ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 1. Advanced Macroeconomics, ECON 402. New Growth Theories

Similar documents
General motivation behind the augmented Solow model

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PS 5, preliminary version

Advanced Macroeconomics

The Solow Growth Model

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

004: Macroeconomic Theory

14.05: Section Handout #1 Solow Model

The Solow Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. January 26, Econ520

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Generic Analysis of Endogenous Growth Models

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2015 P. Gourinchas/D. Romer MIDTERM EXAM

From Difference to Differential Equations I

Economics 2: Growth (Growth in the Solow Model)

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

Economic Growth

Neoclassical Models of Endogenous Growth

Chapter 9 Solow. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos. Computational Economics: a concise introduction

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

The Romer Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. February 7, Econ520

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

Advanced Macroeconomics

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

Endogenous Growth. Lecture 17 & 18. Topics in Macroeconomics. December 8 & 9, 2008

One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 8 : Empirical studies of convergence

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L2: Economic growth II

The Real Business Cycle Model

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Lecture 1: The Classical Optimal Growth Model

Equating output per worker to GDP per capita, the growth rate of GDP per capita

The Ramsey/Cass-Koopmans (RCK) Model

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Econ 204A: Section 3

DEPARTMENT OF MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMICS Royal Military College of Canada. ECE Modelling in Economics Instructor: Lenin Arango-Castillo

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

2008/73. On the Golden Rule of Capital Accumulation Under Endogenous Longevity. David DE LA CROIX Grégory PONTHIERE

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Problem Set #2: Overlapping Generations Models Suggested Solutions - Q2 revised

1 Motivation for Instrumental Variable (IV) Regression

On Returns to Scale Assumption in Endogenous Growth

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 2 : Balance Growth Paths

Exam 1. Econ520. Fall 2013

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 4

On the Dynamic Implications of the Cobb- Douglas Production Function

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Macroeconomics Theory II

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Econ 7110 slides Growth models: Solow, Diamond, Malthus. January 8, 2017

Solution to Homework 2 - Exogeneous Growth Models

Lecture 3 - Solow Model

Solow Growth Model. Sang Yoon (Tim) Lee. Jan 9-16, last updated: January 20, Toulouse School of Economics

Economics 202A Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 5

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Advanced Macroeconomics

14.452: Introduction to Economic Growth Problem Set 4

Endogenous Growth Theory

A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth

Cointegration and the Ramsey Model

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Online Appendix I: Wealth Inequality in the Standard Neoclassical Growth Model

Knowledge creation and human capital in a growing economy

Factor Substitution, Income Distribution, and Growth in a Generalized Neoclassical Model

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Another Proof for the Stability of a Modified Solow Model

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models. An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS 2015 FINAL EXAMINATION FOR THE FIRST HALF OF SPRING SEMESTER

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

Growth. Growth Theory. Mark Huggett 1. 1 Georgetown. January 26, 2018

Lecture 4 Economic Growth: Foundations

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

Lecture 2: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn Lars Calmfors

Lecture 1: Basic Models of Growth

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

Chapter 5. The Engine of Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

Transcription:

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 1 Advanced Macroeconomics, ECON 402 New Growth Theories The conclusions derived from the growth theories we have considered thus far assumes that economic growth is tied principally to capital accumulation However, as long as capital is paid its marginal contribution to output, and as long as capital s contribution is small relative to labour resource, we are unable to explain the persistent long run growth, and cross country differences in income using capital accumulation In fact, we have relegated that function to the catch all of effectiveness of labour, A There are two strands of New Growth Theories, one seeks to augment the models of Ramsey (1928), Cass (1965) and Solow (1956) by explicitly modelling the accumulation of knowledge, that is effectiveness of labour now is explicitly interpreted as knowledge, and we will examine its evolution across time Generically, these models are know as Research and Development models, or R & D models Another class of model tries to maintain capital s central importance by expanding on the definition of capital to include human capital, such as that as accumulated through education We will refer to these latter class of models as Human Capital Models We will consider each class of models in turn 1 R & D Models The following assumptions will be made in the setup of the model: 1 Time is continuous 2 The variables of the model include labour (L), capital (K), technology (A) and output (Y ) 3 There are two production sectors, one producing output, while the other adds to the stock of knowledge and know-how Both sectors makes use of the stock of knowledge or technological know-how A 4 It will be assumed that this stock of knowledge is a public good so that use of it by one sector does not deny its use by the other 5 Of the two inputs, labour and capital, a fraction of 1 a L and 1 a K will be devoted to use by the output production section, while the remainder a L and a K will be used

