Heteroskedasticity in Time Series

Similar documents
Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

Introduction to ARMA and GARCH processes

Final Exam Financial Data Analysis at the University of Freiburg (Winter Semester 2008/2009) Friday, November 14, 2008,

GARCH Models. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. December Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics / 50

Romanian Economic and Business Review Vol. 3, No. 3 THE EVOLUTION OF SNP PETROM STOCK LIST - STUDY THROUGH AUTOREGRESSIVE MODELS

Prof. Dr. Roland Füss Lecture Series in Applied Econometrics Summer Term Introduction to Time Series Analysis

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO Graduate School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2003, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay

13. Estimation and Extensions in the ARCH model. MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, References for this Lecture:

Symmetric btw positive & negative prior returns. where c is referred to as risk premium, which is expected to be positive.

1 Linear Difference Equations

Week 5 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Characterizing Cycles

Nonstationary Time Series:

Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series

Introduction to Stochastic processes

1 Class Organization. 2 Introduction

Stochastic Processes

Class 1: Stationary Time Series Analysis

in the time series. The relation between y and x is contemporaneous.

Univariate linear models

ECON/FIN 250: Forecasting in Finance and Economics: Section 7: Unit Roots & Dickey-Fuller Tests

1. Fundamental concepts

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Multivariate Time Series: VAR(p) Processes and Models

Financial Time Series Analysis: Part II

Lecture 6a: Unit Root and ARIMA Models

Lecture 6: Univariate Volatility Modelling: ARCH and GARCH Models

Econ 424 Time Series Concepts

Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

ECON3327: Financial Econometrics, Spring 2016

Problem Set 2: Box-Jenkins methodology

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia

6. The econometrics of Financial Markets: Empirical Analysis of Financial Time Series. MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, 2006.

Multivariate GARCH models.

Trend-Cycle Decompositions

TIME SERIES ANALYSIS. Forecasting and Control. Wiley. Fifth Edition GWILYM M. JENKINS GEORGE E. P. BOX GREGORY C. REINSEL GRETA M.

Topic 4 Unit Roots. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

Sample Exam Questions for Econometrics

Chapter 2: Unit Roots

Time Series Econometrics 4 Vijayamohanan Pillai N

Econ 427, Spring Problem Set 3 suggested answers (with minor corrections) Ch 6. Problems and Complements:

Example 2.1: Consider the following daily close-toclose SP500 values [January 3, 2000 to March 27, 2009] SP500 Daily Returns and Index Values

Empirical Market Microstructure Analysis (EMMA)

ECON 616: Lecture 1: Time Series Basics

Econometric Forecasting

Time Series 4. Robert Almgren. Oct. 5, 2009

Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing

Forecasting. Francis X. Diebold University of Pennsylvania. August 11, / 323

Financial Econometrics

GARCH processes probabilistic properties (Part 1)

Univariate Nonstationary Time Series 1

Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing

Econometrics II Heij et al. Chapter 7.1

ECONOMETRIC REVIEWS, 5(1), (1986) MODELING THE PERSISTENCE OF CONDITIONAL VARIANCES: A COMMENT

FORECASTING IN FINANCIAL MARKET USING MARKOV R MARKOV REGIME SWITCHING AND PRINCIPAL COMPONENT ANALYSIS.

Covariance Stationary Time Series. Example: Independent White Noise (IWN(0,σ 2 )) Y t = ε t, ε t iid N(0,σ 2 )

Chapter 4: Models for Stationary Time Series

Cointegration, Stationarity and Error Correction Models.

Nonlinear time series

6.435, System Identification

9) Time series econometrics

Lecture 5: Unit Roots, Cointegration and Error Correction Models The Spurious Regression Problem

Autoregressive and Moving-Average Models

Lecture 2: ARMA(p,q) models (part 2)

Shape of the return probability density function and extreme value statistics

TIME SERIES AND FORECASTING. Luca Gambetti UAB, Barcelona GSE Master in Macroeconomic Policy and Financial Markets

