Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Similar documents
Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model

EconS Sequential Competition

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Basics of Game Theory

Advanced Microeconomics

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

Static Models of Oligopoly

Industrial Organization

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

EconS Nash Equilibrium in Games with Continuous Action Spaces.

EXAMINATION #4 ANSWER KEY. I. Multiple choice (1)a. (2)e. (3)b. (4)b. (5)d. (6)c. (7)b. (8)b. (9)c. (10)b. (11)b.

Backwards Induction. Extensive-Form Representation. Backwards Induction (cont ) The player 2 s optimization problem in the second stage

Answer Key: Problem Set 1

Durable goods monopolist

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information

October 16, 2018 Notes on Cournot. 1. Teaching Cournot Equilibrium

Y j R L divide goods into produced goods (outputs) > 0 output, call its price p < 0 input, call its price ω

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE)

Oligopoly. Firm s Profit Maximization Firm i s profit maximization problem: Static oligopoly model with n firms producing homogenous product.

Lecture 7. Simple Dynamic Games

ECO 2901 EMPIRICAL INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1

Lecture 1: Introduction to IO Tom Holden

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

3. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilibrium

Quantity-setting games with a dominant

EconS Vertical Integration

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Chapter 7 Duopoly. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos. Computational Economics: a concise introduction

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Repeated Games

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

Research and Development

Modeling of Chaotic Behavior in the Economic Model

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

3.3.3 Illustration: Infinitely repeated Cournot duopoly.

T R(y(L)) w L = 0. L so we can write this as p ] (b) Recall that with the perfectly competitive firm, demand for labor was such that

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games

Mixed duopolies with advance production

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly

Quantity-setting games with a dominant firm

On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation

Pass-Through as an Economic Tool

Lecture 1. Evolution of Market Concentration

Overview. Producer Theory. Consumer Theory. Exchange

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness

Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information

Carrot and stick games

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) -

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

The Economics of E-commerce and Technology

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium

EC3224 Autumn Lecture #03 Applications of Nash Equilibrium

y = F (x) = x n + c dy/dx = F`(x) = f(x) = n x n-1 Given the derivative f(x), what is F(x)? (Integral, Anti-derivative or the Primitive function).

Cournot Competition Under Asymmetric Information

Katz and Shapiro (1985)

STRATEGIC TRADE POLICY AND MANAGERIAL DELEGATION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY FANG WEI (UNIVERSITY OF KITAKYUSHU)

Game theory and market power

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly

Name: Final Exam EconS 527 (December 12 th, 2016)

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

Product differences and prices

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form)

Price and Capacity Competition

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

DISCRETE-TIME DYNAMICS OF AN

THE FIRM: DEMAND AND SUPPLY

Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan Question 1 (duopoly games with imperfect information)

EconS Cost Structures

Vertical Product Differentiation and Credence Goods: Mandatory Labeling and Gains from International Integration

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version)

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Ranking Bertrand, Cournot and Supply Function Equilibria in Oligopoly

Transcription:

This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 1 / 1

We will cover the following topics: with Sequential Moves Bertrand versus Bertrand After these basic static models we will examine: Dynamic oligopoly and Self-enforcing Collusion John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 2 / 1

wrote in 1838 - well before John Nash! He proposed an oligopoly-analysis method that is (under many conditions) in fact the Nash equilibrium w.r.t. quantities. Firms choose... production levels. Version 1: Two-seller game Cost: TC i (q i )=c i q i Demand: p(q) =a bq where Q = q 1 + q 2 John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 3 / 1

Define a game: Players: firms. Action/Strategy set: production levels/quantities. Payo function: profits, defined: 1 (q 1, q 2 )=p(q 1 + q 2 )q 1 TC 1 (q 1 ) 2 (q 2, q 1 )=p(q 2 + q 1 )q 2 TC 2 (q 2 ) Now we need an equilibrium concept. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 4 / 1

{p c, q1 c, qc 2 } is a equilibrium ( Nash-in-quantities equilibrium) if: 1 a) given q 2 = q c 2, qc 1 solves max q 1 1 (q 1, q c 2 ) b) given q 1 = q c 1, qc 2 solves max q 2 2 (q 2, q c 1 ) 2 p c = a b(q c 1 + qc 2 ), for pc, q c 1, qc 2 0 No firm could increase its profit by changing its output level, given what other firms produced. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 5 / 1

