Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Similar documents
Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

The Time Consistency Problem - Theory and Applications

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Inflation traps, and rules vs. discretion

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

GCOE Discussion Paper Series

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Lecture 9: Stabilization policy with rational expecations; Limits to stabilization policy; closed economy case.

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Third Edition

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes.

Lecture 4A: The Discrete-Time Overlapping-Generations Model: Basic Theory & Applications

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

Advanced Macroeconomics

Stabilization policy with rational expectations. IAM ch 21.

Note on Time Consistency

Public Economics Ben Heijdra Chapter 3: Taxation and Intertemporal Choice

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

POLICY GAMES. u t = θ 0 θ 1 π t + ε t. (1) β t (u 2 t + ωπ 2 t ). (3) π t = g t 1 + ν t. (4) g t = θ 1θ 0 ω + θ 2 1. (5)

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Public Economics Ben Heijdra Chapter 9: Introduction to Normative Public Economics

Can a Conservative Governor Conduct an Accommodative Monetary Policy?

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

Blocking Development

Eco504, Part II Spring 2008 C. Sims POLICY GAMES

POLICY GAMES. u t = θ 0 θ 1 π t + ε t. (1) β t (u 2 t + ωπ 2 t ). (3)

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 8. Institutional Change and Democratization

The Real Business Cycle Model

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: Solving Models with Rational Expectations

Macroeconomics Theory II

The Making of Optimal and Consistent Policy: An Implementation Theory Framework for Monetary Policy*

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 8. Institutional Change and Democratization

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

Macroeconomics Theory II

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital?

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Delegation, Time Inconsistency and Sustainable Equilibrium

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

MA Macroeconomics 4. Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model

TIME INCONSISTENCY AND REPUTATION IN MONETARY POLICY: A STRATEGIC MODELLING IN CONTINUOUS TIME

The Making of Optimal and Consistent Policy: An Implementation Theory Framework for Monetary Policy*

Advanced Macroeconomics

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

14.05 Lecture Notes Crises and Multiple Equilibria

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

An introduction of a simple monetary policy with savings taxation in the overlapping generations model

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 7: A Closer Look at the Labour Market

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

Loss Aversion and the Dynamics of Political Commitment

Lecture 2 Optimal Indirect Taxation. March 2014

Problem 1 (30 points)

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Equilibrium Determinacy in a Two-Tax System with Utility from Government Expenditure

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 6. Solving Models with Rational Expectations

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Dynamic Optimization Problem. April 2, Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo. Math Camp Day 4. Daiki Kishishita.

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions)

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Third Edition

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Lars Svensson 2/16/06. Y t = Y. (1) Assume exogenous constant government consumption (determined by government), G t = G<Y. (2)

INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT: THE PHILLIPS CURVE. Dongpeng Liu Department of Economics Nanjing University

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 9: Search in the Labour Market

Time Consistency of Optimal Monetary and Fiscal Policy in a Small Open Economy

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

The Lucas Imperfect Information Model

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

Recursive Methods Recursive Methods Nr. 1

Transcription:

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition Chapter 9: Macroeconomics policy, credibility, and politics Ben J. Heijdra Department of Economics & Econometrics University of Groningen 1 September 2009 Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 1/34

Outline Dynamic inconsistency and inflation 1 Dynamic inconsistency and inflation 2 3 Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 2/34

Aims of this lecture What do we mean by dynamic inconsistency? How can reputation effects help in solving the problem? Why do we appoint conservative central bankers? Why does taxing capital lead to dynamic inconsistency? Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 3/34

Dynamic inconsistency (1) Monetary policy: policy maker exploits the Lucas supply curve. The Lucas supply curve is: y = ȳ + α [π π e ] + ε, α > 0 y (ȳ) is the logarithm of (full employment) output. π is actual inflation. π e is expected inflation. ε is a stochastic supply shock [observable to policy maker but not to public]. LSC can be inverted: π = π e + (1/α)[y ȳ ε] In terms of Figure 9.1 the LSC curves are upward sloping lines with a vertical intercept at the level of π e. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 4/34

