Nowcasting gross domestic product in Japan using professional forecasters information

Similar documents
The Case of Japan. ESRI CEPREMAP Joint Workshop November 13, Bank of Japan

Predicting economic turning points by professional forecasters -Are they useful?

e Yield Spread Puzzle and the Information Content of SPF forecasts

GDP forecast errors Satish Ranchhod

NOWCASTING THE NEW TURKISH GDP

Nowcasting and Short-Term Forecasting of Russia GDP

Assessing recent external forecasts

Research Brief December 2018

Volume 38, Issue 2. Nowcasting the New Turkish GDP

The Superiority of Greenbook Forecasts and the Role of Recessions

GDP growth and inflation forecasting performance of Asian Development Outlook

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014

Euro-indicators Working Group

The Central Bank of Iceland forecasting record

Is the Purchasing Managers Index a Reliable Indicator of GDP Growth?

Error Statistics for the Survey of Professional Forecasters for Industrial Production Index

Error Statistics for the Survey of Professional Forecasters for Treasury Bond Rate (10 Year)

PJM Long-Term Load Forecasting Methodology: Proposal Regarding Economic Forecast (Planning Committee Agenda Item #5)

ARTICLE IN PRESS. Journal of Economics and Business xxx (2016) xxx xxx. Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Journal of Economics and Business

Error Statistics for the Survey of Professional Forecasters for Treasury Bill Rate (Three Month)

WORKING PAPER NO DO GDP FORECASTS RESPOND EFFICIENTLY TO CHANGES IN INTEREST RATES?

Nowcasting GDP with Real-time Datasets: An ECM-MIDAS Approach

ESRI Research Note Nowcasting and the Need for Timely Estimates of Movements in Irish Output

Periklis. Gogas. Tel: +27. Working May 2017

NOWCASTING GDP IN GREECE: A NOTE ON FORECASTING IMPROVEMENTS FROM THE USE OF BRIDGE MODELS

A NEW APPROACH FOR EVALUATING ECONOMIC FORECASTS

Random Matrix Theory and the Failure of Macro-economic Forecasts

THE DATA ON MOST ECONOMIC VARIABLES ARE ESTIMATES. THESE ESTIMATES ARE REVISED, Data Vintages and Measuring Forecast Model Performance

A Comparison of Business Cycle Regime Nowcasting Performance between Real-time and Revised Data. By Arabinda Basistha (West Virginia University)

Testing for Regime Switching in Singaporean Business Cycles

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

S ince 1980, there has been a substantial

How Useful Are Forecasts of Corporate Profits?

WORKING PAPER NO THE CONTINUING POWER OF THE YIELD SPREAD IN FORECASTING RECESSIONS

On inflation expectations in the NKPC model

Are Forecast Updates Progressive?

03/RT/11 Real-Time Nowcasting of GDP: Factor Model versus Professional Forecasters

Are Forecast Updates Progressive?

The Blue Chip Survey: Moving Beyond the Consensus

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract

Forecasting the term structure interest rate of government bond yields

Stellenbosch Economic Working Papers: 23/13 NOVEMBER 2013

WORKING PAPER N FORECASTING WITH A REAL-TIME DATA SET FOR MACROECONOMISTS

An Empirical Study of Forecast Combination in Tourism

Seasonality in macroeconomic prediction errors. An examination of private forecasters in Chile

Business Cycle Dating Committee of the Centre for Economic Policy Research. 1. The CEPR Business Cycle Dating Committee

Comment on: Automated Short-Run Economic Forecast (ASEF) By Nicolas Stoffels. Bank of Canada Workshop October 25-26, 2007

Nowcasting New Zealand GDP Using Machine Learning Algorithms

Forecast performance in times of terrorism

Are 'unbiased' forecasts really unbiased? Another look at the Fed forecasts 1

Empirical Approach to Modelling and Forecasting Inflation in Ghana

14 03R. Nowcasting U.S. Headline and Core Inflation. Edward S. Knotek II and Saeed Zaman FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

What Do Professional Forecasters Actually Predict?

