Robust Markowitz portfolio selection. ambiguous covariance matrix

Similar documents
HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover

Weak solutions of mean-field stochastic differential equations

On continuous time contract theory

Strong Solutions and a Bismut-Elworthy-Li Formula for Mean-F. Formula for Mean-Field SDE s with Irregular Drift

The Robust Merton Problem of an Ambiguity Averse Investor

Random G -Expectations

Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem

Robust control and applications in economic theory

LECTURES ON MEAN FIELD GAMES: II. CALCULUS OVER WASSERSTEIN SPACE, CONTROL OF MCKEAN-VLASOV DYNAMICS, AND THE MASTER EQUATION

Perturbative Approaches for Robust Intertemporal Optimal Portfolio Selection

Key words. Ambiguous correlation, G-Brownian motion, Hamilton Jacobi Bellman Isaacs equation, Stochastic volatility

Control of McKean-Vlasov Dynamics versus Mean Field Games

Ambiguity and Information Processing in a Model of Intermediary Asset Pricing

Mean-Field Games with non-convex Hamiltonian

Mean-Field optimization problems and non-anticipative optimal transport. Beatrice Acciaio

Multilevel Monte Carlo for Stochastic McKean-Vlasov Equations

Robust Optimization: Applications in Portfolio Selection Problems

Utility Maximization in Hidden Regime-Switching Markets with Default Risk

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models

Research Article Optimal Portfolio Estimation for Dependent Financial Returns with Generalized Empirical Likelihood

Robust Efficient Frontier Analysis with a Separable Uncertainty Model

Multi-dimensional Stochastic Singular Control Via Dynkin Game and Dirichlet Form

Robust Growth-Optimal Portfolios

Bernardo D Auria Stochastic Processes /12. Notes. March 29 th, 2012

Shadow prices and well-posedness in the problem of optimal investment and consumption with transaction costs

Consumption. Consider a consumer with utility. v(c τ )e ρ(τ t) dτ.

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems

Stochastic optimal control with rough paths

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009

Homogenization with stochastic differential equations

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Optimal Trade Execution with Instantaneous Price Impact and Stochastic Resilience

Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation

Optimal transportation and optimal control in a finite horizon framework

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting

Markowitz Efficient Portfolio Frontier as Least-Norm Analytic Solution to Underdetermined Equations

Singular Perturbations of Stochastic Control Problems with Unbounded Fast Variables

Aggregate Risk. MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management. John Dodson. February 6, Aggregate Risk. John Dodson.

Theoretical Tutorial Session 2

Minimal Supersolutions of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Robust Hedging

minimize x subject to (x 2)(x 4) u,

Optimal portfolio strategies under partial information with expert opinions

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets 17: Fortune s Formulas

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. January 25, 2012

On a class of stochastic differential equations in a financial network model

LAN property for ergodic jump-diffusion processes with discrete observations

Conjugate duality in stochastic optimization

General approach to the optimal portfolio risk management

A problem of portfolio/consumption choice in a. liquidity risk model with random trading times

Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem

Controlled Diffusions and Hamilton-Jacobi Bellman Equations

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 18 Oct 2016

Bernardo D Auria Stochastic Processes /10. Notes. Abril 13 th, 2010

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University

Distributionally Robust Stochastic Optimization with Wasserstein Distance

Chance Constrained Programming

Interest Rate Models:

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

An Uncertain Control Model with Application to. Production-Inventory System

Portfolio Allocation using High Frequency Data. Jianqing Fan

Semidefinite and Second Order Cone Programming Seminar Fall 2012 Project: Robust Optimization and its Application of Robust Portfolio Optimization

On Consistent Decision Making. and the Theory of Continuous-Time. Recursive Utility

Mean-field SDE driven by a fractional BM. A related stochastic control problem

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan)

Better than Dynamic Mean-Variance Policy in Market with ALL Risky Assets

Some Terminology and Concepts that We will Use, But Not Emphasize (Section 6.2)

A SECOND ORDER STOCHASTIC DOMINANCE PORTFOLIO EFFICIENCY MEASURE

Time-Consistent Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection in Discrete and Continuous Time