Figure 9.1: Consistent and optimal monetary policy π E D! Ω D π = (1/α)[y! y] - LSC D E C! Ω C Ω R E R! y - E! y * y LSC R π =!(α/β)[y! y * ] Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 5/34

Dynamic inconsistency (2) The objective function of the policy maker [social welfare function]: Ω 1 2 [y y ] 2 + β 2 π2, β > 0 y is desired output target of the policy maker. y > ȳ; policy maker deems ȳ to be too low [overly ambitious? ȳ distorted?]. β measures the relative inflation-aversion of the policy maker [ high β is a right-winger]. Policy maker chooses π (by monetary policy) and thus y to minimize Ω subject to the Lucas supply curve. The Lagrangian is: min {π,y} L 1 2 [y y ] 2 + β 2 π2 + λ [y ȳ α(π π e ) ε] Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 6/34

Dynamic inconsistency (3) First-order conditions: L y = (y y ) + λ = 0 L = βπ αλ = 0 π where λ is the Lagrange multiplier. Combining the two FONCs yields the social expansion path [combinations of π and y for which Ω is minimized]: y y = (β/α)π π = (α/β)[y y ] (S1) In terms of Figure 9.1, the FONC is a downward sloping [dashed] line through y. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 7/34

Dynamic inconsistency (4) The optimal solution under discretionary policy is computed by combining (S1) with the constraint and solving for the inflation rate, π D : π D = α2 π e + α [y ȳ ε] α 2 + β (S2) In terms of Figure 9.1, all points on the line between E D and E are solutions for π D for a particular expected price level (π e ). By invoking the rational expectations hypothesis [REH] we find a unique solution for the inflation rate under discretionary policy. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 8/34

Dynamic inconsistency (5) Derivation: By REH we have π e = E(π D ). =0 From (S2) we get: {}}{ E(π D ) = α2 π e + α[y ȳ E(ε)] α 2 = π e + β so that we can solve for π e : π e = α β [y ȳ] (S3) Substituting (S3) into (S2) and the LSC we find the actual inflation rate: π D = (α/β)[y ȳ] α α 2 + β ε y D = ȳ + β α 2 + β ε In Figure 9.1 this is represented by point E D. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 9/34

Dynamic inconsistency (6) But the discretionary solution (π D, y D ) is sub-optimal! If the policy maker commits to a zero-inflation rule (π R = 0) and households would expect it to stick to the rule [so that π e = 0 also] then output would be: y R = ȳ + ε In terms of Figure 9.1 the rule-based solution (π R, y R ) is found in point E R. [Later on we shall use R to denote reputation.] Social welfare is higher in E R than in E D. But unfortunately the rule-based solution is (π R, y R ) inconsistent! If the policy maker is able to convince the public that it will follow the rule [so that π e = 0] then the policy maker is tempted to produce surprise inflation to steer the economy towards y. In terms of Figure 9.1 the cheating solution [subscript C] lies at point E C. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 10/34

Dynamic inconsistency (7) We find: π C = α [y ȳ ε] α 2 + β β y C = α 2 + βȳ + It follows from the diagram that: α2 α 2 + β y + Ω D > Ω R > Ω C > 0 β α 2 + β ε Discretion: satisfies REH but is sub-optimal [worst of all cases]. Rule: optimal and satisfies REH. But is open to temptation and thus not credible. Cheating: closest to bliss but inconsistent with REH. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 11/34