Lucrezia Reichlin London Business School & Now-Casting Economics Ltd and Silvia Miranda Agrippino, Now-Casting Economics Ltd

No Staff Memo. Evaluating real-time forecasts from Norges Bank s system for averaging models. Anne Sofie Jore, Norges Bank Monetary Policy

Combining expert forecasts: Can anything beat the simple average? 1

UPPSALA UNIVERSITY - DEPARTMENT OF STATISTICS MIDAS. Forecasting quarterly GDP using higherfrequency

General comments Linear vs Non-Linear Univariate vs Multivariate

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007

The Measurement and Characteristics of Professional Forecasters Uncertainty. Kenneth F. Wallis. Joint work with Gianna Boero and Jeremy Smith

A Horse-Race Contest of Selected Economic Indicators & Their Potential Prediction Abilities on GDP

This time it is different! Or not? Discounting past data when predicting the future

A New Approach to Rank Forecasters in an Unbalanced Panel

Lecture 2. Business Cycle Measurement. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD II Semestre 2017 Last updated: August 18, 2017

FaMIDAS: A Mixed Frequency Factor Model with MIDAS structure

How Well Are Recessions and Recoveries Forecast? Prakash Loungani, Herman Stekler and Natalia Tamirisa

Economics 390 Economic Forecasting

PREDICTIONS AGGREGATION BY COUNTRY TO IMPROVE THE ACCURACY OF EUROPEAN UNION GDP RATE FORECASTS? Mihaela Simionescu *

Nowcasting Norwegian GDP

Selecting a Nonlinear Time Series Model using Weighted Tests of Equal Forecast Accuracy

Gorge Area Demand Forecast. Prepared for: Green Mountain Power Corporation 163 Acorn Lane Colchester, Vermont Prepared by:

Do we need Experts for Time Series Forecasting?

NOWCASTING THE OBAMA VOTE: PROXY MODELS FOR 2012

The Making Of A Great Contraction. With A Liquidity Trap And A Jobless Recovery. Columbia University

Introduction to Modern Time Series Analysis

Introduction to Econometrics

Has the crisis changed the monetary transmission mechanism in Albania? An application of kernel density estimation technique.

Approximating fixed-horizon forecasts using fixed-event forecasts

Testing an Autoregressive Structure in Binary Time Series Models

Analyzing the Spillover effect of Housing Prices

Evaluating USDA Forecasts of Farm Assets: Ted Covey & Ken Erickson

Oil-Price Density Forecasts of U.S. GDP

Mixed frequency models with MA components

U n iversity o f H ei delberg

Short-term forecasts of GDP from dynamic factor models

NOWCASTING REPORT. Updated: September 7, 2018

Forecasting in a Mixed Up World: Nowcasting Hawaii Tourism

Approximating Fixed-Horizon Forecasts Using Fixed-Event Forecasts

EXAMINATION OF RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN TIME SERIES BY WAVELETS: ILLUSTRATION WITH CZECH STOCK AND INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION DATA

Time-Varying Comovement of Foreign Exchange Markets

Nowcasting the Finnish economy with a large Bayesian vector autoregressive model

NOWCASTING REPORT. Updated: September 14, 2018

Advances in Economic Forecasting

THE ACCURACY OF PROPERTY FORECASTING

Estimating Macroeconomic Uncertainty Using Information. Measures from SPF Density Forecasts

Charting Employment Loss in North Carolina Textiles 1

Nowcasting GDP in Real-Time: A Density Combination Approach

Can a subset of forecasters beat the simple average in the SPF?

