Problem Set 3

Similar documents
MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS: OPTIMIZATION. Contents

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

ECON 4117/5111 Mathematical Economics

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy.

U e = E (U\E) e E e + U\E e. (1.6)

Lakehead University ECON 4117/5111 Mathematical Economics Fall 2002

E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Computational Optimization. Mathematical Programming Fundamentals 1/25 (revised)

cse303 ELEMENTS OF THE THEORY OF COMPUTATION Professor Anita Wasilewska

Constrained Optimization

Properties of Walrasian Demand

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

UNDERGROUND LECTURE NOTES 1: Optimality Conditions for Constrained Optimization Problems

Mathematical Preliminaries for Microeconomics: Exercises

ECON 5111 Mathematical Economics

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

Constrained maxima and Lagrangean saddlepoints

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9

M17 MAT25-21 HOMEWORK 6

Topology, Math 581, Fall 2017 last updated: November 24, Topology 1, Math 581, Fall 2017: Notes and homework Krzysztof Chris Ciesielski

Course Notes for EE227C (Spring 2018): Convex Optimization and Approximation

Chapter 1 Preliminaries

Lecture 4: Optimization. Maximizing a function of a single variable

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

NAME: Mathematics 205A, Fall 2008, Final Examination. Answer Key

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16

Solutions. F x = 2x 3λ = 0 F y = 2y 5λ = 0. λ = 2x 3 = 2y 5 = x = 3y 5. 2y 1/3 z 1/6 x 1/2 = 5x1/2 z 1/6. 3y 2/3 = 10x1/2 y 1/3

15 Real Analysis II Sequences and Limits , Math for Economists Fall 2004 Lecture Notes, 10/21/2004

Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

Econ 508-A FINITE DIMENSIONAL OPTIMIZATION - NECESSARY CONDITIONS. Carmen Astorne-Figari Washington University in St. Louis.

Mathematics II, course

Homework 3 Suggested Answers

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han

Lecture Notes: Math Refresher 1

Computational Optimization. Convexity and Unconstrained Optimization 1/29/08 and 2/1(revised)

Lecture 1. Econ 2001: Introduction to Mathematical Methods (a.k.a. Math Camp) 2015 August 10

Chapter 1 The Real Numbers

DO NOT OPEN THIS QUESTION BOOKLET UNTIL YOU ARE TOLD TO DO SO

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES

Assignment 1: From the Definition of Convexity to Helley Theorem

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

2019 Spring MATH2060A Mathematical Analysis II 1

The general programming problem is the nonlinear programming problem where a given function is maximized subject to a set of inequality constraints.

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists

Math 564 Homework 1. Solutions.

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline

MA651 Topology. Lecture 10. Metric Spaces.

Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces

Handout 2 (Correction of Handout 1 plus continued discussion/hw) Comments and Homework in Chapter 1

Iowa State University. Instructor: Alex Roitershtein Summer Homework #1. Solutions

Constrained optimization.

Metric Space Topology (Spring 2016) Selected Homework Solutions. HW1 Q1.2. Suppose that d is a metric on a set X. Prove that the inequality d(x, y)

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Solutions to Sample Problems for Midterm

In N we can do addition, but in order to do subtraction we need to extend N to the integers

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

In N we can do addition, but in order to do subtraction we need to extend N to the integers

Extreme Abridgment of Boyd and Vandenberghe s Convex Optimization

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Supergradients. KC Border Fall 2001 v ::15.45

Copyright c 2007 Jason Underdown Some rights reserved. statement. sentential connectives. negation. conjunction. disjunction

ECARES Université Libre de Bruxelles MATH CAMP Basic Topology

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

Mathematical Methods in Economics (Part I) Lecture Note

Writing proofs for MATH 51H Section 2: Set theory, proofs of existential statements, proofs of uniqueness statements, proof by cases

Math 5052 Measure Theory and Functional Analysis II Homework Assignment 7

Concave programming. Concave programming is another special case of the general constrained optimization. subject to g(x) 0

