Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition

Similar documents
Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Maximin and minimax strategies in symmetric oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

On the Robustness of Private Leadership in Mixed Duopoly

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

CSR as a bribe to a government

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership

Sion s minimax theorem and Nash equilibrium of symmetric multi-person zero-sum game

Relative Profit Maximization and Bertrand Equilibrium with Convex Cost Functions

Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

On production costs in vertical differentiation models

Sequential mergers with differing differentiation levels

Katz and Shapiro (1985)

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

Advanced Microeconomics

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness

Free Entry and Social Inefficiency under Vertical Oligopoly: Revisited

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous?

Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract

Are Targets for Renewable Portfolio Standards Too Low? A Complementarity-Based Policy Analysis

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Profitability of price and quantity strategies in a duopoly with vertical product differentiation

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract

Quantity-setting games with a dominant

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1

Mixed oligopoly in a two-dimensional city y

THE EXISTENCE OF EQUILIBRIUM IN A DIFFERENTIATED DUOPOLY WITH NETWORK EXTERNALITIES*

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias. Web Appendix

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly

COMPARING BERTRAND AND COURNOT OUTCOMES IN THE PRESENCE OF PUBLIC FIRMS

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Networks of Collaboration in Multi-market Oligopolies

Welfare Reducing Mergers in Differentiated Oligopolies with Free Entry

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies

A Note on Cost Reducing Alliances in Vertically Differentiated Oligopoly. Abstract

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

Equilibrium a la Cournot and Supply Function Equilibrium in Electricity Markets under Linear Price/Demand and Quadratic Costs

On strategic complementarity conditions in Bertrand oligopoly

Mixed duopolies with advance production

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Durable goods monopolist

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Basics of Game Theory

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

A Note on Bank Behavior and Monetary Policies in an Oligopolistic Market

Introduction to Game Theory

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Sequential mergers under product differentiation in a partially privatized market

Endogenous Timing in a Quantity Setting Duopoly

Blocking Development

Static Models of Oligopoly

s<1/4 p i = 2 3 s s [1/4, 9/16[ p i = p j + 2 s p j 1 if p j < p j p i = 2 3 s if p j p j p i = p j if p j < p j s 9/16

On the relation between Sion s minimax theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Mergers, investments and demand expansion

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition

A Note on Networks of Collaboration in Multi-market Oligopolies

Among the available options: horizontal separation (HS) and vertical separation (VS)

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty

Should a local public firm be privatized under unidirectional transboundary pollution?

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Internation1al Trade

Optimal Objective Function

Profitable Competition: A Multi-Product Firm Case

3. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilibrium

Multiple-Quality Cournot Oligopoly and the Role of Market Size

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Mathematical Economics - PhD in Economics

Farsighted stability of collusive price leadership. Yoshio Kamijo and Shigeo Muto Discussion Paper No

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

COMPETITION IN MARKETS WITH NETWORK EXTERNALITIES. Fatma Busra Gunay

Multiple-Quality Cournot Oligopoly and the Role of Market Size

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

Monopolistic Competition when Income Matters

Licensing probabilistic Patents and Liability Rules: The Duopoly case

Modeling of Chaotic Behavior in the Economic Model

No Information Sharing in Oligopoly: The Case of Price Competition with Cost Uncertainty

CORVINUS ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS. The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies. by Barna Bakó, Attila Tasnádi CEWP 11/2014

On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition Taku Masuda and Susumu Sato Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo, Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo 3 October 27 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/82269/ MPRA Paper No. 82269, posted 2 November 27 6:43 UTC

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition Taku Masuda and Susumu Sato October 3, 27 Abstract We investigate the effect of multimarket contacts on the privatization policy in mixed duopoly with price competition. There are two markets, one of which is served solely by the state-owned public firm, and the other is served by both public and private firms. Two markets are linked by the production technology of the public firm. In the general model, we first show that privatization is never optimal in the absence of multimarket contacts, i.e., if there is only one monopoly market or one duopoly market. Then, using a linear-quadratic specification, we show that a positive degree of privatization can be optimal in the presence of multimarket contacts. This result has an implication for the privatization policy in universal service sectors. JEL classification H42, L33 Keywords Multimarket contacts, partial privatization, state-owned public enterprise Introduction Since the early 98s, we have observed a worldwide wave of the privatization of stateowned public enterprises. Nevertheless, many public and semi-public enterprises i.e., firms owned by both public and private sectors) are still active in planned and market economies in developed, developing, and transitional countries. While some public enterprises Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo, Email:taku228@gmail.com Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo, Email:susumusato@live.jp

