The New Keynesian Model

Similar documents
Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Gali (2008), Chapter 3

Macroeconomics Theory II

Monetary Policy Design in the Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. October 2015

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes.

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Lecture 6, January 7 and 15: Sticky Wages and Prices (Galí, Chapter 6)

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

Equilibrium Conditions for the Simple New Keynesian Model

Problem 1 (30 points)

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

New Keynesian Macroeconomics

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital. Lawrence J. Christiano

Optimal Monetary Policy with Nominal Rigidities. and Lumpy Investment

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

The Basic New Keynesian Model, the Labor Market and Sticky Wages

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Inflation Stabilization and Welfare: The Case of a Distorted Steady State

Aspects of Stickiness in Understanding Inflation

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

The Return of the Wage Phillips Curve

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Dynamics of Sticky Information and Sticky Price Models in a New Keynesian DSGE Framework

Optimal Monetary Policy

Endogenous information acquisition

Monetary Economics Notes

WORKING PAPER NO INTEREST RATE VERSUS MONEY SUPPLY INSTRUMENTS: ON THE IMPLEMENTATION OF MARKOV-PERFECT OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

A Dynamic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy. Jordi Galí and Tommaso Monacelli. March 2005

2 New Keynesian Model

The Zero Lower Bound

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Forward Guidance without Common Knowledge

Nominal Rigidities, Government Spending, and Long-Run Policy Trade-Off

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

New Keynesian DSGE Models: Building Blocks

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

Citation Working Paper Series, F-39:

DSGE Models in a Liquidity Trap and Japan s Lost Decade

Discretionary Monetary Policy in the Calvo Model. Willem Van Zandweghe and Alexander L. Wolman February 2010; Revised March 2017 RWP 10-06

Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

The Smets-Wouters Model

Comments on A Model of Secular Stagnation by Gauti Eggertsson and Neil Mehrotra

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

WORKING PAPER SERIES OPTIMAL SIMPLE MONETARY POLICY RULES AND NON-ATOMISTIC WAGE SETTERS IN A NEW-KEYNESIAN FRAMEWORK NO 690 / OCTOBER 2006

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Incorporating a Simple DMP Version of the Labor Market and Rediscovering the Shimer Puzzle

The full RBC model. Empirical evaluation

Discouraging Deviant Behavior in Monetary. Economics

Optimal Trend In ation

GCOE Discussion Paper Series

Expanding Variety Models

The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy

Macroeconomics Theory II

Discretionary Monetary Policy in the Calvo Model

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

To Respond or Not to Respond: Measures of the Output Gap in Theory and in Practice

A framework for monetary-policy analysis Overview Basic concepts: Goals, targets, intermediate targets, indicators, operating targets, instruments

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 09-18

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Taylor rules with delays in continuous time

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Do credit market imperfections justify a central bank s response to asset price fluctuations?

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Inflation dynamics, marginal cost, and the output gap: Evidence from three countries

Monopolistic Competition when Income Matters

Assessing the Fed s Performance through the Effect of Technology Shocks: New Evidence

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Monetary Policy with Heterogeneous Agents: Insights from Tank Models

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

Aggregate Supply. A Nonvertical AS Curve. implications for unemployment, rms pricing behavior, the real wage and the markup

Y t = log (employment t )

Bayesian Estimation of DSGE Models: Lessons from Second-order Approximations

Transcription:

The New Keynesian Model Basic Issues Roberto Chang Rutgers January 2013 R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 1 / 22

Basic Ingredients of the New Keynesian Paradigm Representative agent paradigm Nominal rigidities, price setting Phillips Curve, Dynamic IS Focus on policy rules Welfare based analysis of policy R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 2 / 22

Aggregate Supply The final good is a Dixit-Stiglitz aggregate of individual varieties: Y t = hence the demand for each variety is where the price level is [ ] ε Y t (i) ε 1 ε 1 ε di ( ) Pt (i) ε Y t (i) = Y t P t [ 1/(1 ε) P t = P t (i) di] 1 ε R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 3 / 22

The Pricing Problem The reason to assume monopolistic competition is to obtain a model in which prices are set by producers. Producer i has technology Y t (i) = A t N t (i) 1 α Assuming that labor is homogeneous, nominal marginal cost is then: MC t (i) = dn t(i) dy t (i) = 1 ( ) 1 1 α (Y 1 α t(i)) α 1 1 α.wt A t In the absence of nominal rigidities, each producer would set price as a constant markup over marginal cost: where M = ε ε 1 P t (i) = MMC t (i) = MMC t = P t R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 4 / 22