Reputation as an enforcement mechanism (1) Idea presented by Barro & Gordon (1983). Key idea: Monetary policy is like a prisoners dilemma [PD] game. If we only consider solution consistent with the REH then (π R,y R ) is preferable over (π D,y D ) but society nevertheless ends up with the worst case. Repeated interactions may help mitigate the PD problem. Barro and Gordon suggest that the reputation of the policy maker may act as an enforcement mechanism which makes the rule-based solution credible Model is inherently dynamic [reputation is an asset that can be accumulated or decumulated!]. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 12/34

Reputation as an enforcement mechanism (2) The social welfare function is now: V Ω 0 + Ω 1 1 + r + Ω 2 (1 + r) 2 + = Ω t (1 + r) t t=0 where r is the discount factor [interest rate] and Ω t is: Ω t 1 2 [y t y ] 2 + β 2 π2 t The Lucas supply is deterministic: y t = ȳ + α [π t π e t], α > 0 Again we look at three types of solution, discretion [D], rule-based [R], and cheating [C]. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 13/34

Policy under discretion From our previous discussion we see that under discretion we would have: π D,t = (α/β)[y ȳ] So that: V D 1 + r Ω D r α 2 + β Ω D 1 2 [ȳ y ] 2 β Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 14/34

Policy under a constant-inflation rule The policy maker follows the rule π t = π R [a constant]. The REH implies E(π t ) = π R. From our earlier discussion we find that: Ω R = 1 2 [ȳ y ] 2 can be generalized [for a non-zero π R ] to: Ω R (π R ) = Ω R + β 2 π2 R The social welfare function under the rule-based solution is: V R (π R ) 1 + r r [ ΩR + β 2 π2 R] Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 15/34

Cheating solution If the policy maker manages to make the agent expect that the rule will be followed [π e = π R ] then he has the incentive to cheat by exploiting the Lucas supply curve associated with π e = π R. The result is: π C = α2 π R + α [y ȳ] α 2 + β β y C = α 2 + βȳ + α2 α 2 + β y αβ α 2 + β π R so that the objective function under cheating is: [ β Ω C (π R ) = 1 2 α 2 + β [ȳ y ] αβ α 2 + β π R [ α 2 + β 2 α 2 + β π R + α α 2 + β [y ȳ] Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 16/34 ] 2 ] 2

Reputation (1) We now introduce the following reputation mechanism [ tit-for-tat ]: π e t = { πr if π t 1 = π e t 1 π D,t if π t 1 π e t 1 If the policy maker did in the last period what the public expected him to do (π t 1 = π e t 1) then this policy maker has credibility and the public expects that the rule inflation rate (π R ) will be produced in the present period. If the policy maker did not do in the last period what the public expected him to do (π t 1 π e t 1) then this policy maker has no credibility and the public expects that the discretionary inflation rate (π D,t ) will be produced in the present period. The public adopt the tit-for-tat strategy in the repeated prisoner s dilemma game that it plays with the policy maker. If the policy maker misbehaves it gets punished by the public for one period. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 17/34

Reputation (2) Consider a policy maker in period 0 which kept its promise and produced the rule inflation in the period before [i.e. in period -1 it set π 1 = π R ]. This policy maker has credibility in period 0 and the public expects π e 0 = π R. The policy maker can do two things in period 0: Keep its promise and maintain its reputation [produce π 0 = π R ]. No punishment takes place! Cheat in period 0 by producing π C in that period [temptation is present because Ω R (π R ) > Ω C (π R )]. But because he broke his promise, the public punishes the policy maker and expect the discretionary solution next period [π e 1 = π D ]. This involves punishment because Ω D > Ω R (π R ) in period 1. In period 1 the public expects π e 1 = π D and, given this expectation, it is optimal for the policy maker to produce π D. So policy maker has reputation again in period 2 [as it kept its promise in period 1] and the public expects π e 2 = π R. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 18/34