Chapter 2 Convex Analysis

Lakehead University ECON 4117/5111 Mathematical Economics Fall 2003

1 Topology Definition of a topology Basis (Base) of a topology The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3

Econ 101A Problem Set 1 Solution

CONSUMER DEMAND. Consumer Demand

CHAPTER 7. Connectedness

HW 4 SOLUTIONS. , x + x x 1 ) 2

Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets The Real Numbers The Cantor Set

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018

Mathematical Economics. Lecture Notes (in extracts)

Economics 204. The Transversality Theorem is a particularly convenient formulation of Sard s Theorem for our purposes: with r 1+max{0,n m}

Microeconomic Analysis

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Lecture 1: Entropy, convexity, and matrix scaling CSE 599S: Entropy optimality, Winter 2016 Instructor: James R. Lee Last updated: January 24, 2016

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem

Convex Optimization Theory. Chapter 5 Exercises and Solutions: Extended Version

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics

Math 31 Lesson Plan. Day 2: Sets; Binary Operations. Elizabeth Gillaspy. September 23, 2011

Examples of metric spaces. Uniform Convergence

Proofs. Chapter 2 P P Q Q

Math 535: Topology Homework 1. Mueen Nawaz

Homework 1 Solutions

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Midterm Exam

Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 29 September 2004.

Mathematical Appendix

0 Sets and Induction. Sets

Transcription:

4.02 Problem Set 3 Due Thursday, October 2, 2004, in class Starred (*) problems will not count for the grade on this problem set; they are based on material from lectures on 0/2 and 0/26, and provide practice for the midterm on 0/28. If you would like to do them prior to 0/2 and hand them, I will be happy to make comments. Solutions to all problems will be posted after class on 0/2.. Lecture Notes Exercise 68: For a function f defined on a convex subset U in R n,showthatf concave implies f quasiconcave. Solution: Such an f satisfies f(λx +( λ)y) λf(x) +( λ)f(y) for any x, y U and 0 <λ<. We will show that this means that f(x) f(y) implies f(λx +( λ)y) f(y), again for any x, y U and 0 <λ<. So suppose that we have chosen x and y such that f(x) f(y). Then we have f(λx +( λ)y) λf(x)+( λ)f(y) λf(y)+( λ)f(y) =f(y) 2. (Sundaram 5., page 44) Consider the problem of maximizing the utility function u(x, y) =x 2 + y 2 on the budget set px + y =,x 0,y 0. Show that if non-negativity constrains are ignored, and the problem is written as an equality-constrained one, the resulting Lagrangean has a unique critical point. Does this critical point identify a solution to the problem? Why or why not? Solution: We have L(x, y, λ) = x+ y λ(px+y ). The only critical point is given by 2 = pλ and x 2 y = λ, soy = p2 x. Plugging that to the budget constraint gives x = p+p, y = p 2 +p. This unique critical point is indeed the solution to our problem: generally, if we ignore some constraints and find a solution to the problem with relaxed constraints, and it so happens that those relaxed constraints are satisfied at the solution we find, then this is also a solution to the problem with relaxed constraints. Make sure you understand this logic. 3. (Sundaram 6.2, page 7) A firm produces a single output y using three inputs x,x 2,x 3 in nonnegative quantities through the relationship y = x (x 2 + x 3 ).The unit price of y is p y > 0 while that of the input x i is w i > 0,i=, 2, 3. (a) Describe the firm s profit-maximization problem and derive the equations that define the critical points of the Lagrangean L in this problem. Solution: The firm want to maximize p y y w x w 2 x 2 w 3 x 3 subject to y = x (x 2 + x 3 ) and x,x 2,x 3 0. We may immediately plug the first constraint to the objective to make life easier.

