Homework 3 Suggested Answers

Similar documents
Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

1 Theory of the Firm: Topics and Exercises

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly.

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014

CHAPTER 1-2: SHADOW PRICES

Tutorial 3: Optimisation

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1

Midterm Exam - Solutions

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

Introductory Microeconomics

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Queen s University. Department of Economics. Instructor: Kevin Andrew

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm Suggested Solutions 2/8/ (a) The equation of the indifference curve is given by,

Econ 101A Problem Set 1 Solution

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 29 September 2004.

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12

Notes on Consumer Theory

Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, February 21st, 2018

The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

Applications I: consumer theory

E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Preferences and Utility

Problem Set 2 Solutions

Utility Maximization Problem

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Mathematical Foundations II

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics

個體經濟學一. Total utility of consuming (x, y), denoted as u(x, y), is the total level of total satisfaction of consuming(x, y).

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Concave programming. Concave programming is another special case of the general constrained optimization. subject to g(x) 0

= 2 = 1.5. Figure 4.1: WARP violated

The Firm: Optimisation

ECON5110: Microeconomics

Constrained Optimization

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision:

Problem Set 3

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Exercises for Chapter 7

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists Problem set 4: Classical programming

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

The Envelope Theorem

Solutions. F x = 2x 3λ = 0 F y = 2y 5λ = 0. λ = 2x 3 = 2y 5 = x = 3y 5. 2y 1/3 z 1/6 x 1/2 = 5x1/2 z 1/6. 3y 2/3 = 10x1/2 y 1/3

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Midterm Exam

Consumer Theory. Ichiro Obara. October 8, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Consumer Theory October 8, / 51

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Homework #2

Econ Slides from Lecture 14

u(x, y) = x 1 3 y v(p, q, I) = u(x(p, q, I), y(p, q, I))

Constrained optimization.

1 General Equilibrium

Constrained maxima and Lagrangean saddlepoints

Monopolistic Competition Model with Endogeneous Investments: the case of Closed Economy

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

Econ 201: Problem Set 3 Answers

Convex Optimization & Lagrange Duality

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

Mathematical Foundations -1- Supporting hyperplanes. SUPPORTING HYPERPLANES Key Ideas: Bounding hyperplane for a convex set, supporting hyperplane

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

ICS-E4030 Kernel Methods in Machine Learning

8.1. Prot maximization, cost minimization and function cost. December 12, The production function has decreasing returns to scale.

Lecture Notes: Math Refresher 1

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

THE FIRM: OPTIMISATION

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Traditional vs. Correct Transversality Conditions, plus answers to problem set due 1/28/99

Utility Maximization Problem. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 2

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Monotone comparative statics Finite Data and GARP

Microeconomics I. September, c Leopold Sögner

Solutions. ams 11b Study Guide 9 econ 11b

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Adv. Micro Theory, ECON

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

CS-E4830 Kernel Methods in Machine Learning

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

On the (Non-)Differentiability of the Optimal Value Function When the Optimal Solution Is Unique

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2: Demand Theory

Online Supplement to

Econ 508-A FINITE DIMENSIONAL OPTIMIZATION - NECESSARY CONDITIONS. Carmen Astorne-Figari Washington University in St. Louis.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

Transcription:

Homework 3 Suggested Answers Answers from Simon and Blume are on the back of the book. Answers to questions from Dixit s book: 2.1. We are to solve the following budget problem, where α, β, p, q, I are positive and α+β 1 (this assumption is necessary for concavity of the utility function): max x,y 0 {xα y β : px + qy I} The utility function is concave and the constraint function is convex (being linear) so Kuhn-Tucker conditions are necessary and sufficient for a maximum. Given the Lagrangean L(x, y, λ) = x α y β + λ(i px qy), the Kuhn-Tucker conditions are given by x = αxα 1 y β λp 0, x 0, x(αx α 1 y β λp) = 0 (1) y = βxα y β 1 λq 0, y 0, y(βx α y β 1 λq) = 0 (2) = I px qy 0, λ λ 0, λ(i px qy) = 0 (3) Suppose that (x, y, λ ) satisfies the Kuhn-Tucker conditions. If the budget constraint is slack then λ = 0, which implies that marginal utility for both x and y is less than or equal to zero. This is only possible if both x and y equal zero, by the non-negativity constraints. However, since I > 0, there exists a feasible solution (x, y) such that both x and y are positive, yielding a higher utility than zero. This contradicts optimality of (x, y, λ ), therefore the budget constraint must bind. Both x and y must be positive. Indeed, if not then x = 0 or y = 0. (We showed in the previous paragraph that both x and y equal to zero is impossible.) Since both α and β are less than 1, marginal utility is infinity for both goods, so the Kuhn-Tucker conditions are violated (because λp and similarly for λq). Therefore, (x, y, λ ) has both x and y positive. Therefore, the FOC (1), (2) and (3) hold with equality. We must now solve αx α 1 y β = λp (4) βx α y β 1 = λq (5) px + qy = I (6) 1

Dividing (4) by (5) and rearranging, we obtain αx α 1 y β λp = βx α yβ 1 λq = p q αy βx = p q px qy = α β. The last equation says that the optimal expenditure ratio is α/β. Substituting into the budget constraint, we obtain px + qy = I px + px β ( α = I px 1 + β ) α = I px = I 1 + β α x = = αi α + β αi p(α + β) qy = βi α + β y = βi q(α + β) The multiplier λ can be found by plugging x and y into either (4) or (5) [ αx α 1 y β αi = λp α p(α + β) ] α 1 [ Rearranging, we obtain the following solution for λ : ] β βi = λ p q(α + β) λ = αα β β I α+β 1 p α q β (α + β) α+β 2.2. We are to solve the following budget problem: max {α ln(x x 0) + β ln(y y 0 ) : px + qy I} x,y 0 We take as given the constants x 0 and y 0 which we will assume to be positive, as well as the usual α, β, p, q and I, all positive. We assume that α + β = 1. The Lagrangean of this problem is given by: L(x, y, λ) = α ln(x x 0 ) + β ln(y y 0 ) + λ(i px qy) The Kuhn-Tucker FOC are given by: x = y = λ α x x 0 λp 0, x 0, x β y y 0 λq 0, y 0, y ( ) α λp = 0 (7) x x ( 0 ) β λq = 0 (8) y y 0 = I px qy 0, λ 0, λ(i px qy) = 0 (9) 2

The natural logarithm is not defined for non-positive values, so necessarily x > x 0 and y > y 0. Since x 0 and y 0 are both positive and marginal utility is always positive, it follows that all three first-order conditions hold with equality. Hence, we must solve the following system of equations: Dividing (10) by (11) and rearranging, we obtain α = λp x x 0 (10) β = λq y y 0 (11) px + qy = I (12) α(y y 0 ) β(x x 0 ) = λp λq = p q α β = p(x x 0) q(y y 0 ) αq(y y 0 ) = βp(x x 0 ) αqy = βp(x x 0 ) + qy 0 βpx = αq(y y 0 ) + px 0. Plugging this into the budget constraint and using α + β = 1 yields αi = αpx + αqy = αpx + βp(x x 0 ) + qy 0 px = αi + βpx 0 qy 0 qy = βi + αqy 0 px 0. 2.3. We are asked to minimize cost, which in this case amounts to expenditure on inputs, subject to a production constraint. The optimization problem is: The Lagrangean is given by: C(Q) = min K,L 0 {rk + wl : K + L Q} L(x, y, λ) = rk wl + λ( K + L Q) The Kuhn-Tucker conditions are given by K = r + 1 2 λk 1/2 0, K 0, K ( r + 1 2 λk 1/2) = 0 (13) = w + 1 2 λl 1/2 0, L 0, L ( w + 1 2 λl 1/2) = 0 (14) λ = K + L Q 0, λ 0, λ( K + L Q) = 0 (15) Since the objective is concave (being linear) and the constraint function is convex (Q K L 0) any solution to the Kuhn-Tucker conditions solves the 3

