Optimal Growth Models and the Lagrange Multiplier

Similar documents
Equilibrium in the growth model with an endogenous labor-leisure choice

Social Welfare Functions for Sustainable Development

On the Principle of Optimality for Nonstationary Deterministic Dynamic Programming

General existence of competitive equilibrium in the growth model with an endogenous labor-leisure choice and unbounded capital stock

Exhaustible Resources and Economic Growth

A Simple Proof of the Necessity. of the Transversality Condition

On optimal growth models when the discount factor is near 1 or equal to 1

Existence, Optimality and Dynamics of Equilibria with Endogenous Time Preference. Cuong Le Van* Cagri Saglam** Selman Erol**

On the existence, efficiency and bubbles of a Ramsey equilibrium with endogenous labor supply and borrowing constraints

Dynamic Optimization with a Nonsmooth, Nonconvex Technology: The Case of a Linear Objective Function

Non-convex Aggregate Technology and Optimal Economic Growth

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

Dynamic Programming Theorems

The Existence of Equilibrium in. Infinite-Dimensional Spaces: Some Examples. John H. Boyd III

Some Properties of the Augmented Lagrangian in Cone Constrained Optimization

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Financial asset bubble with heterogeneous agents and endogenous borrowing constraints

Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model

Sequences. Limits of Sequences. Definition. A real-valued sequence s is any function s : N R.

The Necessity of the Transversality Condition at Infinity: A (Very) Special Case

Dynamic Optimization Using Lagrange Multipliers

Fixed Term Employment Contracts. in an Equilibrium Search Model

Necessity of Transversality Conditions. for Stochastic Problems

Geometry and topology of continuous best and near best approximations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

On constraint qualifications with generalized convexity and optimality conditions

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

SOME STABILITY RESULTS FOR THE SEMI-AFFINE VARIATIONAL INEQUALITY PROBLEM. 1. Introduction

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies

A nonsmooth, nonconvex model of optimal growth

Deterministic Dynamic Programming in Discrete Time: A Monotone Convergence Principle

Basic Deterministic Dynamic Programming

Multiple Interior Steady States in the Ramsey Model with Elastic Labor Supply

1 The Basic RBC Model

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Regularity of competitive equilibria in a production economy with externalities

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies

The Survival Assumption in Intertemporal Economy J.M. Bonnisseau and A. Jamin 1 November Abstract

A CORRESPONDENCE-THEORETIC APPROACH TO DYNAMIC OPTIMIZATION

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

1 General Equilibrium

Dynamic optimization with a nonsmooth, nonconvex technology: the case of a linear objective function

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

Advanced Macroeconomics

Introduction to Recursive Methods

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

4 Lecture Applications

Subdifferential representation of convex functions: refinements and applications

ON THE SUSTAINABLE PROGRAM IN SOLOW S MODEL. 1. Introduction

Optimal Control. Macroeconomics II SMU. Ömer Özak (SMU) Economic Growth Macroeconomics II 1 / 112

Macroeconomics I. University of Tokyo. Lecture 12. The Neo-Classical Growth Model: Prelude to LS Chapter 11.

Notes on Alvarez and Jermann, "Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 2000

No Equilibrium in Infinite Economies: Two Examples*

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS 2015 FINAL EXAMINATION FOR THE FIRST HALF OF SPRING SEMESTER

2 JOHN STACHURSKI collection of all distributions on the state space into itself with the property that the image of the current distribution ' t is t

Existence and Approximation of Fixed Points of. Bregman Nonexpansive Operators. Banach Spaces

Endogenous Growth Theory

Berge s Maximum Theorem

WORKING PAPER NO. 443

arxiv: v2 [math.pr] 12 May 2013

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists

Neoclassical Growth Model / Cake Eating Problem

Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Supergradients. KC Border Fall 2001 v ::15.45

Almost sure convergence to zero in stochastic growth models

Equilibrium Analysis of Dynamic Economies

Structural and Multidisciplinary Optimization. P. Duysinx and P. Tossings

Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation

Appendix B Convex analysis

Vector Variational Principles; ε-efficiency and Scalar Stationarity

Optimization, Part 2 (november to december): mandatory for QEM-IMAEF, and for MMEF or MAEF who have chosen it as an optional course.

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

Contents. An example 5. Mathematical Preliminaries 13. Dynamic programming under certainty 29. Numerical methods 41. Some applications 57

On the (Non-)Differentiability of the Optimal Value Function When the Optimal Solution Is Unique

Summary Notes on Maximization

THE NEARLY ADDITIVE MAPS

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Optimal control in infinite horizon problems : a Sobolev space approach

Viscosity Iterative Approximating the Common Fixed Points of Non-expansive Semigroups in Banach Spaces

Advanced Macroeconomics

Long Horizon versus Short Horizon Planning in Dynamic Optimization Problems with Incomplete Information

The existence of equilibrium in a simple exchange model

Mathematical Economics. Lecture Notes (in extracts)

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

A Characterization of Polyhedral Convex Sets

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018

A convergence result for an Outer Approximation Scheme

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

The Relation Between Pseudonormality and Quasiregularity in Constrained Optimization 1

Transcription:

CORE DISCUSSION PAPER 2003/83 Optimal Growth Models and the Lagrange Multiplier Cuong Le Van, H. Cagri Saglam November 2003 Abstract We provide sufficient conditions on the objective functional and the constraint functions under which the Lagrangean can be represented by a `1 sequence of multipliers in infinite horizon discrete time optimal growth models. Keywords: Optimal Growth, Lagrange Multipliers. JEL Classification: C61, O41. The authors thank the referee for criticisms, remarks and suggestions. They also thank Yiannis Vailakis for helpful comments. This text presents research results of the Belgian Program on Interuniversity Poles of Attraction initiated by the Belgian State, Prime Minister s Office, Science Policy Programming. The scientific responsibility is assumed by the authors. CNRS, CERMSEM, Université de Paris 1, CORE. E-mail: cuong.le-van@univ-paris1.fr IRES, Université catholique de Louvain. E-mail: saglam@ires.ucl.ac.be

1 Introduction The classical optimal growth models have played a central role in the theory of economic dynamics. The model is described by the presence of a planner maximizing the sum of discounted utilities of consumption subject to a convex one-sector production set. This simple and elegant model proves to be useful in explaining many aspects of capital accumulation. 1 The study of this type of optimal capital accumulation problems can be considerably enhanced by means of Lagrange multipliers techniques. 2 Lagrange multipliers have been widely used in solving finite dimensional constrained optimization problems as they also facilitate the analysis on the properties of the solution [see Rockafellar (1976)]. However, in infinite horizon optimal growth models, these multipliers will typically belong to an infinite dimensional decision space. Therefore, the questions whether the Lagrange multipliers exist and whether they can be represented by a summable sequence arise. 3 In this paper we extend the Lagrangean to infinite dimensional spaces and provide sufficient conditions for Lagrangean to be represented by a summable sequence of multipliers in infinite discrete time horizon optimal growth models. We take the approach of placing restrictions directly on the asymptotic behaviors of the objective functional and the constraint functions. In this sense, our work is closely related to Dechert (1982). Considering the set of problems in the form of: inf {F (x) φ (x) 0}, where F : ` R and φ : ` ` are convex functions and x `, Dechert (1982) extends the Lagrangean to infinite dimensional spaces. However, a limitation to the direct use of his results in infinite horizon optimal growth models stems from the fact that he assumes that the objective functional and the constraint functions are real valued on `. That avoids the analysis of the cases where the usual Inada type conditions are assumed for the utility (in this case there is no extension of utility value to R) and the production functions. The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we first present the problem in general form and give the extension of the Kuhn-Tucker theorem where the multipliers are represented in (` ) p, the dual space of `. Second, we present the sufficient conditions for having an `1 representation of the multipliers and state our main result. Finally, section 3 is devoted to the applications to a one-sector optimal growth model and an incentive-constrained optimal growth model. 1 See Aliprantis, Border and Burkinshaw (1990, 1997) for some recent studies and Stokey et al. (1989) for more details. 2 Dynamic programming is another technique used in analyzing such models; see for instance Alvarez and Stokey (1998), Le Van and Morhaim (2002). See also Weitzman (1973) for the close connection between duality theory for infinite horizon convex models and dynamic programming. 3 The existence of separating vectors and whether they can be represented by a sequence of real numbers in infinite dimensional spaces have been widely studied; see for instance Bewley (1972), Majumdar (1972), Colonius (1983), Rustichini (1998) and McKenzie (1986). 1

2 Model Consider the following intertemporal optimization problem (P ): min F (x) s.t. φ (x) 0 x ` where F : ` R {+ } and (φ t ) t =0,..., : ` R {+ } are convex functions. Let φ (x) denote for (φ t (x)) t =0,...,. We define C = dom (F ) = {x ` F (x) < + }, Γ = dom (φ) = {x ` φ t (x) < +, t} and assume that C 6=. By means of an application of the separation theorem on Banach spaces, we give the following extension of the Kuhn-Tucker theorem in which the multipliers are represented in (` ) p : Theorem 1 Let x be a solution of (P ). Assume that x Γ we have φ (x) `. Suppose x 0 ` such that Then Λ (` ) p such that x 0 C, sup φ t x 0 < 0 (Slater condition). t (i) Λ 0, (ii) Λ φ (x )=0, (iii) F (x)+λ φ (x) F (x ), x (Γ C). Conversely, if x (Γ C), Λ (` ) p such that (i) (iii) hold, then x is asolution. Proof. Define the set Z as: Z = { (ρ,z) R ` : x `, ρ >F(x) F (x ),z t > φ t (x), t 0 }. Z is non-empty (e.g. take ρ = F (x 0 ) F (x )+ε and z t =0, t 0, where ε > 0 and x 0 satisfies the Slater condition). It is obvious that Z is convex and it satisfies Z R ` =. Since int ` 6=, we can apply the separation theorem: (c, Λ) R (` ) p \{0} such that: (ρ, z) Z, ³ρ 0 0, z R In particular, this relation implies that: 0 ` : cρ + Λz 0 cρ + Λz. (1) cρ + Λz 0, (ρ,z) Z. (2) 2