are traditional monopolists in natural monopoly markets, a considerable number of public including semi-public) enterprises compete with private enterprises in a wide range of industries. Optimal privatization policies in such mixed oligopolies have attracted extensive attention from economics researchers in such fields as industrial organization, public economics, financial economics, international economics, development economics, and political economy. 2 Specifically, drawing on the result of Matsumura 998) that full nationalization is never optimal in Cournot mixed duopoly, many studies on mixed oligopolies investigate how economic environments affect the optimal degree of privatization. 3 In this way, most studies of privatization policies in mixed oligopoly use quantity competition model to characterize the optimal privatization policies. However, there are many applications where it is more plausible to assume that firms compete in prices. 4 In addition, as shown by Matsumura and Ogawa 22), when public and private enterprises can choose whether to compete in price or quantity, they choose to compete in price in the equilibrium. Therefore, discussing the optimal privatization policies under price competition is also important in both practical and theoretical perspectives. That said, there is a conventional wisdom in the literature of mixed oligopoly that the privatization policy, as an device to change the public firm s objective toward profit maximization, does not improve the welfare. The reason is that the privatization increases the public firm s price, and it also increases the price of private firms through the strategic interaction, both of which harm welfare. We argue that this reasoning holds only if firms compete in a single market. If the public firm provides in multiple markets, the result changes. To show this, we consider a variation of model of Kawasaki and Naito 27). There are two markets, one of which is served solely by the state-owned public firm, and the other is served by both public and private firms. Two markets are linked by the production cost of public firm. In this environment, we show that a positive degree of privatization can be optimal in the presence of multimarket contacts. As we explain in Section 3, this comes from the intra- Examples include United States Postal Service, Deutsche Post AG, Areva, Nippon Telecom and Telecommunication, Japan Tobacco, Volkswagen, Renault, Électricité de France, Japan Postal ank, Kampo, Korea Development ank, and Korea Investment Corporation. 2 The idea of mixed oligopoly dates at least to Merrill and Schneider 966). Recently, the literature on mixed oligopoly has become richer and more diverse. For examples of mixed oligopolies and recent developments in this field, see Ishibashi and Matsumura 26), Ishida and Matsushima 29), Colombo 26), Chen 27), Matsumura and Sunada 23), and the papers cited therein. 3 For example, see Lin and Matsumura, 22) for the share of foreign investors who purchases the stock of public firm, Matsumura and Kanda 25) for free entry, and Sato and Matsumura 27) shadow cost of public funds 4 For the anslyses of price competition in mixed oligopolies, see árcena-ruiz, J. C. 27), Matsumura. T. 22), Cremer et al.99), and Andersion et al. 997) for examples. 2

firm production substitution of public firm. An increase in the degree of privatization decreases the production of public firm in monopoly market. This decreases the marginal cost of production for the duopoly market, which raises the incentive to increase the production. When the degree of product differentiation between public and private firms are small, the latter effect tends to dominate the unilateral effect of privatization to decrease the production in duopoly market. Under the price competition, this decreases the equilibrium price of private firm through the strategic interaction. This improves the welfare. This is the reason why partial privatization can be optimal in the presence of multimarket contacts. This result sheds light on an important aspect of privatization policy in mixed oligopoly. For example, in transportation industries, there are several situations where the public firm provides its services in both rural and urban areas probably due to universal service reasons, while private firms only provide services in urban areas. In such a situation, privatization of the public firm can stimulate the competition in urban area through the improved production efficiency of the public firm. 2 Model Consider a model of multimarket mixed price competition. There are a state-owned public firm, firm, and a private firm, firm. There are two markets A and. Market A is solely provided by firm, while market is provided by both firm and firm. This means that the public firm serves two markets, in one of which it competes with the private firm. The representative consumer in market A is characterized by its relative size φ [, ] and the utility function U A x A ) + y A, where x A is the amount of the consumption of the products provided by firm and y A is the consumption of the composite goods. The representative consumer in market is characterized by its relative size φ) and the utility function U x, x ) + y, where x and x are the amount of the consumption of the products provided by firm and firm, and y is the consumption of the composite goods. Assuming that the representative consumer in each market has enough income and U A and U are concave, its consumption is derived from the first-order conditions U A x A = p A, U x = p, and U x = p, ) where p A, p, and p are prices of products. We denote D A p A ), D p, p ), and D p, p ) as the demand functions and CS A p A ) and CS p, p ) as the consumer 3