F.O.C. (for firm 1): @ 1 (q 1, q 2 ) @q 1 = a 2bq 1 bq 2 c 1 =0 As always, set marginal revenue (a 2bq 1 bq 2 ) equal to marginal cost (c 1 ). How do we know this is a maximum and not a minimum? @ 2 1 (q 1, q 2 ) @(q 1 ) 2 = 2b < 0 8q 1, q 2 John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 6 / 1

Solve the F.O.C. for q 1... Note: q 1 is a function of q 2.Itisthebest-response function, a.k.a. reaction function of firm 1. Call this R 1 (q 2 ). q 1 = R 1 (q 2 )= a c 1 2b 1 2 q 2 John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 7 / 1

John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 8 / 1

Note both best-response functions are downward sloping. For each firm: if the rival s output increases, I lower my output level. (i.e., an increase in a rival s output shifts the residual demand facing my firm inward, leading me to produce less.) This feature of strategic substitutes. Now we can compute equilibrium output levels. q c 1 = a 2c 1 + c 2 3b q c 2 = a 2c 2 + c 1 3b Equilibrium quantity supplied on the market is Q c = q c 1 + q c 2 = 2a c 1 c 2 3b John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 9 / 1

We can also find equilibrium price. p c = a bq c = a + c 1 + c 2 3 What are the pay-o functions in equilibrium? c i =(p c c i )(q c i )=b(q c i ) 2 John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 10 / 1

Version 2: Extending this to N firms. It s harder to see the reaction functions, but the story is exactly the same. Now each firm maximizes profits according to: i (q 1, q 2,...q N )=p (Q) q i TC i (q i ) We would derive the best response function for all N firms. For firm 1, 0 1 q 1 = R 1 (q 2,...q N )= a c 1 1 NX @ q j A 2b 2 j=2 John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 11 / 1

We need N of these equations. However, if we assume that firms marginal costs are the same (TC i (q i )=cq i 8i), it s a lot easier. Each firm has the same reaction function, which is 0 1 q i = R i (q i )= a c 1 @ X q j A 2b 2 j6=i John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 12 / 1

Look at the 2-firm example. When costs (c 1 and c 2 ) are the same, output levels of the two firms are the same. So, we guess in this case that all the output levels (q 1,...,q N ) are going to be the same too. If so, denote q i = q 8i. WATCH OUT! We cannot substitute in q i = q before we ve derived the best response function. This is a common mistake. Why is it a mistake? Assuming that q i = q before we take first order conditions implies that firm i has control over all firms output decisions (the q i s). Here, we substitute q i = q into the already-derived best-response functions. We do this to make the process of solving N equations for N unknowns easier. And, hopefully because we believe the assumption that firms cost functions are truly the same. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 13 / 1

Back to the reaction function. q i = R i (q i )= a c 2b 0 1 @ X 2 j6=i q j 1 A Thus, q = a c 2b q c = Q c = 1 (N 1)q 2 (a c) (N + 1)b N(a c) (N + 1)b Now it is straightforward to solve for p c (the market price) and i c for each firm). (profits John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 14 / 1

Sanity checks... Do we get the monopoly result for N = 1? Do we get the duopoly result for N = 2? What is the solution for N = 1? Take the limit as N! 1 for q c and Q c and p c.theyare: lim N!1 qc = 0 lim N!1 Qc = a c b lim N!1 pc = c John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 15 / 1

Under the assumption of competition, market supply approaches the competitive supply as N! 1. Note that market supply depends on the slope and intercept of demand, and the (common) marginal cost. Individual firms output levels approach zero as N! 1. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 16 / 1

Convince yourself that you can find the equilibrium quantity supplied and price in the market under the assumption of perfect competition. Simple way: let number of firms = 1, but assume that @p @Q =0 and take F.O.C. to find the Q that maximizes profits for the firm under assumptions of perfect competition. This is what we did in the first week. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 17 / 1

We have obtained producer surplus under the assumption that N firms in a market set outputs levels simultaneously according to a Nash-in-quantities equilibrium. What about consumer surplus? We can compute consumer surplus as the area under the demand curve up to the output level that is supplied on the market. CS c (N) = N2 (a c) 2 2b(N + 1) 2 Does consumer surplus go up or down as the number of firms increases in this model? John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 18 / 1