Note that (ρ,z) Z if ρ > 0 and z t > 0, t (take x = x in the definition of Z). We firstwanttoprovethatc 0. On the contrary, if c<0 then keeping z fixed and letting ρ + in (2), we obtain a contradiction. Hence c 0. Now we claim that Λ (` ) p +, i.e. Λz 0, z ` +. For that, take z ` +. Let θ = (1, 1, 1,...1,...) and ρ = 1. Then, (ρ, θ + µz) Z for any µ > 0. From relation (2), we notice that cρ + Λ (θ + µz) 0, µ >0 or equivalently µ 1 (cρ + Λθ) +Λz 0, µ >0. Letting µ +, we obtain that Λz 0, z ` +. Hence, Λ (` ) p +. We now prove that c>0. Assume on the contrary that c =0. In this case, we know that Λ 6= 0. Note that the closure of Z is: _ Z = { (z 0,z) R ` : x `, z 0 F (x) F (x ),z t φ t (x), t }. Observethatwestillhave, cρ + Λz 0, (ρ,z) _ Z. (3) As F x 0 F (x ), φ x 0 _ Z, from (3), we obtain a contradiction: 0 > Λφ x 0 0, due to the fact that sup φ t x 0 < 0. t Let Λ = c 1 Λ in order to obtain the claim (i) of the theorem. Now, we prove the claim (ii) of the theorem. Since Λ 0, (0, φ (x )) Z _ and φ (x ) `, we have on the one hand Λ φ (x ) 0 and Λ φ (x ) 0 on the other. Hence, Λ φ (x )=0. Finally, take z 0 = F (x) F (x ) and z = φ (x), x (Γ C). Then, from inequality (3), we obtain that: F (x) F (x )+Λ φ (x) 0 F (x)+λ φ (x) F (x )+Λ φ (x ), x (Γ C). As for the converse, let x ` satisfy φ (x) 0. Then, x Γ. If x/ C then F (x) =+ and of course we have F (x) F (x ). Now assume that x C. Relations (i), (ii) and (iii) imply that F (x) F (x)+λ φ (x) F (x )+Λ φ (x )=F (x ). Thus, we have proved that x is an optimal solution. Corollary 1 Let the assumptions of Theorem 1 be satisfied. If x (solution to the optimization problem P )satisfies that x int (Γ C), then we have x `, F (x)+λ φ (x) F (x )+Λ φ (x ) where Λ (` ) p + and Λ φ (x )=0. 3

Proof. We know that Λ (` ) p + such that: x (Γ C),F(x)+Λ φ (x) F (x )+Λ φ (x ) and Λ φ (x )=0. Now assume that x `. As x int (Γ C), we have (µx +(1 µ) x) int (Γ C) where µ [0, 1] and µ approaches to 1. Then, we can write that : F (µx +(1 µ) x)+λ φ (µx +(1 µ) x) F (x )+Λ φ (x ). As F and φ are convex and Λ 0, we obtain that: µf (x )+(1 µ) F (x)+µλ φ (x )+(1 µ) Λ φ (x) F (x )+Λ φ (x ) F (x)+λ φ (x) F (x )+Λ φ (x ), x `. 2.1 An `1representation of the multipliers In this section we provide an `1 representation of the multipliers. As F and φ are convex and a Slater condition on φ is satisfied, by means of a standard separation argument on Banach spaces we have shown the existence of a Λ (` ) p +. However, we know that `1 p = ` but (` ) p 6= `1. Denoting the set of bounded linear functionals generated by the purely finitely additive measures on integers with `s [see Rudin (1973) for a broad analysis of those functionals], we can identify the dual space of ` with a direct sum of two subspaces: (` ) p = `1 `s. Then, for each Λ (` ) p +, we adopt the notation Λ = Λ 1 + Λ s where Λ 1 `1 and Λ s `s. Our aim is to avoid the `s part of Λ (` ) p + so that each constraint φ t (x) will have a multiplier λ t associated with it. To that end, we will take the approach of presenting sufficient conditions so that Λ s =0. Definition 1 Let x `, y ` and T N. Asequencex T (x, y) is defined by: x T (x, y) ={ x t, t T, y t, t > T. We make the following assumptions which will prove to be useful in our analysis: Assumption 1 If x C, y ` satisfy T T 0,x T (x, y) C then F x T (x, y) F (x) when T. Assumption 2 If x Γ, y Γ and x T (x, y) Γ, T T 0 then (a) φ t x T (x, y) φ t (x), as T, (b) M s.t. T T 0, φ x T (x, y) M, (c) N T 0, lim φt x N (x, y) φ t (y) =0. t 4

We also adopt the following conventions [see Rockafellar (1976)] in our analysis: 0(+ ) = (+ ) 0=0, α (+ ) = (+ ) α =+ if α > 0. We have the following remark on the assumptions we have made: Remark 1 Assumption 1 is satisfied if F is continuous in C =dom(f ) for the product topology. Assumption 2-(a) is the asymptotically non-anticipatory assumption (ANA) and Assumption 2-(c) is true if the asymptotically insensitivity (AI) assumption holds [see Dechert (1982)] for φ in Γ = dom (φ). Obviously, Assumption 2-(b) is satisfied when Γ = dom (φ) =` and φ is continuous. More precisely, the restrictions on φ that we use lead to the following two lemmas : Lemma 1 Under Assumption 2-(c), we have: Λ s φ x N (x, y) = Λ s φ (y), for any N T 0. Proof. Follows directly from the property of `s. Indeed, for any Λ s `s and x ` with lim x (t) =0, Λ s x =0. Given N, as lim φt x N (x, y) φ t (y) = t t 0, we have Λ s φ x N (x, y) φ (y) =0, completing the proof. Lemma 2 Let Assumptions (2-a) and (2-b) be satisfied. Then, Λ 1 `1, lim T Λ1 φ x T (x, y) = Λ 1 φ (x). Proof. We have for T T 0, Λ1 φ x T (x, y) Λ 1 φ (x) NX λ t φ t x T (x, y) φ t (x) + φ x T (x, y) φ (x) By Assumption (2-b), we know that M such that: Now, ε > 0, N 0 such that: T, φ x T (x, y) φ (x) M 0 = M + kφ (x)k. t=n 0 +1 λ t < ³ 2M 0 1 ε, and T t T 0, T >T t, λ t φ t x T (x, y) φ t (x) < (2N 0 ) 1 ε. X t=n+1 λ t. 5