Volume 30, Issue 1. A Short Note on the Nowcasting and the Forecasting of Euro-area GDP Using Non-Parametric Techniques

Forecasting. Bernt Arne Ødegaard. 16 August 2018

Transcription:

Kanagawa University Economic Society Discussion Paper No. 2017-4 Nowcasting gross domestic product in Japan using professional forecasters information Nobuo Iizuka March 9, 2018

Nowcasting gross domestic product in Japan using professional forecasters information Nobuo Iizuka March 2018 Abstract This study proposes a new framework for nowcasting, the prediction of the present, the very near future, and the very recent past. Most previous research use a dynamic factor model (DFM) and insist that it is the best method for nowcasting. However, the DFM takes considerable time and effort and for Japanese GDP, the forecast result with DFM is not necessarily good (Bragoli, 2017). We use professional forecasters information instead. In this study, we combine professional forecasters information with single-equation approaches, such as bridge equations (BEQ) and mixeddata sampling (MIDAS) regressions. We use cross-sectional disagreement among forecasters in the ESP forecast survey, which is the first monthly survey of macroeconomic forecasts conducted by professional forecasters in Japan. Key Words: Nowcasting; Forecast disagreement; JEL Classification: C13; C32; E32; E37. 1 Introduction Gross domestic product (GDP) is a key indicator for decision makers in governments, central banks, financial markets, and non-financial firms. However, GDP is available only on a quarterly basis, and is subject to substantial publication lags. In Japan, the first Quarterly Estimate (QE) of GDP is released approximately one and half months after the end of the reference quarter. Thus, many prior studies propose several methods to nowcast GDP and find that the dynamic factor model (DFM) is the best method. For example, Jansen et al..(2016) conduct a systematic comparison of the short-term This research is supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Number 26380332. Faculty of Economics, Kanagawa University, 3-27-1 Rokkakubashi, Kanagawa-ku, YOKOHAMA, 221-8686, JAPAN, E-mail: nobuo-iizuka-0915@kanagawa-u.ac.jp 1

forecasting abilities of twelve statistical models and find the DFM is the best model overall. Bragoli (2017) is the latest study to use the DFM to nowcast GDP in Japan in its proposal of a formal statistical framework to monitor current economic conditions in Japan in real time. Using around 30 variables, they apply the DFM and compare the results with the AR1 model forecasts. However, their results are not necessarily good. In the fully real-time setting, their results do not differ from those of the AR1 model. Urasawa (2014) was the first to nowcast GDP in Japan using the DFM, finding that the forecast performance does not necessary improve when increasing the number of variables. Hara and Yamane (2013) find that the Index of Industrial Production (IIP) and the Index of Tertiary Industries Activity (ITA) can explain a large part of the variation in GDP growth. On the other hand, Jansen et al.. (2016) find that forecasts by professional forecasters tend to perform better during periods of crisis. Legerstee and Franses (2015) examine the predictive power of disagreement among forecasters. As many prior studies insist, forecasters have asymmetric and different loss functions; they update their forecasts in different ways and particular information might cause disagreement among forecasters. Zarnowitz and Lambros (1987) show a positive correlation between disagreement among forecasters and uncertainty, which is a lack of confidence. Thus, we expect that disagreement among forecasters to increase, especially in a recessionary phase when forecast error increases. In this study, we combine professional forecasters information with singleequation approaches, such as bridge equations (BEQ) and mixed-data sampling (MIDAS) regressions. We use cross-sectional disagreement among forecasters in the ESP forecast (ESPF) survey, which is the first monthly survey of macroeconomic forecasts conducted by professional forecasters in Japan 1. The remainder of the paper proceeds in three sections. Section 2 explains the data, base model, and its performance. Section 3 examines the combination of professional forecasters information with base model. Section 4 provides the interpretation and conclusion. 2 Data and base model 2.1 Data set Following Hara and Yamane (2013), we use IIP and ITA to build the base model for forecasting GDP growth. Although Hara and Yamane (2013) use historical data, we use real-time data to compare our results with those in 1 ESP represents Economy, Society, and Policy, published by the public relations magazine of the Cabinet Office, and does not stand for extrasensory perception(komine et al., 2009) 2