Class: Trend-Cycle Decomposition

Time Series Models for Measuring Market Risk

2. Volatility Models. 2.1 Background. Below are autocorrelations of the log-index.

Time Series Models of Heteroskedasticity

MFE Financial Econometrics 2018 Final Exam Model Solutions

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference

The Slow Convergence of OLS Estimators of α, β and Portfolio. β and Portfolio Weights under Long Memory Stochastic Volatility

Covers Chapter 10-12, some of 16, some of 18 in Wooldridge. Regression Analysis with Time Series Data

Time Series Methods. Sanjaya Desilva

Chapter 9: Forecasting

7. Integrated Processes

Define y t+h t as the forecast of y t+h based on I t known parameters. The forecast error is. Forecasting

The Evolution of Snp Petrom Stock List - Study Through Autoregressive Models

at least 50 and preferably 100 observations should be available to build a proper model

The Size and Power of Four Tests for Detecting Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity in the Presence of Serial Correlation

Univariate Volatility Modeling

Introduction to Economic Time Series

4. MA(2) +drift: y t = µ + ɛ t + θ 1 ɛ t 1 + θ 2 ɛ t 2. Mean: where θ(l) = 1 + θ 1 L + θ 2 L 2. Therefore,

7. Integrated Processes

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we

Lecture 19 - Decomposing a Time Series into its Trend and Cyclical Components

Financial Econometrics and Quantitative Risk Managenent Return Properties

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference

State-space Model. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. November Rossi State-space Model Fin. Econometrics / 53

1. How can you tell if there is serial correlation? 2. AR to model serial correlation. 3. Ignoring serial correlation. 4. GLS. 5. Projects.

13. Time Series Analysis: Asymptotics Weakly Dependent and Random Walk Process. Strict Exogeneity

MGR-815. Notes for the MGR-815 course. 12 June School of Superior Technology. Professor Zbigniew Dziong

1 Time Series Concepts and Challenges

Financial Econometrics

Time Series Analysis -- An Introduction -- AMS 586

Financial Econometrics Using Stata

July 31, 2009 / Ben Kedem Symposium

Stationary Time Series, Conditional Heteroscedasticity, Random Walk, Test for a Unit Root, Endogenity, Causality and IV Estimation

7. Forecasting with ARIMA models

Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing

Transcription:

Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Figure: Time Series of Daily NYSE Returns. 206 / 285

Key Fact 1: Stock Returns are Approximately Serially Uncorrelated Figure: Correlogram of Daily Stock Market Returns. 207 / 285

Key Fact 2: Returns are Unconditionally Non-Gaussian Figure: Histogram and Statistics for Daily NYSE Returns. 208 / 285

Unconditional Volatility Measures Variance: σ 2 = E(r t µ) 2 (or standard deviation: σ) Mean Absolute Deviation: MAD = E r t µ Interquartile Range: IQR = 75% 25% Outlier probability: P r t µ > 5σ (for example) Tail index: γ s.t. P(r t > r) = k r γ Kurtosis: K = E(r µ) 4 /σ 4 p% Value at Risk (VaR p )): x s.t. P(r t < x) = p 209 / 285

Key Fact 3: Returns are Conditionally Heteroskedastic I Figure: Time Series of Daily Squared NYSE Returns 210 / 285

Key Fact 3: Returns are Conditionally Heteroskedastic II Figure: Correlogram of Daily Squared NYSE Returns. 211 / 285

Conditional Return Distributions f (r t ) vs. f (r t Ω t 1 ) Key 1: E(r t Ω t 1 ) Are returns conditional mean independent? Arguably yes. Returns are (arguably) approximately serially uncorrelated, and (arguably) approximately free of additional non-linear conditional mean dependence. 216 / 285

Conditional Return Distributions, Continued Key 2: var(r t Ω t 1 ) = E((r t µ) 2 Ω t 1 ) Are returns conditional variance independent? No way! Squared returns serially correlated, often with very slow decay. 217 / 285

Linear Models (e.g., AR(1)) r t = φr t 1 + ε t ε t iid(0, σ 2 ), φ < 1 Uncond. mean: E(r t ) = 0 (constant) Uncond. variance: E(r 2 t ) = σ 2 /(1 φ 2 ) (constant) Cond. mean: E(r t Ω t 1 ) = φr t 1 (varies) Cond. variance: E([r t E(r t Ω t 1 )] 2 Ω t 1 ) = σ 2 (constant) Conditional mean adapts, but conditional variance does not 218 / 285