surpluses. Note that, by the envelope theorem, CS A / p A = D A and CS / p i = D i, i =, hold. We assume that the products in market are substitutes, i.e., D i / p j < for i j. We also assume that the demands are symmetric, that is, D x, x) = D x, x). Further, we assume that the demand functions satisfy the following regularity condition D i p i + D i p j < for i =,, j i. 2) This condition means that if the prices of both firms simultaneously increase, the demands for both products decrease, which is natural to assume in many applications. The production technologies of firms are given by cost functions C q A, q ) and C q ). Then, the profit of each firm is given by Π p A, p, p ) = φd A p A )p A + φ)d p, p )p C φd A p A ), φ)d p, p )), and Social welfare SW is given by Π p, p ) = φ)d p, p ) C φ)d p, p )). 4) SW = φcs A p A ) + φ)cs p, p ) + Π p A, p, p ) + Π p, p ). 5) Firm maximizes the weighted average of its own profit and social welfare where α [, ] is the degree of privatization. 3) Ω = απ + α)sw, 6) 3 Equilibrium We adopt subgame-perfect equilibrium as the solution and solve the model by backward induction. In the market stage, the first-order conditions for firm are given by 5 Ω p A Ω p D A = α p A D = α p p A C ) ) + D A q A + α) DA p A p C ) ) D + D q + α) p p A C q A p C q ) =, ) + D p p C )) =, q 7) 5 In the model of price competition with quadratic costs, firms may have incentives to serve the all the amount demanded. We ignore such possibilities in this model since as shown by Matsumura 22), if the public firm faces the universal service obligation, there are no such incentives. 4

and the first-order condition for firm is given by D p p C ) + D q =. 8) We assume that the second-order conditions are satisfied, i.e., the Hessian matrix of Ω is negative definite, and 2 Π / p <. We also assume that the strategy of firm exhibits strategic complementarity, that is, ) D D 2 C p p 2 + 2 D p p p C ) >. 9) q q A sufficient condition for the strategic complementarity is that 2 D / p p ) and C being weakly convex. Further, to guarantee the uniqueness and the stability of the equilibrium, we put the following restriction. Let R A p ) and R p ) be the best-response functions of firm and R p ) be the best-response function of firm. We assume that R A / p <, R / p <, and R / p <. Let p A α), p α), and p α) be the equilibrium prices given α. Next, in the privatization stage the government chooses α [, ] to maximize SW. Let α be the welfare-maximizing value of α. In the case of interior solution, the first-order condition is given by dsw = dpa α=α φ DA p A + dp φ) p A C q A D p ) + φ) dp D p p C ) + D q p p C ) q p C )) q + D p =. p C )) q We assume that the second-order condition is satisfied. In the case of corner solution, we have either dsw/) α= or dsw/) α=. As a conventional wisdom, in the public monopoly or mixed oligopoly with price competition, positive degree of privatization would never be optimal. The following lemma and proposition formalize this conventional wisdom. ) Lemma If φ =, dp )/ > and dp )/ >. Proof : See Appendix. Proposition If φ = or φ =, full nationalization is optimal. 5