Bragoli (2017). We use the first QE as the actual to compare with the forecast. We collect professional forecasters information from the ESPF survey data set compiled by the Japan Center for Economic Research (JCER) 2. The ESPF survey is the first monthly survey of macroeconomic forecasts conducted by professional forecasters in Japan. We can also obtain monthly forecasts for Japan through Consensus Economics, the world s leading international economic survey organization, which is older than the ESPF. However, in Japan, the ESPF panel has twice the number of participants as the Consensus Economics panel does. Each month since April 2004, the ESPF survey polls professional forecasters from private economic institutions in Japan for their predictions about the main macroeconomic indicators. Neither the Bank of Japan (BOJ) nor the Japanese government participates in the survey. The ESPF requests respondents to provide annual and quarterly forecasts at the beginning of each month. Approximately 40 participants respond every month. Our sample ranges from April 2004 to March 2017 and consists of 156 monthly observations. In our sample, we have 58 respondents, 25 of whom participated in 90 percent of the survey. 2.2 Base model This section outlines our method of nowcasting the first QE. We suppose that nowcasting and backcasting are conducted at the top of the month because the ESPF requests respondents to provide annual and quarterly forecasts at that time. We use the BEQ to nowcast GDP 3. We estimate the quarterly relationship between GDP, the IIP, and the ITA using four kinds of regression: d log(gdp t ) = α 1 + β 1 d log(iip t ) + ϵ 1t (1) d log(gdp t ) = α 2 + β 2 d log(iip t ) + γ 2 d log(it A t ) + ϵ 2t (2) d log(gdp t ) = α 3 + β 3 d log(iip t ) + δ 3 d log(gdp t 1 ) + ϵ 3t (3) d log(gdp t ) = α 4 + β 4 d log(iip t ) + γ 4 d log(it A t ) +δ 4 d log(gdp t 1 ) + ϵ 4t (4) We forecast monthly IIP and ITA if necessary using the ARIMA model. Table 1 summarizes the timing of nowcasting and backcasting, as well as the information available. In the first and second months of nowcasting, we have to make twoquarter ahead forecasts. The actual GDP one quarter before the reference 2 The ESPF was conducted by the Association for Economic Planning since April 2004, and was taken over by the JCER from April 2012 3 We also adopt a MIDAS regression; however, it provided worse results than the BEQ did. 3

Table 1: Information available for forecasting (example for Q3) GDP IIP ITA Nowcast Month1 Q1(2nd) May April Month2 Q1(2nd) June May Month3 Q2(1st) July June Backcast Month1 Q2(2nd) August July Month2 Q2(2nd) September August Table 2: Base model estimation results (1) (2) (3) (4) C 0.00* 0.00* 0.00** 0.00** IIP 0.23*** 0.18*** 0.24*** 0.18*** ITA 0.47*** 0.53*** rgdp(-1) -0.13-0.18** Adj-R 0.75 0.81 0.76 0.83 AIC -7.32-7.54-7.34-7.67 SIC -7.24-7.42-7.22-7.50 Notes: Estimation period:2006q1-2016q4. The null hypothesis of the parameter equal to zero is rejected at the 10% (*), 5%(**), and 1% (***) significance levels. quarter is not available. We also have to forecast monthly IIP and ITA 4 to 5 months ahead. In the third month of nowcasting, we can obtain the actual GDP one quarter before the reference quarter. In the second month of nowcasting, we can obtain the actual IIP one quarter before the reference quarter, but we must make a one-month ahead forecast for ITA. 2.3 Base model results Table 2 presents the estimation results for the real-time GDP forecast using the four base models. The observation period is 2004Q4, the start of the chain-based first QE, to 2016Q4. We do a rolling estimation using 10 years (40 quarters) of realtime data. We estimated the results in Table 2 using data from 2006Q1 to 2016Q4. The adjusted R 2 of around 0.8 in Table 2 indicate that these models can explain a large part of the variation in GDP growth. On the other hand, a lag in GDP improves the performance very little. This is in line with the performance of the AR1 model, which as an adjusted R 2 of around 0. 4