ARCH(1) Process r t Ω t 1 N(0, h t ) h t = ω + αr 2 t 1 E(r t ) = 0 E(r 2 ω t ) = (1 α) E(r t Ω t 1 ) = 0 E([r t E(r t Ω t 1 )] 2 Ω t 1 ) = ω + αr 2 t 1 219 / 285

GARCH(1,1) Process ( Generalized ARCH ) r t Ω t 1 N(0, h t ) h t = ω + αr 2 t 1 + βh t 1 E(r t 2 ) = E(r t ) = 0 ω (1 α β) E(r t Ω t 1 ) = 0 E([r t E(r t Ω t 1 )] 2 Ω t 1 ) = ω + αr 2 t 1 + βh t 1 Well-defined and covariance stationary if 0 < α < 1, 0 < β < 1, α + β < 1 220 / 285

GARCH(1,1) and Exponential Smoothing Exponential smoothing recursion: ˆσ 2 t = λˆσ 2 t 1 + (1 λ)r 2 t = ˆσ 2 t = (1 λ) j λ j r 2 t j But in GARCH(1,1) we have: h t = ω + αr 2 t 1 + βh t 1 h t = ω 1 β + α β j 1 r 2 t j 221 / 285

Unified Theoretical Framework Volatility dynamics (of course, by construction) Volatility clustering produces unconditional leptokurtosis Temporal aggregation reduces the leptokurtosis 222 / 285

Tractable Empirical Framework L(θ; r 1,..., r T ) = f (r T Ω T 1 ; θ)f ((r T 1 Ω T 2 ; θ)..., where θ = (ω, α, β) If the conditional densities are Gaussian, f (r t Ω t 1 ; θ) = 1 ( h t (θ) 1/2 exp 1 r 2 ) t, 2π 2 h t (θ) t so ln L = const 1 ln h t (θ) 1 rt 2 2 2 h t (θ) t 223 / 285

Variations on the GARCH Theme Explanatory variables in the variance equation: GARCH-X Fat-tailed conditional densities: t-garch Asymmetric response and the leverage effect: T-GARCH Regression with GARCH disturbances Time-varying risk premia: GARCH-M 224 / 285

Explanatory variables in the Variance Equation: GARCH-X h t = ω + αr 2 t 1 + βh t 1 + γz t where z is a positive explanatory variable 225 / 285

Fat-Tailed Conditional Densities: t-garch If r is conditionally Gaussian, then r t = h t N(0, 1) But often with high-frequency data, r t ht leptokurtic So take: r t = h t t d std(t d ) and treat d as another parameter to be estimated 226 / 285

Asymmetric Response and the Leverage Effect: T-GARCH Standard GARCH: h t = ω + αr 2 t 1 + βh t 1 T-GARCH: h t = ω + αr 2 t 1 + γr 2 t 1 D t 1 + βh t 1 D t = { 1 if rt < 0 0 otherwise positive return (good news): α effect on volatility negative return (bad news): α + γ effect on volatility γ 0: Asymetric news response γ > 0: Leverage effect 227 / 285

Regression with GARCH Disturbances y t = x tβ + ε t ε t Ω t 1 N(0, h t ) 228 / 285

Time-Varying Risk Premia: GARCH-M Standard GARCH regression model: y t = x tβ + ε t ε t Ω t 1 N(0, h t ) GARCH-M model is a special case: y t = x tβ + γh t + ε t ε t Ω t 1 N(0, h t ) 229 / 285

Back to Empirical Work Standard GARCH(1,1) 230 / 285

GARCH(1,1) 231 / 285

GARCH(1,1) 232 / 285

GARCH(1,1) Figure: Estimated Conditional Standard Deviation, Daily NYSE Returns. 233 / 285

GARCH(1,1) Figure: Conditional Standard Deviation, History and Forecast, Daily NYSE Returns. 234 / 285