Hence, T > max {T t }, 1 t N 0 Λ1 φ x T (x, y) Λ 1 φ (x) <N0 (2N 0 ) 1 ε + M 0 ³ 2M 0 1 ε = ε, completes the proof. With this structure in mind we can proceed with our main result: Theorem 2 Let Assumptions 1-2 and the assumptions of Theorem 1 be satisfied. Let dom (φ t )=dom (φ), t. Let x be a solution and x 0 satisfy the Slater condition. If x T x,x 0 belongs to (Γ C), T T 0,then there exists Λ `1+ such that: x `, F (x)+λφ(x) F (x )+Λφ(x ) and Λφ (x )=0. Proof. By means of Theorem 1, we know that Λ (` ) 0, Λ 0 such that x (Γ C),F(x)+Λ φ (x) F (x )+Λ φ (x ) and Λ φ (x )=0. Write Λ = Λ 1 +Λ s where Λ 1 `1+ and Λ s `s. As Λ 0, we have Λ 1 φ (x )=0 and Λ s φ (x )=0. For a given N T 0,x N x,x 0 (Γ C). Hence, F x N x,x 0 + Λ 1 φ x N x,x 0 + Λ s φ x N x,x 0 F (x ). Note that Λ 1 φ x N x,x 0 Λ 1 φ (x ) when N by Lemma 2 and Λ s φ x N x,x 0 = Λ s φ x 0 by Lemma 1. By Assumption 1, we know that F x N x,x 0 F (x ) when N. If Λ s 6=0, by taking the limits in the previous inequality we obtain F (x ) > F (x )+ Λ s φ x 0 F (x ) : a contradiction. Hence, Λ s =0and Λ = Λ 1 `1+. Wehaveprovedthat: F (x)+λφ (x) F (x ), x (Γ C), Λ `1+ where Λφ (x) can be written as: Λφ (x) = Let I = t λ 1 t > 0 ª. We have λ 1 t φ t (x), λ 1 t 0, t. F (x)+ X t I λ 1 t φ t (x) F (x ). If I =, then F (x) F (x ), x C. In this case, if x/ C, then F (x) =+ and the inequality still holds. Finally, what happens if I 6=? If x/ Γ then 6

P λ 1 t φ t (x) =+. Since F (x) R {+ }, we have F (x)+ P λ 1 t φ t (x) =+ t I t I so that the inequality F (x)+λφ (x) F (x ) holds. On the other hand, if x Γ and x/ C we have also F (x)+ P λ 1 t φ t (x) =+ and F (x)+λφ(x) F (x ). t I Thus, x `, F(x)+Λφ (x) F (x ). 3 Applications Example 1 One-sector optimal growth model Production possibilities are represented by a production function f and preferences are described by a one period reward function u and a discount factor β. At period t, a single commodity is used as capital to produce output and the output is either consumed or saved as capital until the next period. This process repeats ad infinitum. The problem is formalized as follows: subject to max β t u (c t ) c t + k t+1 f (k t ) 0, t c t 0, t 0 k t 0, t 1 k 0 > 0, given. Definition 2 For any initial condition k 0 > 0, when k =(k 1,k 2,...k t,...) is such that 0 k t+1 f (k t ) for all t, we say it is feasible from k 0 and the class of feasible accumulation path is denoted by Q (k 0 ). Definition 3 A consumption sequence c =(c 0,c 1,c 2,...c t,...) is feasible from k 0 > 0 if there exists a sequence k Q (k 0 ) that satisfies 0 c t f (k t ) k t+1, for all t; and the class of feasible consumption sequences from k 0 is denoted by P (k0 ). In section 2, actually ` denotes the space of uniformly bounded sequences of R n,n 1. Now, we will denote by ` the space of sequences {(c t,k t )} with sup c t < + and sup k t < +. We make the following assumptions: t t Assumption 3 The one period reward function u is concave in R + and strictly increasing. Further, β (0, 1) and u 0 (0) +. Assumption 4 The gross production function f is concave, differentiable in R + and strictly increasing. Further, f (0) = 0, 1 <f 0 (0) + and f 0 ( ) < 1. Assumption 5 In order to extend u and f on R, we have u (c) = if c<0 and f (x) = if x<0. 7