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 2 by the knowledge augmentation sector 6 The production function of the output producing sector is, Y t = [(1 a K )K t ] α [A t (1 a L )L t ] 1 α (1) where α (0, 1), and note that this production technology exhibits constant returns to scale 7 The production function of new technology is, A t = B[a K K t ] β [a L L t ] γ A θ t (2) where B > 0, β 0, and γ 0, where B is a shift parameter Notice that the left hand side of the production function is not a stock variable such as Y t, since knowledge production is an addition over previous stocks Further, notice that the production of knowledge can have increasing, constant or decreasing returns to scale Justify to yourself how this is possible Finally, notice that we have not restricted θ since a priori it is not possible to say how current stock of knowledge could affect the discovery of new ones 8 The savings rate is exogenous and constant, and there is no depreciation so that, K t = sy t (3) 9 The rate of growth of the population is exogenous, L t = nl t (4) where n > 0 11 Model without Capital The first thing you should realize is that the model is set up very similarly to the Solow s (1956) model, which mean there is no optimization to be performed Secondly, unlike in Solow s model, there are two endogenous stock variables in the model, namely capital and technology This creates some complications which can be ameliorated by considering a simplified version of it, as suggested in your text, where the economy has no capital

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 3 This allows us to glean the implications of including a secondary knowledge sector that augments the technology of the economy endogenously When there is no capital in the economy, the production function of the economy is, Y t = [A t (1 a L )L t ] (5) Y t L t = A t (1 a L ) (6) since α = 0 Similarly, the production function of technology is, A t = B[a L L t ] γ A θ t (7) From equation (6) it is clear that the growth rate of output per worker in such an economy is proportional to the growth rate of knowledge Therefore, from equation (7), g A t = A t A t ġ A t = = B[a L L t ] γ A θ 1 t [ γ L t A t + L t A t (θ 1) A 2 t A 2 t ] = [γn + (θ 1)g A t ]g A t (8) First note that given the production function for knowledge is strictly increasing, this means that gt A is always greater than zero Secondly, letting the steady state value of growth rate of knowledge be g A, where we dropped the subscript t since in steady state the growth rate must be constant, it can be seen that the rate of growth of knowledge ġ A t is increasing if and only if γn + (θ 1)g A t is positive, and decreasing if γn + (θ 1)g A t is negative Steady state occurs when ġ A t = 0, which occurs when, g A = nγ 1 θ (9) From the equation above, there are three scenarios we have to consider, each in turn: 1 θ < 1: When this is true, equation (8) is a concave quadratic equation with roots 0 and nγ, so that 1 θ ga t is initially increasing, and decreases for gt A > nγ Only at ga 1 θ is the economy at steady state, and is on a balanced growth path At steady state, both A and Y/L are growing at a steady constant rate of g A There are two key points to note here:

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 4 (a) From equation (8) we see that growth rate is dependent on the growth rate (a positive function of) population growth In fact, the economy here can have positive sustained growth if and only if there is population growth It is tempting to interpret this result implies that economies with higher population growth should then have a higher economic growth, which is counter factual There are two possible explanations, firstly if we construe, as in your text, that this model is depicting the economy of the entire world, then given the free flow of technology and that production is increasing and concave in stock of technology (see equation (7), continued growth is possible through population growth since it intuitively makes it more likely a new discovery is achievable A second interpretation highlights the fallacy of the assumption of technology as a public good since in most instances, discoveries are protected by patents and copyrights, which restricts their immediate transmission across borders Nonetheless, all this says is that you have another venue through which to improve the model (if it have not been done) However, if you look carefully at equation (9), differential in the stock of A t across economies does not enter into the growth rate of A t g A This is because since technology generation is endogenous, the stock of knowledge only has a level but not a growth effect (see equation (7)), in other words, we should still see a parallel growth path in technology production which is counter factual (b) Notice that the growth rate of technology is not dependent on the proportion of labour force dedicated to knowledge production (a L ) As in the last argument above, changes in a L would only have a level but not a growth effect 2 θ > 1: In this case, this case implies that equation (8) for ġt A is increasing and convex in gt A Put another way, this case implies that once the economy embarks on knowledge/technology accumulation, the economy grows forever, and never achieved a balanced growth or steady state equilibrium In fact, in this case, the idea of knowledge begets more knowledge here implies that when the economy allocated more labour force towards knowledge acquisition, the greater the growth would be into the future 3 θ = 1: When this is true, ġt A = nγgt A, and growth in technology growth is a linear function of gt A In other words, growth in knowledge is perpetually increasing at a

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 5 ġ A Figure 1: Dynamics of Growth Rate of Knowledge, θ < 1 g A g A constant state in proportion to population growth Here A t has no impact on growth of itself, in other words, there is no cumulative effect Similarly, the proportion of labour dedicated to technology accumulation will raise the long run growth rate of the economy In this case, since the portion of the labour force dedicated to consumption production, 1 a L, which has no growth effects, while a L contributes to future growth, we can conceive of a L as savings, so that when θ = 1, such a model would have savings contributing to the growth of an economy The models exhibiting these features are typically known as linear growth models or more commonly as Y = AK models The important insight from the above discussion is that whether the produced factor of production, knowledge/technology, aids growth is ultimately dependent on whether there is increasing, decreasing or constant returns to scale, which is reflected by θ

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 6 ġ A Figure 2: Dynamics of Growth Rate of Knowledge, θ > 1 g A 12 The General Model We can now examine the more general case of the model when capital is part of the production process so that we have two endogenous variables, capital and knowledge Firstly, note that the capital accumulation equation is, K t = sy t = s[(1 a K )K t ] α [A t (1 a L )L t ] 1 α K [ ] 1 α t = s(1 a K ) α (1 a L ) 1 α At L t (10) K t K t [ ] 1 α gt K At L t = c K (11) K t

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 7 ġ A Figure 3: Dynamics of Growth Rate of Knowledge, θ = 1 g A where c K = s(1 a K ) α (1 a L ) 1 α is just a constant term Next note that, [ ] { Kt K t (ȦtL t + A t Lt ) A t L t ( K } t ) ġ K t = c K (1 α)g K t = c K (1 α)g K t = c K (1 α)g K t A t L t [ Kt ] { A t A t A t L t A t L t { } g A t + n gt K K t K 2 t + L t A t L t K t A t L t L t K t K t K t } (12) which then implies the gt K is rising if and only if gt A + n gt K > 0, and decreasing if it were negative, and constant when it is zero This sets of points are depicted figure 4 This locus has a intercept of n, and a slope of 1, in a diagram with g K on the y axis, and g A on the x axis

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 8 g K n Figure 4: Dynamics of Growth Rate of Capital ġ K < 0 ġ K < 0 ġ K = 0 g A We have still to analyze the evolution of knowledge A, which we can write as, g A t Ȧ t = B[a K K t ] β [a L L t ] γ A θ t A = t = Ba β K A aγ L (Kβ t L γ t At θ 1 ) t = c A (K β t L γ t A θ 1 t ) (13) where c A = Ba β K aγ L Notice that if we think of Kβ t as a constant, then equation (13) is exactly what we had prior Performing a similar analysis, { } ġt A βgt A K t = c A + γga t L t + (θ 1)gA t Ȧ t L t K t A t ġt A gt A = c A (βg K t + γn + (θ 1)g A t ) (14) which implies then that the evolution of g A t is dependent on the sign of βg K t + γn + (θ 1)g A t, where is it rising when the expression is positive, decreasing when negative, and constant if zero Their relationship is depicted in figure 5 The steady state locus occurs