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations

Some aspects of the mean-field stochastic target problem

Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time

Asymptotic Perron Method for Stochastic Games and Control

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

Mean-Field optimization problems and non-anticipative optimal transport. Beatrice Acciaio

Nonparametric Drift Estimation for Stochastic Differential Equations

Long time behavior of Mean Field Games

LAN property for sde s with additive fractional noise and continuous time observation

Ambiguity in portfolio optimization

Lecture 6: Recursive Preferences

Optimization Problems with Probabilistic Constraints

Stochastic Integration and Stochastic Differential Equations: a gentle introduction

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 5 Mar 2013

of space-time diffusions

Financial Asset Price Bubbles under Model Uncertainty

The concentration of a drug in blood. Exponential decay. Different realizations. Exponential decay with noise. dc(t) dt.

A Minimax Theorem with Applications to Machine Learning, Signal Processing, and Finance

Sharp bounds on the VaR for sums of dependent risks

MEAN FIELD GAMES WITH MAJOR AND MINOR PLAYERS

Systemic Risk and Stochastic Games with Delay

Convex Stochastic Control and Conjugate Duality in a Problem of Unconstrained Utility Maximization Under a Regime Switching Model

Econ 2148, spring 2019 Statistical decision theory

Mathematical Methods for Neurosciences. ENS - Master MVA Paris 6 - Master Maths-Bio ( )

Translation invariant and positive homogeneous risk measures and portfolio management. Zinoviy Landsman Department of Statistics, University of Haifa

Additional information and pricing-hedging duality in robust framework

Transcription:

under ambiguous covariance matrix University Paris Diderot, LPMA Sorbonne Paris Cité Based on joint work with A. Ismail, Natixis MFO March 2, 2017

Outline Introduction 1 Introduction 2 3 and Sharpe ratio

Classical Markowitz formulation in continuous time X α = (X α t ) t wealth process with α = (α t ) : amount invested in risky assets at any time t [0, T ], T < investment horizon Markowitz criterion : on (Ω, F, P) maximize over α : E[X α T ] subject to Var(X α T ) ϑ U 0 (ϑ) : maximal expected return given risk ϑ > 0 Lagrangian mean-variance criterion : Graph of U 0 : Efficient frontier V 0 (λ) minimize over α : λvar(x α T ) E[X α T ], Duality relation : { V0 (λ) = inf ϑ>0 [ λϑ U0 (ϑ) ], λ > 0, U 0 (ϑ) = inf λ>0 [ λϑ V0 (λ) ], ϑ > 0.

Optimal MV portfolio in BS model Multidimensional BS model : risk-free asset 1, d stocks with b R d : vector of assets return Σ S d >+ : covariance matrix of assets Optimal amount invested in the d stocks : ( αt = E[Xt ] Xt + 1 t)) 2λ er(t Σ 1 b ( = x 0 + 1 ) 2λ ert Xt Σ 1 b, 0 t T. R := b Σ 1 b R : (square) of risk premium of the d stocks e RT 1 ϑ λ = λ(ϑ) =. 4ϑ Efficient frontier : straight line in mean/standard deviation diagram U 0(ϑ) = x 0 + e RT 1 ϑ, ϑ > 0. Ref : Zhou, Li (00), Andersson-Djehiche (11), Fisher-Livieri (16), P., Wei (16).

Robust portfolio optimization Inacurracy in parameters estimation : Drift : well-known Correlation : asynchronous data and lead-lag effect Portfolio optimization with Knightian uncertainty (ambiguity) on model set of prior subjective probability measures : ambiguity on return/drift : Hansen, Sargent (01), Gundel (05), Schied (11), Tevzadze et al. (12), etc ambiguity on volatility matrix : Denis, Kervarec (07), Matoussi, Possamai, Zhou (12), Fouque, Sun, Wong (15), Riedel, Lin (16), etc Our main contributions : Markowitz criterion Ambiguity on covariance matrix, robust efficient frontier, and lower bound for robust Sharpe ratio

Robust framework Introduction Canonical space Ω = C([0, T ], R d ) : continuous paths of d stocks B = (B t ) t canonical process, P 0 : Wiener measure, F = (F t ) t canonical filtration Drift b R d of the assets is assumed to be known (well-estimated or strong belief) but uncertainty on the covariance matrix, possibly random (even rough!)