As for social welfare, we want to compare the sum of firm profits and consumer surplus as the number of firms increases. (Firms are owned by consumers in the end...) We can compute this as a function of the number of firms in the market. The bottom line: firm profits go down as more firms enter, but consumer surplus goes up, and goes up by more. (a c) W c (N) =CS c (N)+N c 2 N 2 +2N (N) = 2b N 2 +2N +1 The important point: @W c (N) @N > 0. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 19 / 1

Version 3: Di erent Marginal Costs We have been assuming that all firms are identical, which implies symmetric equilibrium outcomes. Take a look at the results when firms have di erent levels of marginal cost. Let marginal cost of firm i be c i. The F.O.C. is only a slight modification from before. @ i = a 2bqi b X qj c i =0 @q i i6=j John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 20 / 1

Rewrite the F.O.C. as Substitute in for price: Rearrange... a bq bq i = c i p c i = bq i Q Q p p p p c i c i = bq i Q Q p = @p @Q qi Q Q p The term q i Q the market share of firm i. Denote this simply as s i. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 21 / 1

We now have the inverse elasticity rule of oligopoly: p p c i = s i " d John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 22 / 1

- Stackelberg with Sequential Moves: We could also think about this in a game where firm 1 moves first, firm 2 moves second, etc. We call this a leader-follower market structure, or a Stackelberg game. Keep everything as in the 2-firm cournot model, but assume firm 1 sets quantity (q 1 ) first, then firm 2 sees this qunatity and then chooses its quantity, q 2. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 23 / 1

- Stackelberg Work backwards: Suppose firm 1 sets output level to q 1. What would firm 2 do? R 2 (q 1 )= a c 2b 1 2 q 1 Firm 1 can figure this out. What will Firm 1 do in response? max q1 [p(q 1 + R 2 (q 1 ))q 1 cq 1 ] John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 24 / 1

- Stackelberg Firm 1 can figure this out. What will Firm 1 do in response? max q1 [p(q 1 + R 2 (q 1 ))q 1 cq 1 ] What s di erent between this profit function and the profit function? John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 25 / 1

- Stackelberg Turns out leader output level is: q1 S = a c 2b = 3 2 qc. Follower output level is: q2 S = a c 4b = 3 4 qc. Equilibrium price is lower than, output is larger than hence more consumer surplus. First-mover advantage: leader makes more profit than follower. Leader is better o than in. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 26 / 1

Bertrand When do you think price setting makes more sense than setting quantity? In general, economists may believe that di erent assumptions hold for di erent settings. Then we have to argue about which one is more consistent with the data. Bertrand reviewed s work 45 years later. Go through a two-firm example again. Now firms set prices. We need two assumptions. 1 Consumers always purchase from the cheapest seller (recall definition of homogeneous goods). 2 If two sellers charge the same price, consumers are split 50/50. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 27 / 1

Bertrand The second assumption is that demand takes the form: 8 >< 0 if p i > p j or p i > a a p q i = 2b if p i = p j = p < a >: a p b if p i < min(a, p j ) Equilibrium: p b 1, pb 2, qb 1, qb 2 is a Bertrand equilibrium ( Nash-in-prices equilibrium) if: 1 a) given p 2 = p b 2, pb 1 solves max p 1 1 (p 1, p b 2 )=(p 1 c 1 )q 1 b) given p 1 = p b 1, pb 2 solves max p 2 2 (p b 1, p 2)=(p 2 c 2 )q 2 2 q 1 and q 2 are determined as above. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 28 / 1

Bertrand That is: No firm could increase its profit by changing its price, given the price set by the other firm. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 29 / 1

Bertrand 1 If costs are the same, a Bertrand equilibrium is price = marginal cost, with quantity supplied on the market equal to the perfectly competitive outcome (equally split between the two firms). 2 If costs di er, (say firm 1 has cost = c 1 where c 1 < c 2 ), then the firm with the lower cost charges p 1 = c 2 ",firm2sellszeroquantity, and firm 1 sells quantity given by q1 b = (a c 2+") b. Intuition: If costs are the same, undercutting reduces price to marginal cost. If costs di er, undercutting reduces price to just below the cost of the high-cost firm. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 30 / 1

Bertrand P MC Marginal Cost Demand Q John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 31 / 1