The assumption of f 0 ( ) < 1 implies the existence of a maximum sustainable capital stock k for which f (k) <kiff k> k and f k = k. Further, ³ _ _ if f 0 (0) > 1, then for all k 0 > 0, there must be some 0 <k 0 k 0 such that f ³k 0 >k 0. Then, for all k 0 > 0, there is a feasible interior consumptionaccumulation plan described by k 0 > 0 and c 0 = f ³k 0 k 0. Note that this problem can be written as min F (x) s.t. φ (x) 0 x ` ` P where x =(c, k),f(x) = β t u (c t ) and F : ` ` R {+ }. We denote φ t = (φ 1 t, φ 2 t, φ 3 t ) where φ 1 t (x) = c t + k t+1 f (k t ), φ 2 t (x) = c t, t 0, and φ 3 t+1 (x) = k t+1, t 0. Accordingly, C = dom (F )=` + `, Γ = dom (φ) =` ` + = dom (φ t ), t and C Γ = ` + ` +. Now we will show that Theorem 2 is satisfied for this optimal growth problem under Assumptions 3 to 5: 1. Since f 0 (0) > 1. for any k 0 > 0, there exists k 0 such that 0 <k 0 + ε < f (k 0 ) and 0 <k 0 + ε <f ³k 0 ³ with ε > 0. Let k 0 = k 0,k 0,k 0,..., c 0 =(ε, ε, ε,...) and x 0 = c 0, k 0. Note that sup φ t c 0 < 0. Thus, t Slater condition is verified. ³ 2. Consider any x C, x, x ` ` such that T, x T x C. We know that: F ³x ³ T TX ³ c ³ c x, x = β t u β t u. t=t +1 As x ` `, sup c t < +. In other words, a >0, t, c t a. t Note that, β t u (a) =u (a) β t 0 when T,asβ (0, 1). t=t +1 t=t +1 Then, we have F ³x ³ ³ T x x, x F when T so that Assumption 1 is satisfied. 8

3. Let x =(c, k),k t 0, t and y =(c 0, k 0 ),k 0 t 0, t. We have: φ 1 t x T (x, y) = { c t + k t+1 f (k t ) < +, if t<t c 0 t + kt+1 0 f (kt) 0 < +, if t>t and φ 1 T x T (x, y) = c T + k p T +1 f (k T ) < +. Then, x T (x, y) Γ, T. It is evident that if T>t+1, we have: x T (x, y) = φ 1 t (x). φ 1 t It is clear that the same is also true for φ 2 t x T (x, y) and φ 3 t x T (x, y), as well. Thus, Assumption 2-(a) is satisfied. 4. For any x Γ, y Γ, let M 1 = kφ (x)k =sup φ t (x) t 0 and M 2 = kφ (y)k =sup φ t (y). t 0 Knowing that x T (x, y) ={ x t,t T y t,t>t and simply setting µ M =max{m 1,M 2 } lead us to conclude that M such that, T, φ x µx T,y M. ThisprovesthatAssumption 2-(b) is satisfied. 5. We know that N, φ t x T (x, y) = { φ t (x),t N φ t (y), t > N Let t = N +1. Then we have φ t x T (x, y) = φ t (y), when t> t>n. Thus, Assumption 2-(c) is satisfied. 6. It is obvious that x T x, x 0 belongs to ` + ` +, T. Summimg up, we have shown that the assumptions of Theorem 2 are fulfilled for our optimal growth problem. Hence there exists Λ `1+ such that x `, if x is optimal, then F (x)+λφ (x) F (x )+Λφ (x ) and Λφ (x )=0. These establish the following proposition. 9

Proposition 1 If x =(c, k ) is optimal then there exists λ `1+ such that x =(c, k) ` `, and β t u (c t ) λ 1 t c t + kt+1 f (kt ) + λ 2 t c t + λ 3 t kt β t u (c t ) λ 1 t (c t + k t+1 f (k t )) + λ 2 t c t + λ 3 t k t (4) λ 1 t c t + k t+1 f (k t ) =0, t (5) λ 2 t c t =0, t (6) λ 3 t kt =0, t. (7) As by-products of this proposition, we obtain that the sequence β t u 0 (c t ) ª is in `1 and Euler equation holds for this optimal growth problem. Clearly, the property β t u 0 (c t ) ª is in `1 can be obtained in different ways even without resorting to our approach. In order to obtain that prices belong to `1, Le Van and Dana (2003), for instance, use Euler equation and the monotonicity of the optimal paths. In fact, the monotonicity property of optimal paths in the one sector growth models goes back to Dechert and Nishimura (1983) among others. Ekeland and Scheinkman (1986) obtain that β t u 0 (c t ) ª is in `1 under more general settings by considering non-concave infinite horizon problems with unbounded returns. Their analysis does not involve Euler equation and the monotonicity of the optimal paths. Instead, their analysis relies mainly on Fatou s lemma together with some technical assumptions on the utility function (see Assumption P2(c t ), page 221). In our approach, both results are obtained independent of each other. In particular, the proof of the summability of the sequence β t u 0 (c t ) ª is immediate from our theorem. Corollary 2 Let Assumptions 3-5 be satisfied. Assume that u is strictly concave and continuously differentiable with u 0 (0) = +. Let x =(c, k ) be the optimal solution. Then we have: (i) The sequence β t u 0 (c t ) ª is in `1+\{0}. (ii) Euler equation: t, u 0 (c t )=βu 0 c t+1 f 0 kt+1 (8) Proof. It is clear that by means of Inada condition (u 0 (0) = + ), we have c t > 0, kt > 0, t. Thus, λ 2 t = λ 3 t =0, t, from equations (6) and (7). (i) Define c, k as follows: k t = kt, t, c t = c t, t 6= T, c T = c T + ε, ε R such that c T + ε > 0. 10