Calvo Pricing Nominal rigidities are often introduced via the "Calvo protocol", which implies that the optimal pricing rule is θ k { ( )} E t Qt,t+k Y t+k t P t MMC t+k t = 0 k=0 The Calvo protocol also implies that P 1 ε t = (1 θ)p 1 ε t + θp 1 ε t 1 R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 5 / 22

Linear Approximation: The Phillips Curve The log linear approximation to these eqs. (assuming that inflation is zero in ss) yields: p t = µ + (1 βθ) k=0 (βθ) k E t { mct+k t + p t+k } p t = (1 θ)p t + θp t 1 One has to work a little to express mc t+k t in a simple way: where mc t+k t = mc t+k αε 1 α (p t p t+k ) mc t = (w t p t ) 1 1 α (a t αy t ) is a measure of average marginal cost (I ignore irrelevant constants) R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 6 / 22

Inflation Combining, you get where λ depends on θ, α, ε. Notice that this means π t = βe t π t+1 + λmc t π t = λe t β k mc t+k k=0 This says that inflation goes up when marginal costs are expected to go up or, equivalently, when markups fall short of desired ones. R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 7 / 22

The Output Gap Woodford suggested to express marginal costs in terms of the "gap " of output from its flexible price or "natural " value. To do this, one expresses marginal costs as: ( mc t = σ + ϕ + α ) y t 1 + ϕ 1 α 1 α a t This holds whether or not prices are flexible. But if they are, mc t is constant, say mc. This leads to a definition of natural output as: ( mc t mc = σ + ϕ + α ) (y t yt n ) 1 α The difference ỹ t = y t y n t is the output gap R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 8 / 22

The NKPC Combining everything, we finally get the NKPC: π t = βe t π t+1 + κỹ t Note that the output gap has entered the determination of inflation because it completely summarizes the role of marginal costs in pricing. In more complicated models, marginal costs may depend on other variables, such as relative prices or the real exchange rate (in open economies). R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 9 / 22

Aggregate Demand The representative agent s problem in Gali s chapter 3 is standard. (Note, however, that complete financial markets are implicitly assumed). In equilibrium, Y t = C t, and log linearizing the Euler equation yields y t = E t y t+1 1 σ (i t E t π t+1 ρ) This can be usefully rewritten by substituting output with the output gap: where ỹ t = E t ỹ t+1 1 σ (i t E t π t+1 r n t ) r n t = π + σe t y n t+1 is a good enough definition of the natural interest rate. This is the dynamic IS and essentially says that aggregate demand increases when the (actual) real interest rate falls below the natural interest rate. R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 10 / 22

Recap, so far We have AS, the NKPC: π t = βe t π t+1 + κỹ t and AD, the IS: ỹ t = E t ỹ t+1 1 σ (i t E t π t+1 r n t ) These two equations will determine the behavior of inflation and the output gap once we relate the nominal interest rate to the same two variables. R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 11 / 22

Interest Rate Rules If one assumes that i t follows an exogenous process, however, the price level is indeterminate. Leeper, Woodford: in practice, central banks adjust policy rate in response to endogenous variables Taylor: this is in fact what the Fed does Example: Taylor Equilibrium is then determinate if Taylor Principle i t = ρ + φ π π t + φ y ỹ t + v t κ(φ π 1) + (1 β)φ y > 0 R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 12 / 22

Policy Analysis: The Effi cient Allocation Gali (section 4.1) considers the effi ciency problem and shows that effi ciency requires: C t (i) = C t N t (i) = N t U nt U ct = MPN t These are intuitive. Equilibrium allocations may differ because of two distortions: imperfect competition and nominal rigidities. R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 13 / 22

Ineffi ciencies related to Imperfect Competition To isolate those, consider flexible price equilibria. In those, all varieties have the same price and are produced in the same quantities, so C t (i) = C t and N t (i) = N t. On the other hand, markup pricing means so P t = MMC t = M W t MPN t U nt U ct = W t P t = MPN t M < MPN t since M = ε/(ε 1) > 1 In words, the real wage is less than the marginal product of labor, which leads to ineffi ciently low employment Accordingly, much of the literature assumes that there is a subsidy τ = 1/ε to the wage, which restores the effi ciency of flex price equilibria. R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 14 / 22