Table 3: Real-time GDP forecast results(1) Base Model AR1 (1) (2) (3) (4) ESP Evaluation period: 2004Q4-2016Q4 Nowcast Month1 1.17 1.59 1.77 1.59 1.80 0.80 Month2 1.17 0.92 0.92 0.92 0.92 0.73* Month3 1.10 0.96 1.05 0.99 1.06 0.67* Backcast Month1 1.12 0.74* 0.80 0.75* 0.83 0.52** Month2 1.12 0.50** 0.50** 0.51** 0.53** 0.29*** Excluding: 2008Q2-2009Q1 Nowcast Month1 0.87 2.09 2.36 2.09 2.41 0.71 Month2 0.87 1.15 1.16 1.16 1.16 0.71 Month3 0.91 0.90 0.94 0.94 0.96 0.64 Backcast Month1 0.92 0.67 0.65 0.68 0.69 0.54* Month2 0.92 0.50** 0.46** 0.51** 0.50** 0.36** Notes: For AR1, the entries refer to the RMSE; for all other models, they refer to the RMSE relative to the AR1 model s RMSE. The null hypothesis of no difference is rejected at the 10% (*), 5%(**), and 1% (***) significance levels. Table 3 shows the result of the real-time GDP forecast with an evaluation period from 2004Q4 to 2016Q4. Of all the nowcasts and backcasts, the ESPF provides the best forecast. All relative Root Mean Squared Error (RMSE) values compared to the AR1 model s RMSE are below one. Using the Diebold and Mariano (2002) test of equal predictive accuracy, the forecasting performance between the AR1 model and ESPF is significant, except in the first month s nowcast. Excluding 2008Q2 to 2009Q1, when the economic downturn occurred after the financial crises, the ESPF performs significantly better only for the backcast. This is in line with Jansen s et al.. (2016) finding that professional forecasters tend to perform better during periods of crisis. Among the four models, those without the lag of GDP, models (1) and (2), tend to perform better. Although the adjusted R 2 of model (2) is better than that for model (1), these two models have similar performance because we must forecast monthly ITA, even in the second month s backcast. Hereafter, we use the real-time forecast result for model (2) because it contains more information. Using the Diebold and Mariano (2002) test of equal predictive accuracy, the forecasting performance difference between the real-time forecast results of model (2) and ESPF is not significant. 5

3 Combination of professional forecasters information with the base model 3.1 Forecast averaging In this section, we examine two methods to combine professional forecasters information with model forecasting: forecast averaging and a single-equation approach with professional forecasters information. Most prior studies show that forecast averaging improves performance. There is room to improve the performance if we average the real-time forecast results of model (2) and the ESPF because the difference between the two is not significant. Following Stock and Watson (2001), we use the weight w calculated by equation (5) to average the real-time forecast result of model (2) and the ESPF. w ESP F + (1 w) model(2)forecast is the averaged forecast. w = 1/ABSF E espf 1/ABSF E espf + 1/ABSF E model, (5) where ABSF E espf is the absolute forecast error of the ESPF and ABSF E model is the absolute forecast error of the real-time forecast result of model(2). Figure 1 shows the ex-ante variation of w in the second month backcast. Figure 2 shows the trend in disagreement among professional forecasters. The shaded areas indicate recessionary phases determined by the Japanese government. Disagreement becomes larger, especially from 2008Q2 to 2009Q1, when the economic downturn occurred after the financial crises. Disagreement also increased in 2011Q2 immediately after the Great East Japan Earthquake and in 2014Q2 when the consumption tax rate was raised from 5 percent to 8 percent. We have to forecast w because we cannot know the ABSFE before the actual data are released. Stock and Watson (2001) propose using the past mean squared error of each forecast instead the ABSFE in equation (5). Here, we propose forecasting w using the disagreement between forecasters in the ESPF. We use the root mean squared deviation among individual forecasts as a measure of forecast disagreement. As many prior studies show, disagreement increases when uncertainty in the Japanese economy also increases. Table 4 shows the estimation results. In the backcast, the parameter of disagreement is positive and significant. This means that the weight for ESPF increases as disagreement increases. The disagreement tends to become larger when the economy is in a recession phase. This is in line with Jansen s et al.(2016) finding that forecasts by professional forecasters tend to perform better during periods of crisis. 6