Inequality (4) implies that: β T u (c T ) λ 1 T c T β T u (c T + ε) λ 1 T (c T + ε), for any ε in a neighborhood of zero. This implies: β T u 0 (c T ) λ 1 T =0. Since, from Proposition 1, λ `1+, then ³β ) T u 0 (c T (ii) Define By (4), we have: `1+. c t = c t, t k t = kt, t 6= T +1 k T +1 = kt +1 + ε, ε R such that kt +1 + ε > 0. λ 1 T k T +1 + λ 1 T +1 f k T +1 λ 1 T k T +1 + ε + λ 1 T +1 f k T +1 + ε, for any ε in a neighborhood of zero. Therefore, λ 1 T + λ 1 T +1f 0 k T +1 =0. From (i), we know that λ 1 T = β T u 0 (c T ). Hence, Euler equation follows. Remark 2 In order to have an `1 representation of Lagrangean, Dechert (1982) introduces the hypothesis that: F (x ) `1, together with two constraint conditions: φ is asymptotically insensitive (AI) and non-anticipatory (ANA). Contrary to Dechert (1982), the hypothesis F (x ) `1 is not necessarily verified. Indeed, suppose that f 0 (0) < 1 β. Let u be differentiable in R + with u 0 (0) = +. If F (x ) `1, then we will have: F (x )= u 0 (c 0), βu 0 (c 1),..., β t u 0 (c t ),... ª. Hence, F is differentiable at x and thus, continuous at x (for the topology ` ). Hence, ε > 0, η, sup c t c t η β t u (c t ) β t u (c t t ) ε. We know that c t 0. Then, T, t T, 0 c t < η. So define c t = c t, t 6= T and c T = c T η < 0. (c 0,...c t,...) verifies sup c t c t = η and u (c t )= t. Thus, β T u (c T ) βt u (c T ) =+ and P β t u (c P t ) β t u (c t ) ε, does not hold. 11

Remark 3 The assumption that f 0 (0) > 1 is crucial to have multipliers in `1. Indeed,assume,onthecontrary,thatf 0 (0) 1. Assume that Inada condition holds. We then have the Euler equation: λ 1 T + λ 1 T +1f 0 k T +1 =0. Since f 0 is decreasing, we have f 0 k T +1 f 0 (0) 1. Hence λ 1 T +1 λ 1 T, T. In other words, λ 1 T λ 1 0 = u 0 (c 0) > 0, T. That proves that the multipliers λ 1 are not in `1. Example 2 The Recursive Utility and Optimal Growth In the previous example, one can use the support prices approach according to Weitzman (1973) and McKenzie (1986) tradition. But this approach is specific to separable utilities. We give below an example where their method fails. Actually, if we want to generalize their method to this example, we will not find support prices period by period, but the whole sequence of support prices. It turns out to prove that the optimal growth model has a summable sequence of multipliers. Regarding production technology we keep the same assumptions as in Example 1. We know that for all k 0, there exists A (k 0 ) > 0 such that k Π (k 0 ) implies k t A (k 0 ) for all t. Letπ denote the first coordinate projection function and S be the shift operator, i.e. πx =x 0 and S (x) =(x 1,...x t,...). Following Dana and Le Van (1990, 1991), we focus on utility functions that can be expressed as: U(c) =W (πc,u(sc)) (9) where W : R + R + R + is an aggregator function that satisfies the following properties: (W1) W is continuous and satisfies W (0, 0) = 0; (W2) W is concave and nondecreasing in both arguments; (W3) There exists δ (0, 1) such that W (c, z) W c, z p δ z z p, z, z p, c. Under assumption (W3), one can check that for any A 0, onecandefine the utility of the stationary sequence (A, A,..., A,...) denoted by W (A, W (A,..) as the limit of W (c 0,W(c 1,...W (c T, 0))...) with c t = A, for every t. We actually have W (A, W (A,..) (1 δ) 1 W (A, 0). Dana and Le Van (1991) established that, under (W1)-(W3), with every aggregator W is associated a unique utility function U, which satisfies (9) and meets other regularities conditions such as continuity and the concavity. As in Dana and Le Van (1990), we add: 12

(W4) W is C 1.Itsatifies Inada conditions: W (0,z) c = +, z 0, W (c, z) z < +, c >0, z 0. This optimal growth problem with recursive preferences can be written as follows: min F (x) s.t. φ (x) 0 x ` + ` + where x =(c, k), φ t (x) =c t + k t+1 f (k t ), t 0, k 0 > 0 is given and F ( x) = U (c) with F : ` + ` + R +. Proposition 2 The optimal growth problem with recursive preferences under (W1)-(W4) has a solution and multipliers in `1. Proof. The proof of the existence of a solution is standard and follows from the continuity of U and f. We will show that Theorem 2 applies : i) We know that for all k 0, there exists A (k 0 ) > 0 such that k Π (k 0 ) implies k t A (k 0 ) for all t. ThenU is well defined and bounded from above over Σ (k 0 ) as a consequence of A (k 0 ) also bounding feasible consumption. In other words, ³ c feasible, U W (A (k 0 ),W (A (k 0 )...)) <. c Consider now x = (c, k) C, x = (c 0, k 0 ) ` + ` + ³ such that T, x, x T x C. We have: F ³x T ³ x, x F ³ x = W c0,...w c T,W c 0 T +1,... W (c 0,...W (c T,W (c T +1,...))) W δ ³c T +1 0 T +1,W (...) W (c T,W (...)) 2δ T +1 W (A (k 0 ),W (A (k 0 )...)), which leads to: F ³x ³ ³ T x x, x F when T. Thus, Assumption 1 is satisfied. ii) Slater condition and Assumption 2 are easily verified from Example 1. Finally, it is obvious that x T x, x 0 belongs to ` + ` +. All the assumptions of Theorem 2 are satisfied. 13