Ambiguous covariance matrix : Epstein-Ji (11) Γ compact set of S d >+ : prior realizations of covariance matrix Γ = Γ(Θ) parametrized by convex set Θ of R q : there exists some measurable function γ : R q S d >+ s.t. Any Σ in Γ is in the form : Σ = γ(θ) for some θ Θ. Concavity assumption (IC) : γ ( 1 2 (θ 1 + θ 2 ) ) 1 ( γ(θ1 ) + γ(θ 2 ) ) (1) 2 Remark : in examples, we have = in (1). Notation : for Σ Γ, we set, σ = Σ 1 2, the volatility matrix.

Examples Introduction Uncertain volatilities for multivariate uncorrelated assets : d Θ = [σ 2 i, σ i 2 ], 0 σ i σ i <, i=1 γ(θ) = σ1 2... 0....., 0... σd 2 Ambiguous correlation in the two-assets case : for θ = (σ 2 1,..., σ 2 d). γ(θ) = ( σ 2 1 σ 1 σ 2 θ σ 1 σ 2 θ σ 2 2 ), for θ Θ = [ϱ, ϱ] ( 1, 1), for some known constants σ 1, σ 2 > 0.

Prior (singular) probability measures V Θ : set of F-adapted processes Σ = (Σ t ) t valued in Γ = Γ(Θ) P Θ = { P σ } : Σ V Θ, with P σ := P 0 (B σ ) 1, σ t = Σ 1 2 t, Bt σ := In other words : t d < B > t = Σ t dt under P σ. 0 σ s db s, P 0 a.s. Remark : connection with the theory of G-expectation (Peng), and quasi-sure analysis (Denis/Martini, Soner/Touzi/Zhang, Nutz). We say P Θ q.s. : P σ a.s. for all Σ V Θ.

Assets price and wealth dynamics under covariance matrix uncertainty Price process S of d stocks : ds t = diag(s t )(bdt + db t ), 0 t T, P Θ q.s. Set A of portfolio strategies : F-adapted processes α valued in R d s.t. sup Pσ P Θ E σ[ T 0 α t Σ t α t dt] < Wealth process X α : dx α t = α t diag(s t ) 1 ds t = α t (bdt + db t ), 0 t T, X α 0 = x 0, P Θ q.s.

Robust Markowitz mean-variance formulation : { maximize over α A, E(α) := infp (M ϑ ) σ P E σ[x α Θ T ] subject to R(α) := sup Pσ P Var σ(x α Θ T ) ϑ. U 0 (ϑ), ϑ > 0 : robust efficient frontier Lagrangian robust mean-variance problem : given λ > 0, ( ) (P λ ) V 0 (λ) = inf sup λvar σ (XT α ) E σ [XT α ] α A P σ P Θ Not clear a priori that U 0 and V 0 are conjugates of each other! ( ) sup P σ P Θ λvar σ (XT α ) E σ [XT α ] λr(α) E(α)

Solution to (P λ ) Introduction Worst case scenario constant covariance matrix Σ = γ(θ ) minimizing the risk premium : θ arg min θ Θ R(θ), R(θ) := b γ(θ) 1 b. Optimal robust MV strategy = optimal MV strategy in the BS model with covariance matrix Σ R = b (Σ ) 1 b : Key remark : αt = ( x 0 + 1 T 2λ er Xt ) (Σ ) 1 b, 0 t T. E σ [XT ] = x 0 + 1 [ e R T 1 ] does not depend on P σ 2λ

Example : ambiguous correlation in the two-assets case Known marginal volatilities σ i, and drift b i, i = 1, 2, but unknown correlation lying in Θ = [ϱ, ϱ] ( 1, 1). Instantaneous Sharpe ratio of each asset : We set : β i = b i σ i > 0, i = 1, 2, ϱ 0 := min(β 1, β 2 ) max(β 1, β 2 ) (0, 1] as a measure of proximity between the two stocks.