Figure 1: Ex-ante variation of w in the second month backcast 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 Quarterly Figure 2: Trend in disagreement among professional forecasters.9.8.7.6.5.4.3.2.1.0 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 Quarterly BACKCAST_2 BACKCAST_1 NOWCAST_3 NOWCAST_2 NOWCAST_1 7

Table 4: Forecast combination estimation results (1) C Disag Adj-R AIC SIC Nowcast Month1 0.45*** 0.30 0.00-0.29-0.21 Month2 0.59*** -0.24 0.00-0.04 0.04 Month3 0.40*** 0.40 0.02-0.20-0.13 Backcast Month1 0.43*** 0.26* 0.00-0.01 0.07 Month2 0.37*** 0.82*** 0.14-0.20-0.12 Notes: Estimation period: 2004Q4-2016Q4. The null hypothesis of the parameter equal to zero is rejected at the 10% (*), 5%(**), and 1% (***) significance levels. Table 5: Forecast combination estimation results (2) C ModelF Disag Adj-R AIC SIC Nowcast Month1 0.49 0.00-1.32-0.03 3.04 3.15 Month2 0.67** 0.34** -1.94 0.24 2.74 2.85 Month3 0.02 0.46*** 0.22 0.42 2.48 2.59 Backcast Month1 0.74** 0.44*** -2.41* 0.64 1.98 2.10 Month2 0.44* 0.70*** -1.43 0.79 1.47 1.58 Notes: Estimation period: 2004Q4-2016Q4. The null hypothesis of the parameter equal to zero is rejected at the 10% (*), 5%(**), and 1% (***) significance levels. 8

3.2 Single-equation approach with professional forecasters information The second approach is to estimate equation (6) to forecast GDP growth. dlog(gdp t ) = α 5 + β 5 model(2)forecast t + γ 5 disagreement t + ϵ t (6) Disagreement tends to increase, and forecasts using a single-equation approach tend to be optimistic when the economy is in a contraction. We expect a negative value for the parameter γ 5. Table 5 reports the estimation results. Although most of the γ 5 values are negative, is significant only in the first month s backcast. In the first month backcast, we have to forecast the one-month ahead IIP and two-month ahead ITA, so there is room to improve forecast performance using disagreement. 3.3 Forecast comparisons Using the estimation results, we create two types of combination forecasts and report the results in Table 6. Combi(1) refers to the forecast average and combi(2) refers to the Single-equation approach with professional forecasters information. We use the Mean Absolute Forecast Error (MAE) and Mean Absolute Forecast Percentage Error (MAPE) besides the RMSE to evaluate the forecasts. If we evaluate the full sample (2004Q4-2016Q4), the ESPF offers the best performance in most cases. However, excluding 2008Q2 to 2009Q1, when the economic downturn occurred, Combi(1) performs better than the ESPF in the backcast. This means that averaging the ESPF and model forecasts improve forecast performance under normal economic circumstances. On the other hand, the Combi(2) model has notably better than Model(2) does in nowcasting; thus, it is possible to improve the performance of the singleequation forecast using disagreement among forecasters. 4 Interpretation and conclusion In this paper, we propose a new framework for nowcasting. We examine two types of combinations of professional forecasters information with model forecasting: forecast averaging and a single-equation approach with professional forecasters information. In the backcast, averaging the ESPF and single-equation approach forecast using the weight estimated by disagreement among forecasters can improve performance. In the nowcast, disagreement among forecasters improves the performance of single-equation forecasts. As Legerstee and Franses (2015) state, forecast disagreement is useful for forecasting because it becomes larger during recessions. In addition, 9