Ineffi ciencies Related to Nominal Rigidities In equilibrium, average markups are P t M t = P t = MC t (1 τ)w t /MPN t P t M = W t /MPN t assuming a subsidy τ = 1/ε to the wage. Then we get U nt U ct = W t P t = MPN t M M t The factor M M t can fluctuate and is an ineffi cient wedge between MRS and MPN In addition, under Calvo Pricing, different varieties of the same good have different prices, which leads to violations of the effi ciency conditions C t (i) = C t and N t (i) = N t. These are usually referred to as costs of price dispersion. R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 15 / 22

The Optimality of Zero Inflation In the basic model, zero inflation implies that equilibrium outcomes coincide with natural (flex price) outcomes, which are effi cient by construction. Not much else needs to be said, except to check that this is consistent with the way we have expressed the model: π t = 0 implies ỹ t = 0 by the NKPC Then M t = M and U nt U ct = MPN t Finally, all goods are priced the same, so C t (i) = C t and N t (i) = N t. R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 16 / 22

The Implementation Question If zero inflation is optimal, how do we attain it? One possibility: if inflation is zero, then the nominal interest rate must equal the natural interest rate rt n. But a policy rule i t = rt n leads to indeterminacy. (Why?) Instead, one can consider a rule: i t = r n t + φ π π t ==> If φ π > 1, the equilibrium is determinate, and implies π t = 0 at all times. Note that this rule is "complex "in that it requires observing r n t. R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 17 / 22

Evaluating Simple Rules For many reasons, one may want to compare alternative simple rules, such as Taylor s: i t = ρ + φ π π t + φ y ỹ t + v t Gali (ch. 4 and Appendix) shows that, if the flex price outcome is effi cient, equilibrium outcomes can be ranked according to the loss function: W = 1 [( 2 E β t σ + ϕ + α ) var(ỹ t ) + ε ] t=0 1 α λ var(π t) Note ( the interpretation ) of the coeffi cients: σ + ϕ+α 1 α captures the importance of the wedge between MRS and MPN matters because of price dispersion (λ depends on θ) ε λ R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 18 / 22

Policy Tradeoffs The basic model displays a divine coincidence: stabilizing inflation leads to flexible price equilibria which are effi cient. Hence there is no policy tradeoff. The literature has then asked: what if flexible price outcomes are not effi cient? This makes the policy question much harder. Gali (ch. 5) starts with the assumption that flexible price outcomes are effi cient in the steady state. In this case, it is useful to define the welfare relevant output gap, x t = y t yt e, as the (log) difference between output and its effi cient level. A second order approximation to welfare is then given by In turn, the NKPC can be written as E β t (π 2 t + α x xt 2 ) t=0 π t = βe t π t+1 + κx t + u t where u t = κ(y e t y n t ) is a purely exogenous process (cost push). R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 19 / 22

Optimal Policy: Commitment Versus Discretion Consider the problem of maximizing: subject to E β t (π 2 t + α x xt 2 ) t=0 π t = βe t π t+1 + κx t + u t for t = 0, 1, 2,... This is a relatively simple problem (subsection 5.1.2) However, the solution is time inconsistent: if the policymaker reoptimizes at some time t 1, she will depart from the original plan (Calvo, Kydland-Prescott) R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 20 / 22

One possible solution under discretion: the policymaker at t assumes that his choice at t will not affect what happens in future periods. Then the choice problem at t is to maximize π 2 t + α x xt 2 subject to The solution is simply x t = κ α x π t. But other solutions may be possible! π t = κx t + u t + constant R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 21 / 22

The Ineffi cient Steady State Case In the more general case of an ineffi cient steady state, Gali shows that the second order approximation to welfare has a linear term: E β t (π 2 t + α x ˆx t 2 ) Λˆx t t=0 where ˆx t = x t x, and x is the welfare relevant output gap in the zero inflation steady state. This is problematic because one can no longer use a linear approximation to the equilibrium conditions to evaluate welfare up to second order. Several solutions in the lit: 1. Assume that the steady state distortion is "small " 2. Approximate equilibrium to second order 3. Solve for optimum policy with original nonlinear specification, then linearize. R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 22 / 22