From Inada condition, the optimal paths satisfy t, c t > 0,k t > 0. Proposition 2 implies that there exists λ `1+ such that x =(c, k) ` + ` +, W (c 0,..W (c t,...)) λ t c t + kt+1 f (kt ) W (c 0,..W (c t,...)) λ t (c t + k t+1 f (k t )), (10) and λ t c t + k t+1 f (k t ) =0, t. Corollary 3 Assume that W is strictly concave and continuously differentiable. Let x =(c, k ) be the optimal solution. Let U be the recursive utility defined by U(c) =W (πc,u(sc)).then we have: (i) The sequence U c t (c 0,.., c t,...) is in `1+\{0}. (ii) Euler equation: t, W c c t,z t+1 = W c c t+1,zt+2 W z (c t,zt+1)f 0 kt+1, (11) where t, z t = W (c t,w(c t+1,...))) = U(c t,c t+1,...). Proof. (i) Define c, k as follows: Inequality (10) implies that: k t = kt, t, c t = c t, t 6= T, c T = c T + ε, ε R such that c T + ε > 0. W (c 0,..W (c T,...)) λ T c T W (c 0,..W (c T + ε,...)) λ T (c T + ε), for any ε in a neighborhood of zero. Then, we have: U c T (c 0,.., c T,...) λ T =0. (ii) Define c t = c t, t k t = kt, t 6= T +1 k T +1 = kt +1 + ε, ε R such that kt +1 + ε > 0. By (10), we have: λ T kt +1 + λ T +1 f kt +1 λt k T +1 + ε + λ T +1 f kt +1 + ε, 14

for any ε in a neighborhood of zero. Therefore, λ 1 T + λ 1 T +1f 0 k T +1 =0. From (i), we know that λ T = U c T (c 0,.,c T,...). It is easy to check that U (c 0 c,.,c T,...) = W T z (c 0,z 1 )... W z (c t 1,z t ) W c (c t,z t+1 ), while U c c 0,.,c T +1,... = W T +1 z (c 0,z1)... W z (c t,zt+1) W c (c t+1,zt+2). Hence, Euler equation follows. Example 3 The Incentive-constrained optimal growth model [Rustichini (1998)] Consider the following problem (G): max β t V (x t,x t+1 ), 0 β < 1, s.t. (x t,x t+1 ) A R 2n, t, x 0,isgiven, where the government announces the optimal sequence of allocated capital goods (x t ). The government is assumed to have a full commitment power. This assumption is too strong as the government has the possibility to modify its previous plan together with the specification of the continuation value that the government will receive after any deviation from the previous plan. The value of the deviation defines a constraint on the plans chosen by the government: P at any date N, the value of the government s criterion, β t N V (x t,x t+1 ) should be greater than the value of the deviation, D(x N ). Then, the incentive constrained optimal growth problem can be written in the general form by adding these additional constraints to problem (G): t=n max s.t. β t V (x t,x t+1 ), 0 β < 1, β t N V (x t,x t+1 ) D(x N ), N =0, 1,..., t=n (x t,x t+1 ) A R 2n, t, x 0 π 1 (A), isgiven where π 1 denotes the projection on the first component. 15

We make the following assumptions: Assumption 5 The set A is convex, compact and non-empty. Assumption 6 The function V is concave, continuous on A. The function D is continuous and convex on π 1 (A). Assumption 7 If (x 1,x 2,..., x t,...) is optimal from x 0, then there exists x such that: (i) (x 0, x) A, (x, x) A, (ii) D(x 0 ) V (x 0, x) β (1 β) 1 V (x, x) < 0, D(x) (1 β) 1 V (x, x) < 0, (iii) T 0 such that (x T, x) A for every T T 0. We then obtain the following propositions: Proposition 3 Under Assumptions 5-7, the Incentive-constrained problem has asolution. Proof. First, observe that under Assumption 7-(ii), the feasible set is nonempty. It is then straightforward to prove that V is continuous for the product topology and the feasible set is compact for this topology. Hence, there exists a solution. Proposition 4 Under Assumptions 5-7, the Incentive-constrained problem has a solution and multipliers in `1. Proof. Obviously the sequence (x 0, x, x,..., x,...) satisfies the Slater condition by Assumption 7-(ii). Let us check whether the assumptions of Theorem 2 are satisfied: (i)itisobviousthatγ = C = {x ` :(x t,x t+1 ) A, t =0, 1,...}. (ii) Since A is compact and V, D are continuous, Assumption 2 (b) is satisfied. One can easily check that Assumption 1 is also satisfied. (iii) To check Assumption 2 (a), observe that for x, y Γ, for T>N,we have: φ N (x T (x, y)) φ N (x) 2M (1 β) 1 β T N P where i, φ i (x) =D(x i ) β t i V (x t,x t+1 ) and M =max{v (a, b) :(a, b) A}. t=i Thus, when T +, φ N (x T (x, y)) φ N (x). (iv) Since, given N, for t large enough, φ t (x N (x, y)) = φ(y), Assumption 2 (c) is satisfied. Finally, by assumption, the sequence x T (x, x) belongs to Γ = Γ C for every T T 0. All the assumptions of Theorem 2 are satisfied. 16

