q3 2007q1 1989q1 1993q3 1998q1 2002q3 2007q1 Quarterly NSA Quarterly SA LFS PP(2008) Quarterly NSA flowque LFS PP(2008) Monthly NSA Monthly SA Monthly NSA Monthly SA

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment Comparing BHPS and LFS quarterly ow rates gives an indication of the proportion of transitions missed in LFS data through their time aggregation over quarters (meaning that intra-quarter ows that are not maintained for the full quarter are missed, and intra-quarter ows via another state are erroneously included). Mean 1992q1-2005q3 Quarterly ow rate EU UE BHPS 1.47% 29.3% LFS (PP 2008) 1.26% 23.6% Implied necessary time aggregation correction 13.8% 17.9%

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment 0.005.01.015.02.025 EI flow rates 0.01.02.03.04 IE flow rates 1989q1 1993q3 1998q1 2002q3 2007q1 1989q1 1993q3 1998q1 2002q3 2007q1 Quarterly SA LFS PP(2008) Monthly SA Quarterly SA LFS PP(2008) Monthly SA

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment 0.05.1.15.2 UI flow rates 0.01.02.03 IU flow rates 1989q1 1993q3 1998q1 2002q3 2007q1 1989q1 1993q3 1998q1 2002q3 2007q1 Quarterly SA LFS PP(2008) Monthly SA Quarterly SA LFS PP(2008) Monthly SA

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment Simple measures of the relative importance of in ows and out ows in driving unemployment can be derived if we (can) assume that unemployment is well approximated by its steady state value. I In continuous time, and in a 2-state world, the unemployment rate evolves according to u = λ EU e λ UE u λ EU (1 u) λ UE u. (2) I Steady state u implies in ows=ou ows: λ EU (1 u) = λ UE u. I u = λeu λ EU +λ UE s s+f.

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment In a 3-state world: I (U in ows=out ows) λ EU e + λ IU i = λ UE u + λ UI u and I (E in ows=out ows) λ UE u + λ IE i = λ EU e + λ EI e. Then u = λ EI λ IU + λ IE λ EU + λ IU λ EU λ EI λ IU + λ IE λ EU + λ IU λ EU + λ UI λ IE + λ IU λ UE + λ IE λ UE. (3)

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment Equilibrium unemployment rates based on monthly and quarterly flows 0.02.04.06.08.1.12 1989q1 1993q3 1998q1 2002q3 2007q1 BHPS equil u BHPS quarterly equil u I Despite the importance of time aggregation for ow rates, steady state unemployment rates calculated on the basis of the relevant (3-state) quarterly and monthly transition rates are almost identical.

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment 0.02.04.06.08.1.12 Unemployment rates 1989q1 1993q3 1998q1 2002q3 2007q1 BHPS u BHPS equil u LFS equil u (PP2008) I Actual unemployment based on BHPS stocks moves quite closely with equilibrium unemployment, except when actual unemployment is changing fast.

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment 0.02.04.06.08.1.12 Unemployment rates 1989q1 1993q3 1998q1 2002q3 2007q1 BHPS u BHPS equil u LFS equil u (PP2008) LFS u I Actual unemployment based on BHPS stocks moves quite closely with equilibrium unemployment, except when actual unemployment is changing fast.

Discrete-time model Continuous-time model Flow rates and in uence of quarterly time aggregation Steady state unemployment The importance of the speed at which unemployment is changing is clear from rearranging (2): u u = s u s + f + s + f. s s+f will be less important the larger is turnover. I In the US, the approximation u = 2007; Fujita and Ramey, 2008). s+f s s+f, i.e. the faster is labour holds well (Shimer, I investigate decompositions allowing for past separation and job nding rates to impact current unemployment. I will show that deviations from steady state in the UK are common, large, and a ect the measured relative importance of job nding and separation.

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition Shimer (2005), Hall (2005), Shimer (2007): empirical work using CPS showing that separation rate acyclical and job nding rate procyclical. I so rise in unemployment during recessions is driven (only) by a reduction in the job nding probability. I Finding has in uenced development of search-matching models (e.g. Blanchard and Gali, 2008). I Recent empirical work, even using Shimer s own data, claims to reinstate a role for separations in driving unemployment.