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 9 when ġ A t = 0, which implies that the locus of points where g A t is constant occurs when βgt K + γn + (θ 1)gt A = 0 Therefore, this locus has an intercept of nγ, and has a slope β, in a diagram with g K on the y axis and g A on the x axis That is the locus has of (1 θ) β a positive slope when θ < 1, is a horizontal line when θ = 1, and is negative sloped when θ < 1 g K nγ β Figure 5: Dynamics of Growth Rate of Knowledge ġ A = 0 ġ A > 0 ġ A < 0 g A It can be seen that the production function of the economy experiences constant returns to scale in the two endogenous factor inputs of capital and knowledge, so that whether there is growth in the economy depends on whether there is a increase, decrease or constant returns to scale in the production of knowledge prior without capital in the economy, from the equation for dependent on the value of θ + β, or which as before there are 3 cases Unlike in our discussion Ȧ t, the returns to scale is 1 When θ + β < 1: In this case, β < 1 θ, which in turn implies that 1 θ > 1 θ = 1 β 1 θ This means that the locus for ġ A is greater than ġ K, which implies that there is a steady state equilibrium where the two lines intersect The initial starting points of

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 10 the economy are determined by the initial values of labour, capital and knowledge What figure 6 reveals is that regardless of this initial values, all paths leads to the promised land in this case In this case, at equilibrium, g A + n g K = 0 g A + n = g K g A β + nβ = nγ + (1 θ)g A g A = n(γ + β) 1 (β + θ) (15) Therefore, in this case the growth rate of output at steady state is g K, and output per worker is growing at a rate of g A Show yourself that this is true Further, in such an economy, as in the case where θ < 1 when we examined issues without capital, growth is an increasing function of the population growth Neither the proportion of labour and capital (a L and a K ) dedicated to knowledge acquisition nor changes in savings affect the long run growth of the economy g K nγ β Figure 6: Dynamics of Growth Rate of Knowledge ġ A = 0 ġ K = 0 g A

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 11 2 When θ + β > 1: It is easy to see, using the previous analysis above that the loci of g A and g K would diverge Further regardless of the initial point of the economy, it will always tend towards the region between the two locus, and once it gets there, this economy would experience perpetual growth, as in the case when θ > 1 Here increases in the savings rate, and population growth will perpetuate growth 3 When θ + β = 1: Which means that 1 θ = 1, so that both the locus has the same β slope If population is growing at a positive rate, the loci are parallel to each other, and the analysis is as in β + θ > 1 If population is not growing at all, n = 0, then the loci are the same, and all initial starting points will lead to this locus, and the economy will be on a balanced growth path Although which point on the locus the economy ends in is dependent on the initial starting point, the steady state is unique given those initial values 2 Human Capital Models The previous discussion essentially suggests that knowledge accumulation likewise is incapable of providing a good explanation for the high cross-nation differential in income In this section, what we do instead is to examine the accumulation of technology or technological growth as captured as a direct enhancement on the labour force, in other words, we distinguish between physical from human capital The primary rationale for the distinction between the method prior, that of knowledge accumulation, is the idea that human capital is excludable once it is internalized A way to think about this is that a technological method is available to all for replication and use, but an individual with a set of skills and knowledge when tasked to complete one activity is necessarily prevented from performing another set of activity elsewhere Here by redistribution of resources towards differing forms of capital accumulation now permit the generation of significant changes to output per worker, unlike Solow s (1956) model, which in turn permits this sort of model to explain cross-country differentials in income The idea is that captured within an individual in the labour force is not only her existence as part of the production process, but the skills she has acquired across time, which would justify greater pay then warranted by her innate abilities This would necessitate estimates of labours share in income Further, as the labour force s skill is raised, it has implications on future production capacity as well Consequently, it necessitates the examination of human