optimization. By (15), we must have either K or L or both positive. Therefore, if K is positive, say, then (13) must hold with equality, so λ > 0. If L equals zero then (14) is violated. Similarly, we get a contradiction if K is zero and L is positive. Hence, both K and L must be positive with λ > 0, so all three conditions above hold with equality. We must therefore solve the following three equations: r = 1 2 λk 1/2 (16) w = 1 2 λl 1/2 (17) K + L = Q (18) Dividing (16) by (17), we obtain ( ) 1/2 r w = K 1/2 L L = 1/2 K L ( r ) 2 K =. w Substituting into the production constraint yields ( r K + L = K + K w ) 2 = ( r w + 1 ) K = Q K = [ Q r K = By (16), the Lagrange multiplier is given by λ = 2r K = 2rwQ r + w [ ] 2 wq L = r + w The quantity λ is the marginal cost of production at Q. + 1 w [ rq r + w Now we are given that the price of output equals p, and that output is a choice. The firm s profit-maximization problem is: max {pq rk wl : K + L Q} K,L,Q 0 Since it would not be profit-maximizing to waste inputs, we may assume that the production constraint holds with equality. Then we may write directly the optimization problem as: max {p( K + L) rk wl} K,L 0 ] 2 ] 2 4

This is a concave function of K and L, so FOC are necessary and sufficient for a maximum. The two conditions are: Therefore, 1 2 pk 1/2 = r K = 1 2 pl 1/2 = w L = Q = K + L = p 2r + p 2w = pw 2rw + pr 2rw ( ) 2 2r (19) p ( ) 2 2w (20) p = p(r + w) 2rw. Since the firm takes output prices as given, average revenue or price equals marginal revenue. Optimizing behavior implies that the firm equates marginal revenue with marginal cost, i.e., p = λ p = 2rwQ r + w Q = p(r + w) 2rw. 3.1. Let us first solve the budget problem without a rationing constraint: max {α 1 ln(x 1 ) + α 2 ln(x 2 ) + α 3 ln(x 3 ) : p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 + p 3 x 3 I} x 1,x 2,x 3 0 We are given that α 1 + α 2 + α 3 = 1. The Lagrangean is given by: L(x 1, x 2, x 3, λ) = α 1 ln(x 1 ) + α 2 ln(x 2 ) + α 3 ln(x 3 ) + λ(i p 1 x 1 p 2 x 2 p 3 x 3 ) The utility function is concave, so a Kuhn-Tucker vector is necessary and sufficient for a maximum. By the same arguments as in question 2.1, x i > 0 and λ > 0, so all FOCs hold with equality. Therefore, finding a Kuhn-Tucker point boils down to solving the following equations: α 1 x 1 = λp 1 (21) α 2 x 2 = λp 2 (22) α 3 x 3 = λp 3 (23) p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 + p 3 x 3 = I (24) Equations (21 23) imply that x i = α i /(λ p i ). Substituting this into the budget constraint yields p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 + p 3 x 3 = I 5 α 1 λ + α 2 λ + α 3 λ = I λ = 1/I

Therefore, x i = α i I/p i and p i x i /I = α i. In other words, the consumer s optimal expenditure share of income on good i equals α i. Now consider the rationing problem. The new maximization problem looks like: max {α 1 ln(x 1 ) + α 2 ln(x 2 ) + α 3 ln(x 3 ) : p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 + p 3 x 3 I, x 1 k} x 1,x 2,x 3 0 Clearly, if k α i I/p i then the consumer can purchase his optimal bundle as if the rationing constraint were not there, which must be optimal. On the other hand, if k < α i I/p i then the rationing constraint will bind. Therefore, x 1 = k. (We will use to denote optimal solutions of the rationed problem.) Denote by µ the multiplier on the rationing constraint. The Lagrangean looks like: L = α 1 ln(x 1 ) + α 2 ln(x 2 ) + α 3 ln(x 3 ) + λ(i p 1 x 1 p 2 x 2 p 3 x 3 ) + µ(k x 1 ) By the same arguments as before, all the FOCs will hold with equality, so we are left with solving: α 1 x 1 = λp 1 + µ (25) α 2 x 2 = λp 2 (26) α 3 x 3 = λp 3 (27) p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 + p 3 x 3 = I (28) x 1 = k (29) Substituting the last equation and defining Î = I p 1k implies α 2 x 2 = λp 2 (30) α 3 x 3 = λp 3 (31) p 2 x 2 + p 3 x 3 = Î (32) Dividing (30) by (31) yields α 2 x 3 = p 2 p 2 x 2 = α 2. α 3 x 2 p 3 p 3 x 3 α 3 Therefore, the ratio of expenditure on good 2 relative to good 3 equals α 2 /α 3. Substituting this ratio into (32), we obtain p 2 x 2 + p 3 x 3 = Î α 2 p 3 x 3 + p 3 x 3 = α Î α 2 + α 3 p 3 x 3 = Î 3 6 α 3 p 3 x 3 = α 3Î α 2 + α 3 p 2 x 2 = α 2Î α 2 + α 3