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition I The relative importance of separations and job nding are sometimes measured by their cyclical correlations with unemployment, productivity,... I Alternatively their importance can be measured in terms of their relative contributions to unemployment dynamics. I If actual and steady-state unemployment move closely together, simple decompositions can be used (Fujita and Ramey, 2008; Petrongolo and Pissarides, 2008; Elsby, Michaels and Solon, 2009) I Rearrange (3): I u t = I λ EU t λ EI λ IU λ IU +λ IE + λei t λ IU t λ EU t λ IU t +λ IE t + λei t λ IU t λ IU t +λ IE t + λ UE t + λui t λ IU t λ IE t +λ IE t capture u in ows working via inactivity. s t s t + f t (4)

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition Then the dynamics of u can be decomposed into contributions arising from the various ows: u t u t = s t s t + f t s t 1 s t 1 + f t 1 (5) = (1 u t ) u t 1 s t s t 1 {z } u s t u t (1 u t 1 ) f t f t 1 {z } u f t

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition Can use (4) to decompose s t and f t in (5), obtaining the contributions to steady state unemployment dynamics from separation and job nding rates and the contributions working through inactivity.

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition Can also obtain betas from (5) (and (4)): the contributions to the variance of u t : β s = cov ( u t, ut s ) var ( u t ), β f = cov ut, ut f var ( u t ) β EU = cov u t, ut EU, β EIU = cov u t, u EIU t var ( u t ) var ( u t ) β UE = cov u t, ut UE var ( u t ), β UIE = cov u t, ut UIE var ( u t ) If u t u t then β s β f β EU + β EIU u t u s t u f t. β UE + β UIE 1, since

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition Variance contribution BHPS LFS CPS β s 0.601 β f 0.418 β EU 0.279 0.352 0.325 β UE 0.354 0.133 0.053 β EIU 0.322 0.364 0.588 β UIE 0.065 0.151 0.035 Covariance contributions to unemployment variance BHPS: 1988q4-2007q2; LFS (Petrongolo and Pissarides, 2008): Claimant count: 1992q1-2005q3; CPS (Petrongolo and Pissarides, 2008 using Shimer, 2007, CPS data for 1967-2006) I Overall, job separations (EU and EI ) play the biggest role in unemployment uctuations. I But direct unemployment-employment transitions are more in uential than employment-unemployment.

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition Given the at times graphically obvious deviation of unemployment from steady state, I investigate the impact of allowing for past changes in in ow and out ow rates to a ect current unemployment. A discrete-time version of (2), using s and f to represent transition rates in a 2-state model, is: du t dt = s t (1 u t ) f t u t Solving this forward one month gives u t = ρ t u t + (1 ρ t ) u t 1 where ρ t is the monthly rate of convergence of u t to the steady state u t : ρ t = 1 exp (s t +f t )

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition If ρ t 6= 1, Elsby, Hobijn and Sahin (2008) show that ln u t ρ t 1 (1 u t ) [ ln s t ln f t ] {z } ut s and ut f as before + ρ t 1 1 ρ t 2 ρ t 2 ln u t 1 {z } due to devns from ss caused by past changes in s and f I If ρ t = 1, 8t, there are no deviations from steady state. I If ρ t = ρ, 8t, changes in u t are a distributed lag of current and past changes in s t and f t.

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition Contributions to unemployment variance are again expressed in terms of betas. I Here β s = cov ( ln u t,c s t ) var ( ln u t ) and β f (similarly de ned) represent the contribution to changes in the (log) unemployment rate of the cumulative contribution of current and past changes in transition rates C s t and C f t. Ct s = ρ t 1 (1 u t 1 ) ln s t + 1 ρ t 2 Ct s 1 ρ t 2 Ct f = ρ t 1 (1 u t 1 ) ln f t + 1 ρ t 2 Ct f 1 ρ t 2 I where C s 0 C f 0 0.

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition I There is also a contribution from the initial deviation from steady state at t = 0: I where C 0 0 ln u 0; C 0 t = ρ t 1 1 ρ t 2 ρ t 2 C 0 t 1 I and a possible contribution from the residual, which captures everything not included in the second-order expansion: it should be zero if the lags used fully capture actual unemployment dynamics.

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition Variance contribution BHPS OECD-LFS β s 0.223 0.569 β f 0.021 0.417 β 0-0.024 0.008 β residual 0.779 0.006 Covariance contributions to unemployment variance BHPS: 1988q4-2007q2; OECD-LFS (Elsby, Hobijn and Sahin, 2008): 1983-2007 I Note that the large residual in the BHPS case results because monthly, rather than annual, unemployment dynamics are involved.

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition I Results suggest a role for separations in UK unemployment dynamics. I UK unemployment dynamics are clearly more complex than previous models have allowed for. I Aspects of ows involving inactivity deserve more attention. I Reweighting pre-panel data may avoid some of the apparent recall error observed by Elias (1996) and enable investigation over a larger number of business cycles.

Background Measuring contributions Steady state decomposition Non-steady state decomposition THE END