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 12 capital as a wholly separate type of capital in the production process, and consequently its explanatory power in cross-border examination of income The basic assumption to such models are as follows: 1 The production function is of the following form: Y t = K α t H β t [A t L t ] 1 α β (16) where α > 0, β > 0, and α + β < 1 In addition, H t is the stock of human capital, besides the other usual variables L t denotes the number of skilled labour, each supplying one unit of labour and some amount of H t Note that the production function reflects constant returns to scale in production 2 Labour and capital has the following dynamics, L t = nl t (17) K t = s K Y t (18) respectively, where s K is the fraction of output channelled towards physical capital accumulation There is no depreciation of capital 3 Since economic growth is not being modelled like in Solow s (1956) model, technological progress is exogenous and is described by, A t = ga t (19) 4 The dynamics of human capital accumulation is as follows: Ḣ t = s H Y t (20) where s H is the fraction of resources channelled towards human capital accumulation Note that you can add to this model what you have learned in the previous section through, 1 having endogenous technological progress, and 2 assuming both human and physical capital accumulation have similar production functions

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 13 To analyse the dynamics, we can write the production function in intensive form, This then means that, Y t A t L t = K α t (A t L t ) α H β t (A t L t ) β y t = k α t h β t (21) K t k t = K t(a t Lt + L t Ȧ t ) A t L t (A t L t ) ( 2 ) = s KY t K t Lt + Ȧt A t L t A t L t L t A t = s K y t k t (n + g) Therefore, at steady state when k t = 0, we have (22) = s K k α t h β t k t (n + g) (23) s K k α t h β t = k t (n + g) kt 1 α = s Kh β t n + g k t = ( s K h β t n + g ) 1 1 α In a diagram with k t on the y axis, and h t on the x axis, it is clear from the above that the locus of k t = 0 is a increasing and concave function of h t From equation (23), we can find the direction of the sketching bars, k t h t = β(s k k α t h β 1 t ) > 0 Similarly, for the locus of ḣt, which in turn implies that on the locus of h t = 0, ḣ t = s H k α t h β t h t (n + g) (24) s H kt α h β t = h t (n + g) ( (n + g)h 1 β k t = s H ) 1/α

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 14 Figure 7: Dynamics of per effective unit of Human Capital k t ḣ t = 0 E k t = 0 h t which implies that the locus is an increasing and convex function in h t Further, ḣt k t = α(s H k α 1 t h β t ) > 0 Diagrammatically, the diagram of the dynamics is reflected below, Notice then that regardless of the initial values of the economy pertaining to all the four variables, which determines the economy s starting point The economy will always tend towards the steady equilibrium of E, and this steady state equilibrium is stable in the sense that once the equilibrium stock of physical and human capital is attained, the economy will remain there, and has no impetus to changes Point E is known as the balanced growth path, where k, h and y are all constant

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 15 The growth rates of the respective variables are, K t = K t (n + g) (25) Ḣ t = H t (n + g) (26) Ẏ t = α(y t K t /K t ) + β(y t Ḣ t /H t ) + (1 α β)y t (L t A t + A t Lt )/(A t L t ) = Y t ((α + β)(n + g) + (1 α β)(n + g)) = Y t (n + g) (27) The first two equalities are obtained from equation (22) and its analogue for ḣt Show that K/L, H/L and Y/L are growing at a rate of g This implies that the long run growth rate, as in Solow (1956) is dependent on exogenous technological progress only

ECON 402: Advanced Macroeconomics 16 References Cass, D (1965): Optimum Growth in an Aggregate Model of Capital Accumulation, Review of Economic Studies, pp 233 240 Ramsey, F P (1928): A Mathematical Theory of Saving, The Economic Journal, pp 543 559 Solow, R (1956): A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65 94