Proof : See Appendix. The reason for the above result is that an increase in the degree of privatization from full nationalization increases the public firm s price since it leans to its own profit, which also increases the price of private firms through the strategic interaction. The former change has negligible effect on the welfare since the public firm is welfare maximizer envelope theorem), but the latter harms the welfare. 4 Partial Privatization with Multimarket Contact In this section, we show that the result drastically changes when we take multimarket contacts into account. In order to maintain tractability in analyzing multimarket situation, we restrict our attention to quadratic utility and cost functions. Specifically, we assume that U A x A ) = x A x A ) 2 /2, U x, x ) = x + x x ) 2 + 2γx x + x ) 2 )/2 for γ, ), C q A, q ) = q A + q ) 2 /2, and C q ) = q ) 2 /2. 6 Then we yield and ) ) γ p Π = p φ) + γ p φ)2 γ p + γp 2, ) γ 2 2 γ 2 ) γ p Π o =p A φ p A ) + p φ) + γp γ 2 ) φ) γ p + γp 2 ) + φ p), 2 γ 2 CS A = pa ) 2, 2) 2 CS = p 2 + p 2 + 2 p p ) 2γ p ) p ). 3) 2 γ 2 ) In this specification, we obtain the following lemma. Lemma 2 If φ, ) then, γ s.t. γ > γ p α < 4) α= Proof : See Appendix. The mechanism behind Lemma 2 is following. Departing from full nationalization to partial privatization makes a public enterprise lean to own profit, and that basically pulls 6 In this specification, all the assumptions put in the general model hold. 6

up its prices in both markets. In a market solely supplied by the public firm especially, it leads to less production. ecause of the less production in the one market, the public firm can have a room in its cost function to cut down the price in the other market. This sequence ends up slicing off the competitor s price through strategic complement relationship. The last effect gets stronger as their products being similar, and beyond some threshold it dominates the first pulling up effect. Lemma 2 immediately yields our main proposition stating an optimality of the partial privatization in price competition situation, which never be optimal without multimarket contacts. Proposition 2 If φ, ) then for γ defined in Lemma 2, γ > γ SW α > 5) α= Proof : Suppose that γ > γ. SW α = dpa dsw dp A + dp dsw dp + dp dsw dp 6) At α =, the first and second term of the right hand side are zero from the envelope theorem. The first factor of the third term is negative from Lemma 2, and the second factor is negative as shown in the proof of Proposition in the Appendix. Thus the sign of the whole derivative is positive. Q.E.D. 5 Conclusion In this paper, we have formally shown the conventional wisdom that under the price competition, privatization of public enterprises never improves welfare if they serve to a single market. Then we have shown that the partial privatization can be optimal if the public firm faces multimarket contacts. These results shed lights on the importance of taking multimarket interactions into account for the analysis of optimal privatization policies. In addition, these results have policy implications for the privatization policy in sectors such as transportation, in which public enterprises often solely serve to rural areas and compete with private enterprises in urban areas. 7

Appendix Equilibrium Prices for Section 4 The equilibrium prices given α under the specification in Section 4 are as follows: p A α) = δ [α2 γ 2 ) φ 3) + α γ γ γ 2 + γφ ) + φ 2)φ 4 ) φ + ) 2φ + 6 ) +γ )γ γ 2 2 ) φ + γ ) 2γ φ + 3]7) p α) = δ [α2 γ 2 )2γ + φ 3) + αγγγ 2 + 2γφ + γ + φ )φ 5) φ 2) 2φ + 6) +γγ 2)γγ + )φ + ) + 2φ) φ + 3]8) where p α) = γ2 + φ 2) α 2 γ 2 ) + α γ 2 φ + ) + γ 3) + γ 2), 9) δ δ α 2 γ 2 ) φ 3) + α γ 4 + γ 2 φ 2 φ 7 ) 3φ + 9 ) + γ 4 φ + ) 2γ 2 φ + 2) 2φ + 6.2) Proof of Lemma In the case where φ =, the equilibrium prices given α is characterized by Ω/ p = and Π / p =. Using the implicit function theorem, we have ) ) ) D D p p C q H dp dp = 2) where At α =, we have H = 2 Ω p 2 2 Π p p D D p 2 Ω p p 2 Π p 2 p C ) q =D + D / p D D / p >, 22) 23) which follows from the regularity condition, p function. < p, and the symmetry of demand 8