Bertrand w capacity constraints (keep the assumption that costs are the same): Previous results (with no capacity constraints): 1 price competition reduces prices to unit costs 2 firms earn zero profits. Do we believe these results? Maybe, maybe not. We might worry about the fact that the number of firms makes no di erence. Undercutting reduces price to marginal cost with only 2 firms. (Consider the policy implications of this for the anti-trust authorities.) John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 32 / 1

Bertrand w capacity constraints Edgeworth had the idea that in the short run, firms may be constrained by capacity that limits their production levels. Bertrand with capacity constraints: Consider the following example. There are two hair salons, both charging an initial price of $35. Under the basic Bertrand model (no capacity constraints), Salon-2 could take all customers if it set its price at $34. Suppose initial business is 12 haircuts per day per firm, and that the maximum capacity for either firm is 15 haircuts in a day. Now the basic Bertrand result of marginal cost pricing won t arise. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 33 / 1

Bertrand w capacity constraints Assume the marginal cost of a haircut is simply c. The regular Bertrand solution is of course p 1 = p 2 = c 1 = 2 =0 And the total market output is the same as the competitive level of output q 1 + q 2 = Q Competn = a bp = a bc But now add in the capacity constraint (k i ) with the following features: k i < Q Competn k i > 1 2 (QCompetn ) John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 34 / 1

Bertrand w capacity constraints If p 2 > p 1 = c, firm 2 loses some customers, but not all of them, because firm 1 cannot serve the entire residual demand. =) 2 > 0forp 2 = p 1 + " In other words, there exists a unilateral profitable deviation from p 1 = p 2 = c. p 1 = p 2 = c is not a Nash equilibrium of the Bertrand game with capacity constraints (of the type described above). In order the determine the Nash equilibrium of the price-setting game with capacity constraints, we can consider a two-stage game: 1 Firms invest in (choose) capacities; then 2 Firms choose prices John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 35 / 1

Bertrand w capacity constraints Example: Let c =0, p =1 Q, for Q = q1+q2. Capacity of each firm: k 1, k 2 Capacity has been acquired at unit cost c 0 2 [ 3 4, 1] Claim 1: Firms won t invest in capacities above 1 3 Proof 1: Monopoly profit is 1 4. Net profit is negative for k i > 1 3. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 36 / 1

Bertrand w capacity constraints Let c =0, p =1 Q, for Q = q1 +q2. Capacity of each firm: k 1, k 2 Capacity has been acquired at unit cost c 0 2 [ 3 4, 1] Claim 2: If k i apple 1 3, both firms charging p =1 equilibrium, and this equilibrium is unique (k 1 + k 2 )isan Proof: Suppose firm 2 is charging p and has capacity k 2.What should firm 1 do? Can firm 1 lower price? No, because at p, both firms are at capacity, so there s no use in lowering price. Can firm 1 raise price? Assume she charges p 1 p.letq 1 be the quantity that firm 1 sells at this high price. Then profit is (1 q 1 k 2 )q 1.Derivativeis1 2q 1 k 2. This is greater than 0 when q 1 = k 1 since k i apple 1 3,i.e.loweringquantity,orequivalently, raising price is not profitable. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 37 / 1

Bertrand w capacity constraints Claim 3: Given Claim 2, it is optimal for firms to set capacities equal to levels in the first stage. Proof 3, step 1: In second stage, p =1 (k 1 + k 2 ). Proof 3, step 2: Hence, firm 1 s profit function is: (1 k 1 k 2 )k 1 c 0 k 1, with derivative (or best-response function), 1 2k 1 k 2 c 0.Hence,k 1 = k 2 = 1 c 0 3. CRUCIAL ASSUMPTION: setting capacities above 1 3 is not profitable. This was due to the high investment costs. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 38 / 1

Bertrand w capacity constraints We made this rather problematic assumption since it turns out that if firms build capacity above the level, then there is no pure strategy equilibrium in the second stage. Mixed strategies are pretty tough to derive; you can look at Kreps and Scheinkman (1983) for a full derivation. Main message of the above model, however, is that capacity constraints can soften Bertrand competition. Sometimes regulation/government can help firms coordinate on capacity limits. Example: zoning laws in communities prevent large stores from being set up. John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 39 / 1

Overview Comparison of Equilibrium in Models Covered So Far: Monopoly (M), (C), Stackelberg CS M < CS C < CS S < CS PC PS M > PS C > PS S > PS PC =0 DWL M > DWL C > DWL S > DWL PC =0 John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 40 / 1