Fancy GARCH(1,1) 237 / 285

Fancy GARCH(1,1) Dependent Variable: R Method: ML - ARCH (Marquardt) - Student's t distribution Date: 04/10/12 Time: 13:48 Sample (adjusted): 2 3461 Included observations: 3460 after adjustments Convergence achieved after 19 iterations Presample variance: backcast (parameter = 0.7) GARCH = C(4) + C(5)*RESID(-1)^2 + C(6)*RESID(-1)^2*(RESID(-1)<0) + C(7)*GARCH(-1) Variable Coefficient Std. Error z-statistic Prob. @SQRT(GARCH) 0.083360 0.053138 1.568753 0.1167 C 1.28E-05 0.000372 0.034443 0.9725 R(-1) 0.073763 0.017611 4.188535 0.0000 Variance Equation C 1.03E-06 2.23E-07 4.628790 0.0000 RESID(-1)^2 0.014945 0.009765 1.530473 0.1259 RESID(-1)^2*(RESID(- 1)<0) 0.094014 0.014945 6.290700 0.0000 GARCH(-1) 0.922745 0.009129 101.0741 0.0000 T-DIST. DOF 5.531579 0.478432 11.56188 0.0000 238 / 285

Nonstationarity and Random Walks Random walk: y t = y t 1 + ε t ε t iid(0, σ 2 ) Just a simple special case of AR(1) φ = 1 249 / 285

Recall Properties of AR(1) with φ < 1 Shocks ε t have persistent but not permanent effects y t = φ j ε t j (note φ j 0) j=0 Series y t varies but not too extremely var(y t ) = σ2 1 φ 2 (note var(y t ) < ) Autocorrelations ρ(τ) nonzero but decay to zero ρ(τ) = φ τ (note φ τ 0) 251 / 285

Properties of the Random Walk (AR(1) With φ = 1) Shocks have permanent effects t 1 y t = y 0 + j=0 ε t j Series is infinitely variable E(y t ) = y 0 var(y t ) = tσ 2 lim var(y t) = t Autocorrelations ρ(τ) do not decay ρ(τ) 1 (formally not defined) 252 / 285

Random Walk with Drift y t = δ + y t 1 + ε t ε t iid(0, σ 2 ) y t = tδ + y 0 + t i=1 ε i E(y t ) = y 0 + tδ var(y t ) = tσ 2 lim var(y t) = t 250 / 285

Forecasting a Linear Trend + Stationary AR(1) x t = a + bt + y t y t = φy t 1 + ε t ε t WN(0, σ 2 ) Optimal forecast: x T +h,t = a + b(t + h) + φ h y T Forecast reverts to trend 7 / 40

Forecasting a Random Walk with Drift x t = b + x t 1 + ε t ε t WN(0, σ 2 ) Optimal forecast: x T +h,t = bh + x T Forecast does not revert to trend 6 / 40

Stochastic Trend vs. Deterministic Trend 9 / 40

A Key Insight Regarding the Random Walk Level series y t is non-stationary (of course) Differenced series y t is stationary (indeed white noise)! y t = ε t A series is called I (d) if it is non-stationary in levels but is appropriately made stationary by differencing d times. Random walk is the key I (1) process. Other I (1) processes are similar. Why? 253 / 285

The Beveridge-Nelson Decomposition y t I (1) = y t = x t + z t x t = random walk z t = covariance stationary Hence the random walk is the key ingredient for all I (1) processes. The Beveridge-Nelson decomposition implies that shocks to any I (1) process have some permanent effect, as with a random walk. But the effects are not completely permanent, unless the process is a pure random walk. 254 / 285

I (1) Processes and Unit Roots Random walk is an I (1) AR(1) process: y t = y t 1 + ε t (1 L) }{{} y t = ε t deg 1 One (unit) root, L = 1 y t is standard covariance-stationary WN More general I (1) AR(p) process: Φ(L) }{{} y t = ε t deg p [Φ (L) (1 L) }{{}}{{} ]y t = ε t (deg p-1)(deg 1) p 1 stationary roots, one unit root y t is standard covariance stationary AR(p 1) 255 / 285

Some Language... Random walk with drift vs. stat. AR(1) around linear trend unit root vs. stationary root Difference stationary vs. trend stationary Stochastic trend vs. deterministic trend I (1) vs. I (0) 8 / 40