Notice that rationing of good 1 implies that demand for the other goods increases, so goods are substitutes. However, if bread and butter are complements then rationing bread diminishes demand for butter. 3.2. We are to solve the following social planning problem: max{y 1 ky2 2 + y 2 ky1 2 : y 1 + y 2 Y } y 1,y 2 We are given that k > 0. Suppose that Y > 1/k. We must show that the resource constraint is slack at the optimum. The Lagrangean is given by The Kuhn-Tucker conditions are L = y 1 ky 2 2 + y 2 ky 2 1 + λ(y y 1 y 2 ) = 1 2ky 1 λ = 0 y 1 (33) = 1 2ky 2 λ = 0 y 2 (34) λ = Y y 1 y 2 0, λ 0, λ(y y 1 y 2 ) = 0 (35) Notice that λ = 0 together with y 1 = 1/(2k) = y 2 solves the system above. Since the objective is concave this Kuhn-Tucker point solves the problem. The interpretation is that envy implies that eventually the goods become bads, in that more of the good (beyond 1/(2k) destroys value due to envy. 3.3. The optimization problem is: { α j x j 1β 2 jx 2 j : max x 1,...,x n 0 } x j C We assume that α j,, C > 0. The Lagrangean is given by: [ ] L = α j x j 1β 2 jx 2 j + λ C x j The objective is concave, so the Kuhn-Tucker conditions are necessary and sufficient to solve the problem. The Kuhn-Tucker conditions are: j, = α j x j λ 0, x j 0, x j (α j x j λ) = 0 (36) x j [ ] λ = C x j 0, λ 0, λ C x j = 0 (37) i=1 7

Define H = α j /, K = 1/. (i) Suppose that C > H. In this case, notice that by (36), we have that α j x j λ x j (α j λ)/. Letting λ = 0 and x j = α j / satisfies (36) for every j. Furthermore, since C > H, it follows that C j x j > 0, so (37) is satisfied, too. Therefore, this is an optimal solution to the problem. Since j x j < C, a part of the total sum available is left unused. (ii) Suppose that α j > (H C)/K for every j. By the Kuhn-Tucker Theorem, if we find a solution to the Kuhn-Tucker conditions then it will solve the optimization problem. Firstly, notice that x j > 0, since otherwise this would imply that λ = 0 and x j = 0 for every j, which would not be a Kuhn-Tucker solution. If x j > 0 for all j then rearranging (36) and adding with respect to j, we obtain λ = α j x j λ = α j x j λk = H The resource constraint C j x j implies that λ (H C)/K. Let λ = (H C)/K and choose x j so that λ = α j x j. x j. Since α j > (H C)/K for every j, it follows that x j = (α j λ)/ > 0. Finally, x j = α j λ = H (H C)K/K = C. Therefore, (x 1,..., x n, λ ) is a Kuhn-Tucker vector, since it satisfies all the conditions in (36) and (37). (iii) Suppose that project j 0 receives zero funding but j 1 receives some funding. By (36), it follows that α j0 λ and α j1 1 x j1 = λ. Therefore, α j0 = α j1 1 x j1 < α j1, since x j1 > 0. 8