Reputation (3) The benefits of cheating [temptation] are: T(π R ) Ω R (π R ) Ω C (π R ) [ = 1 [ȳ 2 y ] 2 + β β 2 π2 R 1 2 α 2 + β [ȳ y ] αβ ] 2 α 2 + β π R [ α 2 β 2 α 2 + β π R + α ] 2 α 2 + β [y ȳ] The costs of cheating [punishment] are: P(π R ) Ω D Ω R (π R ) 1 + r [ 1 α 2 ] + β = 2 [ȳ y ] 2 1 2 β [ȳ y ] 2 β 1 2 π2 R 1 + r [ 1 α 2 ] = 2 β [ȳ y ] 2 β 1 2 π2 R 1 + r Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 19/34

Reputation (4) In Figure 9.2 we plot these two curves as a function of the rule inflation rate π R. Rule inflation rates between 0 and π R and the ones exceeding π D are such that the policy maker will always deviate from the rule. The temptation is too big. Rule inflation rates between π R and π D are enforceable. The punishment exceeds the temptation and it is not worthwhile to deviate from the rule. Since social welfare depends negatively on inflation, the optimal enforceable inflation rate is the lowest enforceable one, i.e. π R. If the interest rate rises, P(π R ) rotates counter-clockwise and the optimal enforceable inflation rate rises. Punishment more heavily discounted. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 20/34

Figure 9.2: Temptation and enforcement P, T Enforceable region E! EN! P(B R ) 0 P(B R ) 1 T(B R ) T(B R ) B R * B D! B R Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 21/34

Voting and optimal inflation (1) Rogoff (1985) and Alesina & Grilli (1992) ask themselves why central bankers tend to be conservative economists. The median voter model of A & G can be used to cast some light on this issue. Which agent is elected to head the central bank? Person i has the following cost function: Ω i 1 2 [y y ] 2 + β i 2 π2 (S4) Note that β i appears in (S4). The higher is β i the more right wing we call this person. The Lucas supply curve is still given by: y = ȳ + α [π π e ] + ε, α > 0 Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 22/34

Voting and optimal inflation (2) If person i would be the central banker then he/she would set inflation according to: π i D = α β i [y ȳ] y i D = ȳ + β i α 2 + β i ε α α 2 + β i ε Assume that the distribution of β i across the population is as in Figure 9.3. The person with preference parameter β M is the median voter and effectively decides the election. [There is a single issue and preferences are single-peaked, so the median voter theorem holds]. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 23/34

Figure 9.3: The frequency distribution of the inflation aversion parameter Left wing Right wing 50% $ M $ i Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 24/34

Voting and optimal inflation (3) The median voter s cost function is: ( ( Ω M 1 2 E yd i y ) 2 ) ) 2 + βm (π i D 2 = 1 2 E ȳ y + β α 2 + β ε α + β M }{{} β (y ȳ) α α }{{} 2 + β ε }{{} (b) (a) (c) [ ( ) ] 2 = 1 α 2 1 + β M (ȳ y ) 2 + 1 β 2 + β M α 2 β 2 (α 2 + β) 2 σ2 Median voter cannot observe ε but he knows how banker of type β reacts to ε. (a) Output gap a central banker of type β would create. (b) Evaluated from the point of view of the median voter. (c) Inflation a central banker of type β would create. 2 Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 25/34

Voting and optimal inflation (4) The median voter elects central banker such that Ω M is minimized by choice of β. The first-order condition is: dω M dβ = 12β α 2 2 M β 3 (ȳ y ) 2 dω M dβ = β M β 2(α 2 + β) 2 β 2(β 2 + β + 1 M α 2 )(α 2 + β) 2 ( α β (α 2 + β) 4 σ 2 = 0 ) 2 (ȳ y ) 2 + (β β M)α 2 (α 2 + β) 3 σ2 = 0 It follows that the optimal β exceeds β M. The median voter delegates the conduct of monetary policy to someone more conservative than he is himself. This way the median voter commits to a lower inflation rate. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 26/34