The Lagrangian is L(x,x 2,x 3,λ,λ 2,λ 3 )=p y x (x 2 + x 3 ) w x w 2 x 2 w 3 x 3 + λ x + λ 2 x 2 + λ 3 x 3. Critical points are then given by: p y (x 2 + x 3 ) = w λ p y x = w 2 λ 2 p y x = w 3 λ 3 λ x = 0 λ 2 x 2 = 0 λ 3 x 3 = 0 (b) Show that the Lagrangean L has multiple critical points for any choice of (p y,w,w 2,w 3 ) R 4 ++. Solution: x = x 2 = x 3 =0,λ i = w i,i=, 2, 3 is always a critical point. So is λ = λ 2 =06= λ 3 for w 3 >w 2 and λ = λ 3 =06= λ 2 for w 2 >w 3. For w 2 = w 3 any x 2 and x 3 such that x 2 + x 3 = w p y is acriticalpoint. (c) Show that none of these critical points identifies a solution of the profit-maximization problem. Can you explain why this is the case? Solution: This is the case simply because there is no solution to the profit-maximization problem at all. That is, the profits can be potentially made infinite. To see this, consider moving along the line x = x 2 = a, x 3 =0. Profits then are p y a 2 (w +w 2 )a, which grows to infinity as a. 4. (Sundaram 8.25, page 20) An agent who consumes three commodities has a utility function given by u(x,x 2,x 3 )= 3 x +min{x 2,x 3 }. Given an income of I and prices p,p 2,p 3, write down the consumer s utilitymaximization problem (you need not solve it ). Can the Weierstraß and/or Kuhn-Tucker theorems be used to obtain and characterize a solution (that is, are they applicable to this problem)? Why or why not? Solution: The problem is to maximize u(x,x 2,x 3 )= 3 x +min{x 2,x 3 } subject to p x + p 2 x 2 + p 3 x 3 I. The Weierstraß theorem is applicable, as long as prices are strictly positive, but Kuhn-Tucker theorem is not applicable, since u is not a C function (it is not differentiable at points where x 2 = x 3 ). The way to solve it will be to notice that it is never optimal to have x 2 6= x 3 (if, say, x 2 <x 3, then cutting down on x 3 and buying some more of x 2 will improve utility). Therefore, we may denote by x the composite good composed of equal quantities of x 2 and x 3, which is going at price p = p 2 + p 3. The problem then becomes to maximize u(x,x)= 3 x + x subject to p x + px I; now Kuhn-Tucker theorem is applicable. 5. Lecture Notes Exercise 205: Compute R + te rt dt (use integration by a parts). IfyouevertakeaclassfromBengt,oranexamhewrites,youwillbecomeveryused to problems that require you only to set up the program (but which can still be surprisingly difficult!). 2

Solution: r e rt ] + 2 a R + te rt dt = [ t a r e rt ] + a + R + a = ra r 2 e ra r e rt dt = [ t r e rt 6. Lecture Notes Exercise 206: Compute R + e t dt (use the change of 0 variable u = t). Solution: u = t,sodt =2udu. The limits of integration don t change, so we have R + e t dt = R + 2ue u du =2{[ ue u ] + 0 0 0 + R + e u du} =2[ e u (u+ 0 )] + 0 =2 7. Lecture Notes Exercise 2: For each of the following relations, show that R is (or is not) reflexive, symmetric, and transitive. In each, x, y R n. (a) xry if x >y,wherex and y are the respective first elements of x and y. Solution: x >x cannot hold, so R is not reflexive. Moreover, only one of {x >y,x <y,x = y } can hold, so R is not symmetric. But if x >y, and y >z for a third vector z, thenx >z ; R is transitive. (b) xry if x = y Solution: x = x must hold; x = y = y = x ;andifx = y and y = z, then x = z ; thus, R is reflexive, symmetric, and transitive (it is an equivalence relation - note the implication that an equivalence relation need not be equality). (c) xry if kxk = kyk Solution: We have exactly the same arguments as in part (b) leading to the conclusion that R is an equivalence relation (reflexive, symmetric, and transitive). Note that k k is a function from R n to R. We cannot put an order on n-tuples (vectors); it may not always be possible to say x>y, x<y,orx = y for any pair x, y R n. But a function mapping vectors onto the real line can help us to do this, because we can order the real numbers. This is one aspect of the utility function - it takes bundles of goods which are not inherently comparable and maps them onto the real line, allowing us to rank them according to a preference relation. Can you tell if u(x) =kxk could be a utility function? 8. Let A be a nonempty set of real numbers which is bounded below. Let A be the set of all real numbers x, wherex A. Prove that inf A = sup( A) Solution: FirstwenotethatbecauseA is bounded below, inf A exists in R. Call it α. Now, by definition, α is a lower bound for A, but if there exists a γ>α, γ is not a lower bound for A. Now consider α. 3

