Technical Appendix: When To Fire Customers? Customer Cost Based Pricing

Similar documents
Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising

Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation

in Search Advertising

Optimal Monopoly Mechanisms with Demand. Uncertainty. 1 Introduction. James Peck and Jeevant Rampal. December 27, 2017

Standards vs. labels with imperfect competition and asymmetric information

Market Expansion in Duopoly

EconS Vertical Integration

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 12 Price discrimination (ch 10)-continue

Chapter 5. The Engine of Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Competition in Two-Part Taris Between Asymmetric Firms

Patent Licensing, Entry and the Incentive to Innovate

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101

Competition in Two-Part Taris Between Asymmetric Firms

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Figure T1: Consumer Segments with No Adverse Selection. Now, the discounted utility, V, of a segment 1 consumer is: Segment 1 (Buy New)

Free (Ad)vice. Matt Mitchell. July 20, University of Toronto

Midterm Exam - Solutions

Rice University. Answer Key to Mid-Semester Examination Fall ECON 501: Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Part A

Electronic Companion to Tax-Effective Supply Chain Decisions under China s Export-Oriented Tax Policies

Supplementary Material for \Collusion with Persistent Cost Shocks"

Technology, Skill and Long Run Growth

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Optimal Income Taxation and Public-Goods Provision with Preference and Productivity Shocks

Technology, Skill and Long Run Growth

Technology, Skill and Long Run Growth

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

One Variable Calculus. Izmir University of Economics Econ 533: Quantitative Methods and Econometrics

x ax 1 2 bx2 a bx =0 x = a b. Hence, a consumer s willingness-to-pay as a function of liters on sale, 1 2 a 2 2b, if l> a. (1)

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

EXTENDING THE SCOPE OF MONOTONE COMPARATIVE STATICS RESULTS

Online Companion to Pricing Services Subject to Congestion: Charge Per-Use Fees or Sell Subscriptions?

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

Schumpeterian Growth Models

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Fixed Term Employment Contracts. in an Equilibrium Search Model

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Advanced Microeconomics

Answer Key: Problem Set 1

Knowing What Others Know: Coordination Motives in Information Acquisition

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Introduction In many industrialised countries the market for electricity has been liberalised. Until the end of the eighties there was usually no comp

Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2

Informational Complementarity

Who should pay for two-way interconnection?

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

ON PRICE CAPS UNDER UNCERTAINTY

Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of Offshoring

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

Internation1al Trade

A Note on Demand Estimation with Supply Information. in Non-Linear Models

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

Chapter 2. The Solow Growth Model

Technical Companion to: Sharing Aggregate Inventory Information with Customers: Strategic Cross-selling and Shortage Reduction

Edinburgh Research Explorer

Self-Enforcing Trade Agreements and Private Information

Bresnahan, JIE 87: Competition and Collusion in the American Automobile Industry: 1955 Price War

Static Models of Oligopoly

Quality Uncertainty with Imperfect Information Acquisition

Homework 1 Solutions

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

Virtual Robust Implementation and Strategic Revealed Preference

The commitment eect in belief evolution

On the Stabilizing Virtues of Imperfect Competition 1

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Beyond the Target Customer: Social Effects of CRM Campaigns

IE 5531: Engineering Optimization I

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach

Competitive Advertising and Pricing

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

Fossil fuels supplied by oligopolies: On optimal taxation and rent capture

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

s<1/4 p i = 2 3 s s [1/4, 9/16[ p i = p j + 2 s p j 1 if p j < p j p i = 2 3 s if p j p j p i = p j if p j < p j s 9/16

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

Addendum to: New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

B Search and Rest Unemployment Fernando Alvarez and Robert Shimer Additional Appendixes not for Publication

Externalities and PG. MWG- Chapter 11

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE)

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

THE LIMITS OF PRICE DISCRIMINATION. Dirk Bergemann, Benjamin Brooks, and Stephen Morris. May 2013 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

In classical competitive equilibrium, the rms in a market maximize prots taking price as given, each rm produces the quantity at which price equals ma

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Online Appendix Durable Goods Monopoly with Stochastic Costs

Advanced Microeconomics

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Ordered Search in Di erentiated Markets

Organization, Careers and Incentives

Technology, Skill and Long Run Growth

"A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics"

Transcription:

Technical Appendix: When To Fire Customers? Customer Cost Based Pricing Jiwoong Shin, K Sudhir, and Dae-Hee Yoon 1 May 011 1 Associate Professor of Marketing, Yale School of Management, Yale University, 135 Prospect St New Haven, CT 0650 (E-mail: jiwoongshin@yaleedu, Tel: (03) 43-6665); James L Frank Professor of Private Enterprise and Management and Professor of Marketing, Yale School of Management, Yale University, 135 Prospect St New Haven, CT 0650 (E-mail: ksudhir@yaleedu, Tel: (03) 43-389); Assistant Professor of Accounting, Yonsei School of Business, Yonsei University, 134 Shinchon-dong, Seodaemun-gu, Seoul, Korea 10-749 (E-mail: dae-heeyoon@yonseiackr, Tel: (8) 13-6579)

Table of Content 1 Numerical Example Analysis for endogenous case when τ is large (τ τ IC = ( s (v sh )δ)δ 4( δ) ) 3 Comparison between Price dierence and Cost dierence

Numerical Example In the main text, we set δ = 09, v = 1, s L =0 For the low and high service cost heterogeneity cases, we set s H =03 and s H =1, respectively Several diagnostic metrics for the rst and second periods are provided in Table A below Customers who buy in the rst period are referred to as Old customers and those who buy only in the second period are referred to as New customers First, consistent with propositions 1 and in the main paper, CCP leads to lower aggregate prots (Π CCP = 0946) than the benchmark prots without CCP (Π NoCCP = 1047) when the service cost heterogeneity is low ( s = 03) ; but CCP has higher prot (Π CCP = 0470 > Π NoCCP = 0466) when the service cost heterogeneity is high ( s = 1) One can also see the intuition about the ratchet eect being stronger when service cost hetergoenteity is low When service cost heterogeneity is low ( s = 03), second period prices rise by 57% for old customers (p 1 = 049 p = 077) No distinction is made between the high and low cost types; only the purchase information is used in setting prices (as in Villas-Boas 004 ) In contrast, when service cost heterogeneity is high ( s = 1), both cost and purchase information are used Second period prices rise by 65% for the high cost old customers (p H 1 = 067 ph = 11), but only by 1% for the low cost customers (p L 1 = 067 pl = 081) The weaker ratcheting eect for the old low cost customers coupled with the price discrimination eect between high and low cost customers makes CCP more protable Second, the optimal retention strategy depends on the service cost heterogeneity When the service cost heterogeneity is low, the average retention rate is 100% because there is no reason to re customers The average retention rate declines to 65% when the service cost heterogeneity is high, but this lower retention is dierentiated by high and low cost customers 100% of the low cost customers are retained, but only 5% of the high cost customers are retained In contrast to general exhortations to raise retention rates across customers, our results demonstrate that optimal retention rates should be managed based on customer characteristics Firms should lower retention rates among its higher cost customers in order to obtain a more favorable mix of low to high cost customers 1

Table A-1: Low Service Cost Heterogeneity ( s = 03) Period 1 Old New Benchmark 1 Benchmark Low Cost High Cost Low Cost High Cost Old New Price 049 049 049 0675 Margin 049 019 034 055 Quantity 043 043 086 105 Customer Share 50% 50% Period Old New Benchmark 1 Benchmark Low Cost High Cost Low Cost High Cost Old New Price 077 077 046 046 077 046 0675 Margin 077 047 046 016 06 031 055 Quantity 043 043 031 031 043 031 105 Customer Share 9% 9% 1% 1% Retention 100% 100% Π CCP = 0946 < Π NoCCP = 1047 Benchmark 1: traditional behavior-based price discrmination based only on the past purchase history Benchmark : the case without price discrimination in which the rms uses neither the past purchase information nor the customer cost type information

Table A-: High Service Cost Heterogeneity ( s = 1) Period 1 Old New Benchmark 1 Benchmark Low Cost High Cost Low Cost High Cost Old New Price 067 067 073 085 Margin 067-033 03 035 Quantity 039 039 0571 070 Customer Share 50% 50% Period Old New Benchamrk 1 Benchmark Low Cost High Cost Low Cost High Cost Old New Price 081 11 065 065 091 071 085 Margin 081 01 065-035 041 01 035 Quantity 039 01 015 015 0571 04 070 Customer Share 49% 13% 19% 19% Retention 100% 5% Π CCP = 0470 > Π NoCCP = 0466 Benchmark 1: traditional behavior-based price discrmination based only on the past purchase history Benchmark : the case without price discrimination in which the rms uses neither the past purchase information nor the customer cost type information 3