Case 1 : ϱ < ϱ 0 Worst case scenario : Σ = Σ := γ( ϱ) highest correlation α t = ( x 0 + 1 2λ eb Σ 1 bt Xt ) Σ 1 b, 0 t T, P Θ q.s. Moreover, the two components of Σ 1 b have the same sign : directional trading with worst-case scenario corresponding to highest correlation θ = ϱ, i.e. diversification effect is minimal.

Case 2 : ϱ > ϱ 0 Worst case scenario : Σ = Σ = γ(ϱ) lowest correlation α t = ( x 0 + 1 ) 2λ eb Σ 1 bt Xt Σ 1 b, 0 t T, P Θ q.s. Moreover, the two components of Σ 1 b have opposite sign : spread trading with worst-case scenario corresponding to lowest correlation θ = ϱ, i.e. spread effect is minimal.

Case 3 : ϱ ϱ 0 Introduction ϱ Worst-case correlation scenario : θ = ϱ 0 (not extreme!) α t = ( [ x 0 + 1 exp ( β 2 2λ 1T ) ] Xt b1 σ1 2 0 ( [ 0 x 0 + 1 exp ( β 2 2λ 2T ) Xt ] b2 σ 2 2 ), 0 t T, P Θ q.s., if β1 2 > β2, 2 ), 0 t T, P Θ q.s., if β2 2 > β1. 2

Reformulation of robust Markowitz mean-variance problem Nonstandard zero-sum stochastic differential game : inf sup J(α, σ), with J(α, σ) = λvar σ (XT α ) E σ [XT α ] α A Σ V Θ Introduce ρ α,σ t := L σ (X α t ) law of X α t under P σ valued in P 2 (R), P 2 (R) : Wasserstein space of square-integrable measures R J(α, σ) = λvar(ρ α,σ T ) ρα,σ T where for µ P 2 (R) : µ := xµ(dx), Var(µ) := (x µ) 2 µ(dx). Standard deterministic differential game in P 2 (R). R

Method and tools of resolution Optimality principle from dynamic programming for the deterministic differential game : look for v : [0, T ] P 2 (R) R s.t. (i) v(t, µ) = λvar(µ) µ (ii) t v(t, ρ α,σ t ) is for all α A and some Σ V Θ (iii) t v(t, ρ α,σ t ) is for some α A and all Σ V Θ Derivative in P 2 (R) Chain rule along flow of probability measure

Derivative in the Wasserstein space in a nutshell Differentiation on P 2 (R) Consider u : P 2 (R) R Lifted version of u U : L 2 (F 0 ; R) R defined by U(ξ) = u(l(ξ)), u is differentiable if U is Fréchet differentiable (Lions definition) Differential of u : Fréchet derivative of U on on the Hilbert space L 2 (F 0 ; R) : DU(ξ) = µ u(l(ξ))(ξ), for some function µ u(l(ξ)) : R R µ u(l(ξ)) is called derivative of u at µ = L(ξ), and µ u(µ) L 2 µ(r). For fixed µ, if x R µ u(µ)(x) R is continuously differentiable, its gradient is denoted by x µ u(µ) L µ (R).

Examples of derivative (1) u(µ) = < ψ, µ > := ψ(x)µ(dx) Lifted version : U(ξ) = R E[ψ(ξ)] U(ξ + ζ) = U(ξ) + E[ x ψ(ξ)ζ] + o( ζ L 2 ) DU(ξ) = x ψ(ξ) µ u(µ) = x ψ x µ u(µ) = 2 x ψ (2) u(µ) = Var(µ) := R (x µ)2 µ(dx), with µ := xµ(dx), Lifted R version : U(ξ) = Var(ξ) and then x µ u(µ) = 2. µ u(µ)(x) = 2(x µ),

Chain rule for flow of probability measures Buckdahn, Li, Peng and Rainer (15), Chassagneux, Crisan and Delarue (15) : Consider Itô process : dx t = b t dt + σ t dw t, X 0 L 2 (F 0 ; R). Let u Cb 2(P (R)). Then, for all t, 2 du(l(x t)) = E [ µu(l(x t))(x t)b t + 1 2 x µu(l(xt))(xt)σ2 t ] dt.