Dynamic consistency and capital taxation (1) Dynamic inconsistency can also play a role in fiscal policy. We give the example of capital taxation. Two-period model (t = 1, 2) Household utility: U C1 1/ε 1 1 + 1 1 1/ε 1 1 + ρ [ ] C 2 + α (1 N 2) 1 1/ε 2 + β G1 1/ε3 2 1 1/ε 2 1 1/ε 3 Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 27/34

Dynamic consistency and capital taxation (2) Technology: F(N t, K t ) = an t + bk t Production factors perfect substitutes. Inessential production factors. Constant marginal products. Resource constraints: C 1 + [K 2 K 1 ] = bk 1 C 2 + G 2 = F(N 2, K 2 ) + K 2 = an 2 + (1 + b)k 2 Note that these are expressions like Y = C + I + G. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 28/34

First-best command optimum A benevolent social planner would choose C 1, C 2, N 2, and G 2 such that household utility is maximized subject to the consolidated resource constraint: The solutions are: C 1 + C 2 + G 2 an 2 1 + b C 1 = = (1 + b)k 1 ( ) 1 + b ε1 1 + ρ 1 N 2 = (a/α) ε 2 G 2 = β ε 3 The FBCO can be decentralized [i.e. reproduced in a free market setting] provided the policy maker has access to lump-sum taxes. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 29/34

Second-best optimum (1) What happens if lump-sum tax is not available and only distorting taxes can be used to obtain revenue [needed to pay for the public good]? The GBC becomes: The market solution becomes: ( 1 + b(1 tk ) C 1 = 1 + ρ G 2 = t K bk 2 + t L an 2 ) ε1 C 2 = a(1 t L ) + (1 + b)[1 + b(1 t K )] K 1 (1 + ρ) ε 1 [1 + b(1 t K )] 1 ε 1 α ε 2 [a(1 t L )] 1 ε 2 ( ) a(1 tl ) ε2 1 N 2 = α Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 30/34

Second-best optimum (2) Non-zero t K and/or t L drive the market solution away from the FBCO. We cannot set t L = t K = 0 because that would imply zero G [which is not optimal]. What do we do? We trade off the distortions in the tax system as well as we can by choosing G, t L, and t K such that welfare of the household is maximized given the absence of lump-sum taxes! The optimality conditions are the GBC plus: βg 1/ε 3 2 = η (S5) 1 η = ( ) 1 tl 1 t L ε L (S6) 1 η = ( ) 1 tk 1 t K ε K (S7) Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 31/34

Second-best optimum (3) Continued. η is the marginal cost of public funds [MCPF]. ε L is the uncompensated wage elasticity of labour supply. ε K is the uncompensated interest elasticity of gross saving. Equation (S5) is the modified Samuelson rule. Equations (S6) and (S7) can be solved for the optimal tax rates: ( t L = 1 t L t K 1 t K = 1 1 ) 1 η ε L ( 1 1 ) 1 η ε K (S8) (S9) The intuition is as follows: the objective is to tax in the least distorting fashion by taxing most heavily the most inelastic tax base (e.g. if ε L = 0 then 1/ε L, η = 1, and t K = 0. Labour income source of inelastic tax base in this special case). Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 32/34

Second-best optimum (4) BUT!!! In the general case, with both taxes non-zero, taxing labour in period 2 is not efficient. Once period 2 comes along, K 2 is inelastic and t L = 0 and t K > 0 is optimal. Hence, solutions in (S8) and (S9) are dynamically inconsistent. To find the consistent solution we would have to work backwards. we know that t L = 0 and t K > 0 in period 2. Then we can figure out what t L and t K should be in the first period. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 33/34

Punchlines Dynamic inconsistency is all around us In the context of monetary policy a reputational mechanism can make a rule-based inflation rate enforceable. The median voter can commit to a lower inflation rate by electing a central banker who is more conservative than himself. The optimal taxes on labour and capital suffer from the dynamic inconsistency problem. Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics - Second Edition Chapter 9 34/34