By Proposition 4, we obtain that the Lagrange multipliers are in `1. We will now show how this result can help us to characterize the steady states of the incentive constrained problem. Let (x 1,x 2,..., x t,...) is optimal from x 0. By Proposition (4), (x t,x t+1 ) A, we have: and β t V (x t,x t+1) # λ N "D(x N) β t N V (x t,x t+1) N=0 β t V (x t,x t+1 ) λ N "D(x N) N=0 t=n # λ N "D(x N ) β t N V (x t,x t+1 ) t=n # β t N V (x t,x t+1) =0, N. (12) t=n The first order conditions can be easily obtained as: υt + β t V 2 (x t,x t+1)+ υ t+1 + β t+1 V 1 (x t+1,x t+2) P λ t+1 D 0 (x t+1 )=0,, 1,... (13) where υ t = λ N β t N and V 1,V 2 denote the partial derivatives of V (x, y) N=0 with respect to x and y, respectively. Let us study the steady states (bx 0 ) where the incentive constraints are binding. One of the necessary conditions follows from (12) as: V (bx 0, bx 0 )=(1 β) D (bx 0 ). (14) which can have many solutions. Consider one dimensional case and assume that (bx 0, bx 0 ) int A. Writing (13) for t 1 and t at the steady state, and noting that υ t = βυ t 1 + λ t, one can prove that [see Rustichini (1998)]: λ t+1 = V 2 (bx 0, bx 0 )+βd 0 (bx 0 ) D 0 (bx 0 ) V 1 (bx 0, bx 0 ) λ t. By Proposition 4, we know that λ `1+. Then, in addition to (14) we also have: 0 < V 2 (bx 0, bx 0 )+βd 0 (bx 0 ) D 0 (bx 0 ) V 1 (bx 0, bx 0 ) < 1. (15) It should be noted that (14) and (15) are just necessary conditions for bx 0 to be a steady state of the incentive constrained problem. It is also worth mentioning that Rustichini (1998) used more assumptions (see Theorem 5.7, page 357) on the functions V and D in order to obtain (15). 17

4 References Aliprantis, C. D., D. J. Brown and O. Burkinshaw (1990), "Existence and optimality of competitive equilibria", Heidelberg and New York: Springer and Verlag. Aliprantis, C. D., D. J. Brown and O. Burkinshaw (1997), "New proof of the existence of equilibrium in a single sector growth model", Macroeconomic Dynamics 1, 669-679. Alvarez, F. and N. Stokey (1998), "Dynamic programming with homogeneous functions", Journal of Economic Theory 82, 167-189. Bewley, T. F. (1972), "Existence of equilibria in economies with finitely many commodities", Journal of Economic Theory 4, 514-540. Colonius, F. (1983), "A note on the existence of Lagrange multipliers", Appl. Mathematics and Optimization 10, 187-191. Dana, R.-A. and C. Le Van (1990), "On the structure of pareto-optima in an infinite horizon economy where agents have recursive preferences", Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 64, 269-302. Dana, R.-A. and C. Le Van (1991), "Optimal growth and Pareto optimality", Journal of Mathematical Economics 20, 155-180. Dechert, W. D. (1982), Lagrange multipliers in infinite horizon discrete time optimal control models", Journal of Mathematical Economics 9, 285-302. Dechert, W. D. and K. Nishimura (1983), "A complete characterization of optimal growth paths in an aggregate model with a non-concave production function", Journal of Economic Theory 31, 332-354. Duran, J. (2000), "On dynamic programming with unbounded returns", Economic Theory 15, 339-352. Ekeland, I. and J. A. Scheinkman (1986), "Transversality conditions for some infinite horizon discrete time optimization problems", Mathematics of Operations Research 11(2), 216-229. Le Van, C. and R.-A. Dana (2003), "Dynamic Programming in Economics", Kluwer Academic Publishers. Le Van, C. and L. Morhaim (2002), "Optimal growth models with bounded or unbounded returns: a unifying approach", Journal of Economic Theory 105(1), 158-187. Majumdar, M. (1972), "Some general theorems on efficiency prices with an infinite dimensional commodity space", Journal of Economic Theory 5, 1-13. 18

McKenzie, L. W. (1986), "Optimal economic growth, turnpike theorems and comparative dynamics", in Handbook of Mathematical Economics, Vol. III. Edited by Arrow, K. J. and M. D. Intriligator. North Holland, Amsterdam. Rockafellar, R.T. (1976), "Lagrange multipliers in optimization", SIAM-AMS Proceedings 9, 145-168. Rudin, W. (1973), "Functional Analysis", McGraw-Hill, New York. Rustichini, A. (1998), "Lagrange multipliers in incentive-constrained problems", Journal of Mathematical Economics 29, 365-380. Stokey, N. L., R. E. Lucas, Jr., and E. C. Prescott (1989), "Recursive methods in economic dynamics", Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Weitzman, M. L. (1973), "Duality theory for infinite horizon convex models", Management Science 19(7), 783-789. 19