Because α x for all x A, weknowthat α x for all x A. Thus, α is an upper bound for A (Note: if A is bounded below, then we know that A is bounded above, and hence that sup( A) exists in R). Now consider β< α. If β is an upper bound for A, thenβ y for all y A. But this would imply, first, that y A, and, second, that y β>α, i.e. that there exists a real number greater than α which is a lower bound for A. But we began by pointing out that this is not the case, since α =inf(a). Thus, any such β is not an upper bound for A, which means that α =sup( A), which in turn implies that α =infa = sup( A). 9. (*) Prove carefully that the sum of two convergent sequences is convergent and its limit is the sum of the limits. Solution: Let {a n } a and {b n } b. We want to show that {a n +b n } a + b. By definition of convergence, this means that ε >0 N : n >N a n + b n (a + b) < ε. Indeed, for a given ε > 0 consider ε = ε 2. By definition of convergence, there must exist N a such that n >N a a n a <ε ; likewise, there must exist N b such that n >N b b n b <ε. Set N =max{n a,n b }. Now for any n>n we have a n + b n (a + b) = a n a + b n b a n a + b n b <ε + ε = ε. This completes the proof. 0. (*) Find all limit points of the following sequence:,, 2,, 2, 3,, 2, 3, 4,... Solution: All positive integers are limit points of this sequence.. (*) Show that the intersection of (even infinitely many) closed sets is closed. Give an example of an infinite family of closed sets whose union is not closed. Solution: By definition, a set is closed if its complement is open. We have to prove that the complement of an intersection of closed sets is open, which is the same as the union of complements of each of them (why?), which are all open by definition. Therefore, we have to prove that the union of (any number of) open sets is open. The latter statement is straightforward: if a point belongs to the union, it belongs to one of the sets which, being open, contains a small enough open ball centered in our point and this ball must, therefore, be contained in the union, proving that the union is open. Make sure you understand the logic of the above solution and can, if needed, reproduce it. If A n = { n }, then each A n is closed (it is a singleton), but their union is not (limit point 0 is missing). 2. (*) Let A =[ ; 0) and B =(0, ]. Examine whether each of the following statements is true or false: 4

(a) A B is compact; Solution: False. Point 0 is missing making the set not closed. (b) A + B = {x + y x A, y B} is compact; Solution: False. A + B =( ; ) which is not closed. (c) A B is compact. Solution: True. A B = which is closed and bounded. 3. (*) Define ½ if 0 x f(x) = 0 otherwise. Find an open set O such that f (O) is not open and a closed set C such that f (C) is not closed. Examples: O =( 2, 3 2 ) and C = {0} 4. (*) (Harder) Start from any set A R n. Consider the following two operations: taking closure of a set and taking convex hull of a set. At most how many distinct sets can one obtain by consecutively applying these operations to A (in any order)? Try to show that the number you get is indeed the maximum. Solution: Convince yourself that the closure of a convex set is convex (I will try to explain it in class). Now if you start from any set A, youcango to cl(a) then to con(cla) then to cl(con(cla) at which point you end up withaclosedconvexset,soyoucangonofurther. Thereforemaximum number of distinct sets that you get can not go above four. This bound can indeed be achieved: if A = {(x, y) R 2 x Q,x 6= 0,y = x }. Make sure you can see what A, cl(a), con(cl(a)) and cl(con(cl(a))) are and that they are indeed all distinct. 5