Analysis for endogenous case when τ is suciently large (τ τ IC = ( s (v s H )δ)δ 4( δ) ) Recall we only consider the case of s > δvmax H, where cost information was used by the monopolist in the exogenous case This condition ensures that ŵ L 1 satised in equilibrium We conrm that v + sl < ŵ L 1 > v + sl and ŵ H 1 and v + τ + sh < v + τ + sh τ > ŵ H 1 satised when s > δvmax H Therefore, if (IC) constraint is not binding, the rm charges τ are are indeed p L = ŵ1 L and p H = argmax p (p s H )(v + τ p) = v + τ + sh, (01) and D L(p) = min{v pl, v ŵl 1 } = v ŵl 1, DH (p) = min{v+τ ph, v + τ + v ŵh sh 1 } = v+τ v + τ s H Hence, the monopolist does not serve all of the previous customers = Like the exogenous model in the main paper, the rm sets price for customers who have not purchased in the rst period using the rst-order condition from Equation (15) in the main paper as follows: p O = argmax p (p s H )(ŵ1 H p + τ) + (p s L )(ŵ1 L p) = ŵh 1 + ŵl 1 + sh + s L + τ, (0) 4 We summarize the equilibrium outcomes in the following lemma Lemma 1 When service demanded by consumers (and therefore cost-to-serve) is endogenous and the utility from service τ is suciently large that (IC-H) constraint will be always satised, the marginal customers in the rst period dier by customer type: ŵ L 1 = v + s δsh + ( δ)τ (), v + s ŵh δsh 1 = (6 δ)τ () The equilibrium outcomes are as follows: p 1 = (4v ( δ)τ) ( δ) + 8s s(δ δ ), 4() p H = v + sh + τ, p L = ŵ L v + s δsh 1 = ( δ)τ + (), and po = ŵh 1 + ŵl 1 + sh + s L + τ 4 Proof The marginal consumer in the rst period, ŵ j 1 = ŵj 1 (p 1), can be calculated by using the fact that p O < p 1 and the marginal consumer does not get any surplus in the second period if she already 4

purchased it in the rst period:ŵ1 H + τ p 1 = δ ( ŵ1 H + τ po p 1 = δ ( ŵ1 L ) po ŵ L 1 = p 1 δp O 1 δ ) ŵ H 1 = p 1 τ δ(p O τ) 1 δ, and ŵ1 L Therefore, we can obtain the rst period cuto line for purchasing a product by using the fact that p O = ŵh 1 +ŵl 1 +sh +s L +τ 4 : ŵ1 H = p 1 δs δ τ, ŵ1 L = p 1 δs δ In the rst period, the monopolist maximizes the following total expected prot with a common discount factor δ < 1: Π(p 1 ) =(p 1 s H ) ( v ŵ H 1 ) + (p1 s L ) ( v ŵ1 L ) + δ{(p H s H )(v + τ p H ) + (p L s L )(v p L ) + (p O s H )(ŵ H 1 + τ p O ) + (p O s L )(ŵ L 1 p O )}, where ŵ1 H = p 1 δs δ τ,ŵ1 L = p 1 δs δ, p L = ŵl 1, ph = v + τ + sh Taking the rst order condition gives us the rst period price p 1 : And the rst period marginal consumer is now, p 1 = (4v ( δ)τ) ( δ) + 8s s(δ δ ) 4() ŵ L 1 = v + s δsh + ( δ)τ (), v + s ŵh δsh 1 = (6 δ)τ () Hence, p H = v + sh + τ, p L = ŵ L v + s δsh 1 = + ( δ)τ () Further, we can check that v + sl when δ ( v s H) < s : < ŵ L 1 and v + τ + sh τ > ŵ H 1 are satised in equilibrium ŵ1 L v + sl = δ(v sl ) + (1 δ) (s H s L ) + ( δ)τ > 0, () ( ) v + τ + s ŵ1 H H τ = δ(v sh ) (s H s L ) τ < 0 () Unlike the exogenous case, where customer type is xed, now the marginal customer in the rst period from the high and low type dier in their willingness to pay This is because the high type customer gets an extra utility τ from consuming the rm's augmented services 5