Then, using Cramer s rule, we have dp = α= D D / p D / p det H ) D / p D D / p 2 Π p 2 since det H = 2 Ω 2 Π p 2 p 2 2 Ω 2 Π p p p p ) = 2 Ω 2 Π p 2 p 2 R R > p p from the stability condition. Finally, the equation 2 Π dp p p + 2 Π dp p 2 = implies that dp / >. This completes the proof. Q.E.D. > 24) Proof of Proposition For any φ [, ], we have dsw = φ) dp p α= D / p C ) ) D D D D. 25) q p p p p When φ =, this equals zero, which implies α =. When φ =, Lemma implies that dp / α= >. Since the term other than dp / α= >, say dsw/dp, is negative from the stability condition and the first-order condition of firm, we have dp / α= )dsw/dp ) <. Thus, we have α = in both cases. Q.E.D. Proof of Lemma 2 where p α = α= γγ + ) γ 2 + φ 2) fγ, φ) γ 4 φ + ) 2γ 2 φ + 2) 2φ + 6) 2 26) fγ, φ) γ 4 φ + ) 2 γ 3 φ 2 + φ + ) γ 2 φ 2 + 8φ + 4 ) + 7γφ + ) + φ 3. 27) Since γ, φ, ), the sign of the derivative is the same as of f. We have f, φ) <, f, φ) > and fγ, φ) belongs to C class. Then showing f, φ) has at most one extremum in γ, ) for any φ, ) proves Lemma 2. 7 7 Suppose that f, φ) has at most one minimum or maximum. If the extremum is minimum at γ, then f γ γ, φ) < for all γ < γ, since otherwise there is some point γ, γ) such that f γ γ, φ) =, contradicting the assumption that f, φ) has at most one extremum. Similarly, f γ γ, φ) > for all γ γ, ). These imply that there exists γ such that fγ, φ) < for any γ [, γ ), fγ, φ) =, and fγ, φ) > for any γ γ, ]. The case where the extremum is maximum is analogous. 9

Let f γ γ, φ) and f γγ γ, φ) be the first and second partial derivatives with respect to γ. Then, f γ γ, φ) = 4γ 3 + φ) 2 3γ 2 + φ + φ 2 ) 2γ4 + 8φ + φ 2 ) + 7 + φ) 28) f γγ γ, φ) = 2γ 2 + φ) 2 γ + φ + φ 2 ) 24 + 8φ + φ 2 ). 29) Since f γγ, φ) < and f γγ is convex, f γ has at most one extremum. In addition to it, f γ, φ) > and f γ, φ) < together show the solution of f γ, φ) = with respect to γ is unique, which implies so is the extremum of f ). Q.E.D.

Reference Anderson, S. P., de Palma, A. and Thisse, J.-F. 997), Privatization and Efficiency in a Differentiated Industry, European Economic Review, 49), pp. 635 654. árcena-ruiz, J. C. 27), Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Duopoly: Price Competition, Journal of Economics, 93), pp. 263 272. Chen, T.L. 27), Privatization and Efficiency: a Mixed Oligopoly Approach, Journal of Economics, Vol. 23), pp. 25-268. Colombo, S. 26), Mixed oligopoly and collusion, Journal of Economics, Vol. 82), pp. 67-84. Cremer, H., Marchand, M. and Thisse, J.-F. 99), Mixed Oligopoly with Differentiated Products, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 9), pp. 43 53. Kawasaki, A and T. Naito. 27), Partial Privatization under Asymmertric Multi- Market Competition, mimeo. Lin, M.H and T. Matsumura. 22), Presence of Foreign Investors in Privatized Firms and Privatization Policy, Journal of Economics, Vol. 7), pp. 7-8. Matsumura, T. 998), Partial Privatization in Mixed Duopoly., Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 7, pp. 473-483. Matsumura. T. 22), Welfare Consequence of an Asymmetric Regulation in a Mixed ertrand Duopoly, Economics Letters, 5), pp. 94 96. Matsumura, T and O. Kanda. 25), Mixed Oligopoly at Free Entry Markets., Journal of Economics, Vol. 84), pp. 27-48. Matsumura, T and A. Ogawa. 22), Price versus Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly., Economics Letters, Vol. 62), pp. 74-77. Matsumura and Sudana. 23), Advertising Competition in a Mixed Oligopoly., Economics Letters, Vol. 92), pp. 83-85. Merrill, W and N. Schneider. 966), Government Firms in Oligopoly Industries, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 8, pp. 4-42. Ishibashi, I and T. Matsumura. 26), R&D Competition between Public and Private Sectorts., European Economic Review, Vol. 5, pp. 347-366.

Ishida, J and N Matsushima. 29), Should Civil Servants be Restricted in Wage argaining? A Mixed-Duopoly Approach, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 933), pp. 634-646. Sato, S and T. Matsumura. 27), Shadow Cost of Public Funds and Privatization Policies, mimeo. 2