Table 6: Real-time GDP forecast results (2) RMSE MAE MAPE Nowcast Month1 ESP 0.936 0.626 116.546 Model(2) 2.069 0.877 130.741 Combi(1) 1.244 0.695 106.506 Combi(2) 0.968 0.684 104.830 Nowcast Month2 ESP 0.855 0.592 110.399 Model(2) 1.080 0.676 131.003 Combi(1) 0.858 0.598 115.572 Combi(2) 0.832 0.616 117.526 Nowcast Month3 ESP 0.733 0.540 106.557 Model(2) 1.154 0.693 127.117 Combi(1) 0.752 0.534 107.425 Combi(2) 0.796 0.555 94.139 Backcast Month1 ESP 0.577 0.447 87.507 Model(2) 0.894 0.544 114.606 Combi(1) 0.580 0.441 96.726 Combi(2) 0.618 0.480 113.857 Backcast Month2 ESP 0.323 0.257 66.435 Model(2) 0.561 0.400 83.710 Combi(1) 0.322 0.270 67.197 Combi(2) 0.474 0.382 92.266 Notes: Evaluation period: 2004Q4-2016Q4. best model among all models. Figures in bold indicate the 10

Table 7: Real-time GDP forecast results(3) RMSE MAE MAPE Nowcast Month1 ESP 0.615 0.497 112.598 Model(2) 2.047 0.790 129.728 Combi(1) 1.071 0.580 102.419 Combi(2) 0.711 0.573 100.747 Nowcast Month2 ESP 0.612 0.486 106.801 Model(2) 1.004 0.634 133.724 Combi(1) 0.724 0.534 114.863 Combi(2) 0.692 0.540 114.058 Nowcast Month3 ESP 0.582 0.470 102.812 Model(2) 0.857 0.564 122.654 Combi(1) 0.641 0.482 103.823 Combi(2) 0.667 0.509 90.870 Backcast Month1 ESP 0.497 0.406 84.591 Model(2) 0.597 0.436 116.164 Combi(1) 0.488 0.392 95.469 Combi(2) 0.556 0.444 112.874 Backcast Month2 ESP 0.330 0.263 69.486 Model(2) 0.421 0.339 81.862 Combi(1) 0.317 0.263 68.034 Combi(2) 0.413 0.343 89.680 Notes: Evaluation period: 2004Q4-2016Q4, excluding 2008Q2-2009Q1. Figures in bold indicate the best model among all models. 11

the method outperforms Bragoli s (2017) DFM. Nowcasting with singleequation forecasts using forecasters information is practical because it is easy to implement. References [1] Bragoli, D. (2017). Now-casting the Japanese economy. International Journal of Forecasting, 33(2), 390-402. [2] Hara, N and Yamane, S. (2013). New monthly estimation approach for Nowcasting GDP growth: The case of Japan. Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, 13-E-14. [3] Jansen, W. J., Jin, X and de Winter, J.M. (2016). Forecasting and nowcasting real GDP: Comparing statistical models and subjective forecasts. International Journal of Forecasting, 32(2), 411-436. [4] Komine, T., Ban, K., Kawagoe, M. and Yoshida, H. (2009). What have we learned from a survey of Japanese professional forecasters? Taking stock of four years of ESP forecast experience. ESRI Discussion Paper Series, 214, 1-26. [5] Legerstee, R. and Franses, H. P. (2015). Does disagreement amongst forecasters have predictive value? Journal of Forecasting, 34(4), 290-302. [6] Stock, J. H., Watson, M. (2001). A comparison of linear and nonlinear univariate models for forecasting macroeconomic time series. In: Engle, R.F., White, H (Eds.), Festschrift in Honour of Clive Granger, 1-44. [7] Urasawa, S. (2014). Real-time GDP forecasting for Japan: A dynamic factor model approach. Journal of The Japanese and International Economies, 34, 116-134. [8] Zarnowitz, V. and Lambros, L. A.(1987) Consensus and uncertainty in economic prediction. Journal of Political Economy, 95(3),591-621. 12