From Lemma 1, we identify the τ-condition for (IC-H) constraint to be satised: p L p H τ δ v + s δsh + τ τ IC = ( s (v sh )δ)δ 4( δ) ( δ)τ () v + sh + τ τ δ (03) That is, when τ is suciently large (τ τ IC ), the high type consumer will reveal his type in the rst period by choosing a high level of service Results Suppose that the service cost heterogeneity is suciently large that s > δvmax H, and the utility from service is large enough that τ τ IC = ( s (v sh )δ)δ 4( δ) 1 The monopolist uses CCP and charges dierent prices to the H and L-type customers: p H = v+s H +τ > p L = ŵl 1 Further, the total prot with CCP is greater than the total prot without price discrimination (Π CCP > Π No P D ) when s becomes large Proof First, we calculate the prot under no discrimination Without price discrimination, the monopolist simply maximizes the following per-period prot function Π S t = (p S s H )(v p S + τ) + (p S s L )(v p S ) The optimal price is p S = v+sh +s L +τ 4, and the total prot is Π S = (1+δ) [ Π S ] t = (1 + δ) [(v sh s L ) +(v 3s H +s L )τ+τ ] 8 Using the results of p 1,p H, and pl in Lemma 3 of the main paper, we get Π CCP = v (4+Ω)+(s H ) (+δ) +(s L ) Ω+s L Ω(v τ) s H (+δ)(4v s L ( δ))+ω(4vτ 6s H +τ ) 8(4 δ), where Ω = 4 + ( δ)δ It immediately follows that Π = Π CCP Π S = δ(v ( δ)+4vτ (s H ) (1+δ) (s L ) s L (4v τ) τ +s H (6s L 4v(1 τ)+6τ) 8(4 δ) ( (4 ) (v s L + τ) δ) (1 δ) (1 + δ)τ Therefore, Π 0 if and only if s 1 + δ Hence, as s becomes larger, Π CCP > Π S When τ τ IC, the (IC) constraint for H-type is not binding Therefore, the customers will reveal their types in the rst period even under optimal prices that the monopolist would have charged when the customer type is xed Hence, the equilibrium outcome is consistent with the our main model where the customer types are exogeneous and CCP can increase a rm's prot 6

Comparison between Price dierence and Cost dierence Exogenous case: 1 When the heterogeneity is small: there is no price discrimination so that price dierence (zero) is smaller than cost dierence When the heterogeneity is large, price dierence is always smaller than cost dierence as follows: p H = v + s H, p = v + s δs H, p H p L = s H( + δ) s L vδ ; () p H p L (s H s L ) = s L(3 δ) 3s H ( δ) vδ () Then, p H p L (s H s L ) > 0 if s < s L(3 δ) vδ 3( δ) = s L δ(v s L) 3( δ) < s L,which is a contradiction Therefore, p H p L < s H s L Endogenous case: 1 When τ < τ IC = ((s H s L ) (v s H )δ)δ 4( δ) ; p H p L = τ δ, p H p L (s H s L ) > 0 if τ > (s H s L )δ Therefore, for the condition to hold, it must be the case that τ IC > (s H s L )δ However, we can easily see that τ IC (s H s L )δ because τ IC (s H s L )δ = δ(s H(6 5δ) + vδ s L (6 4δ)) 4( δ) = δ((s H s L )(6 5δ) + δ(v s L )) 0 4( δ) Therefore, p H p L < s H s L When τ > τ IC = ((s H s L ) (v s H )δ)δ 4( δ) ; p H p L = s H( + δ) s L vδ + τ 8 δ 7

We rst note that p H p L (s H s L ) > 0 if And we can show that τ > τ IC since τ > τ = s H(6 3δ) + vδ s L (6 δ) = s H(6 3δ) + vδ s L δ s L (6 3δ) = (s H s L )(6 3δ) + δ(v s L ) τ τ IC = ()((s H s L )(6 5δ) + δ(v s L )) 4( δ) > 0 Therefore, p H p L > s H s L if τ > τ = (s H s L )(6 3δ) + δ(v s L ) 8