Hamiltonian function for robust portfolio optimization problem Hamiltonian : for (p, M) R R +, (a, Σ) R d Γ, H(p, M, a, Σ) = pa b + 1 2 Ma Σa H (p, M) := inf sup a R d Σ Γ H(p, M, a, Σ) (min-max property under (IC)) = sup inf H(p, M, a, Σ) a R d Σ Γ (saddle point) = H(p, M, a (p, M), Σ ) where Σ = arg min Σ Γ b Σ 1 b, a (p, M) = p M (Σ ) 1 b.

Bellman-Isaacs equation in Wasserstein space Verification theorem : Suppose that one can find a smooth function v on [0, T ] P 2 (R) with x µ v(t, µ)(x) > 0 for all (t, x, µ) [0, T ) R P 2 (R), solution to the Bellman-Isaacs PDE : tv(t, µ) + H ( µv(t, µ)(x), x µv(t, µ)(x) ) µ(dx) = 0, (t, µ) [0, T ) P 2 (R) R v(t, µ) = λvar(µ) µ, µ P 2 (R). Moreover, suppose that we can aggregate the family of processes a ( µv(t, P σ X Pσ t )(X Pσ t ), x µv(t, P σ Xt Pσ )(Xt Pσ ) ), 0 t T, P σ p.s., Σ V Θ into a P Θ -q.s process α, where X Pσ is the solution to the McKean-Vlasov SDE under P σ : dx t = a ( µv(t, P σ X t )(X t), x µv(t, P σ X t )(X t) ) [bdt + db t], then α is an optimal portfolio strategy, Σ is the worst-case scenario and V 0(λ) = v(0, δ x0 ) = J(α, σ ) = inf sup α Σ J(α, σ) = sup Σ inf J(α, σ). α

Explicit resolution Introduction From the linear-quadratic structure of the problem, the solution to the Bellman-Isaacs PDE is v(t, µ) = K(t)Var(µ) µ + χ(t) for some explicit deterministic functions K and χ. Key observation : the MKV SDE under P σ is linear in X and E σ [X t ] E σ [X t ] does not depend on P σ we can aggregate X into a P Θ -q.s. solution α optimal strategy, and Σ worst-case scenario.

Duality relation Introduction Since the solution X = X α,λ to the Lagrangian mean-variance problem has expectation E σ [XT ] that does not depend on the prior probability measure P σ [ ] sup λvar σ(xt ) E σ[xt ] = λ sup Var σ(xt ) inf Eσ[X P σ P σ P σ T ] Robust Markowitz value function U 0 (ϑ) and mean-variance value function V 0 (λ) are conjugate : { V0 (λ) = inf ϑ>0 [ λϑ U0 (ϑ) ], λ > 0, U 0 (ϑ) = inf λ>0 [ λϑ V0 (λ) ], ϑ > 0. and solution ˆα ϑ to U 0 (ϑ) is equal to solution α,λ to V 0 (λ) with e R(θ )T 1 λ = λ(ϑ) =, 4ϑ where R(θ ) = b γ(θ ) 1 b : (square) of minimal risk premium.

Robust lower bound for Sharpe ratio : U 0 (ϑ) = x 0 + Sharpe ratio : for a portfolio strategy α e R(θ )T 1 ϑ, ϑ > 0. S(α) := E[X α T ] x 0 Var(X α T ) computed under the true probability measure. By following a robust Markowitz optimal portfolio ˆα ϑ : S(ˆα ϑ ) E(ˆαϑ ) x 0 R(ˆαϑ ) = U 0(ϑ) x 0 ϑ = e R(θ )T 1 =: S.

Conclusion Introduction Explicit solution to robust Markowitz problem under ambiguous covariance matrix and robust lower bound for Sharpe ratio McKean-Vlasov dynamic programming approach applicable beyond MV criterion to risk measure involving nonlinear functionals of the law of the state process Open problem : case of drift uncertainty Aggregation issue for MKV SDE (main difference with expected utility criterion) Duality relation does not hold