Phillips curve and the Tinbergen and Theil approach to economic policy

Similar documents
INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT: THE PHILLIPS CURVE. Dongpeng Liu Department of Economics Nanjing University

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Supplementary Notes on Chapter 6 of D. Romer s Advanced Macroeconomics Textbook (4th Edition)

Queen s University Department of Economics Instructor: Kevin Andrew

Endogenous Information Choice

A Dynamic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes.

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

Source: US. Bureau of Economic Analysis Shaded areas indicate US recessions research.stlouisfed.org

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor David Romer LECTURE 10

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Wage and price setting. Slides for 26. August 2003 lecture

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Economics II. Labor Market, Unemployment and the Phillips Curve, Part II

Final Exam. You may not use calculators, notes, or aids of any kind.

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

The Lucas Imperfect Information Model

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Aggregate Supply. A Nonvertical AS Curve. implications for unemployment, rms pricing behavior, the real wage and the markup

Chapter 4 AD AS. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos. Computational Economics: a concise introduction

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants,

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Self-test for applicants M.Sc. Economics

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

Endogenous Growth Theory

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap

Discussion Global Dynamics at the Zero Lower Bound

Two Models of Macroeconomic Equilibrium

Simultaneous (and Recursive) Equation Systems. Robert Dixon Department of Economics at the University of Melbourne

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

MA Macroeconomics 4. Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Problem 1 (30 points)

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Relationships between phases of business cycles in two large open economies

Appendix to Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macro Analysis

The New Keynesian Model

The transmission mechanism How the monetary-policy instrument affects the economy and the target variables

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452)

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory

1 Numbers, Sets, Algebraic Expressions

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 8

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

ECON 4160: Econometrics-Modelling and Systems Estimation Lecture 9: Multiple equation models II

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Inflation traps, and rules vs. discretion

The Global and Local in Phillips Curve

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Transcription:

Class handout Phillips curve and the Tinbergen and Theil approach to economic policy Giovanni Di Bartolomeo University of Teramo 1. The Phillips menu In the 190s, econometricians estimated a negative relationship between inflation and unemployment (Phillips curve). 1 This relationship is depicted in the following figure. Inflation rate (π) 10 C 19 4 197 19 195 19 194 193 191 α 0 1 3 4 5 7 9 10 Unemployment rate (u) Figure 1 The Phillips curve in the 0s Formally, it can be represented as (1) π = αu + c where α and c and are estimated coefficients. The economists postulate that by controlling the monetary aggregates it is possible to control inflation then, by using (1), the unemployment rate. 1 Indeed, in his original work, Phillips estimated the relationship between the money wages and unemployment. The relationship between inflation and unemployment was later developed by Samuelson and Solow. 1

Note that in our simplified world, 1. assuming that the labor force is given ( l f ), there is a one-to-one (inverse) correspondence between unemployment and labor (l) by definition (i.e., u = 1 l/ lf );. assuming capital is given ( k ), there is a one-to-one (direct) correspondence between labor y = f k, l ). and output by the production function (i.e., ( ) It follows that there is a one-to-one correspondence between unemployment and output (Okun law). Thus we can use output, labor and unemployment as thesauruses.. The policy problem We can assume that the policymaker dislikes both inflation and unemployment and that he would like to obtain zero inflation and zero unemployment (first best solution). Moreover, we can assume that the marginal costs of both are increasing in their levels; it means, e.g., that a marginal increase of inflation costs more (in terms of unemployment) when inflation is high, and vice versa. The loss can be represented by a simple squared expression: u () L= a π + It is worth noticing that the loss is zero if and only if inflation and unemployment are zero otherwise is positive. The loss is increasing in both inflation and unemployment (check the signs of the first derivatives), with increasing marginal costs (check the signs of the second derivatives). Inflation rate (π) 10 L 3 L 4 L 1 First best L 0 0 1 3 4 5 7 9 10 Unemployment rate (u) Figure The policymaker s loss See Appendix A for a discussion.

The policy problem the is to minimize () subject to (1). Graphically, the problem is solved by finding the lowest loss possible given the Phillips curve constraint. Inflation rate (π) 10 L 3 E L First best 4 L 1 L 0 A B 0 1 3 4 5 7 9 10 Unemployment rate (u) Figure 3 The policymaker s problem Figure 3 shows that the policymaker would prefer to be e.g. in point A; however this point is unfeasible as the policymaker has to choose inflation taking account of the Phillip curve (he can only move along the Phillips curve). Point E and B are both feasible, but the former is associated to a lower loss than the latter. The lowest loss is achieved in point E that is the policymaker s problem solution. Therefore, the policymaker will set inflation at about 5% and about % unemployment rate will be observed. Analytically, it can be solved as follows by plugging (1) in () and differentiate for π, (3) π 1 c π L 1 c π L= a + = aπ α π α α We have used the relationship Optimal inflation is then (4) c π u = from (1). α 1 c * c 1 a+ π π a = = + α α α α Using (4) and (1), we find also the optimal unemployment rate: 1 (5) u * 1 c c 1 = a 3 + α α α 3

Exercise 1. Consider (4) and (5), then answer the following questions. 1. What are the effects on inflation and unemployment when the policymaker dislikes inflation more (higher a)? [compute: π * / a and u * / a]. Try to explain.. What are the effects on inflation and unemployment when the Phillips curve becomes steeper (higher α)? [compute: π * / α and u * / a]. Try to explain. Alternatively, the problem can be solved by using the function of a function derivative rule (i.e., g( f( x)) = g'( f( x)) f '( x) ) as u is a function of π: We can write our problem as () ( π ) π u max L= a + π c π s.t. u ( π ) = α The first order condition is then (7) L = aπ + u u = 0 aπ = u u π π marg. cost π marg. benefit i.e., it is optimal for the policymaker to equalize the marginal cost of increasing inflation (higher u 1 inflation) to its marginal benefit (lower unemployment). Note that = is negative, thus the π α r.h.s. of (7) is positive. Equation (7) can be written as: 1 () π = u aα Solving the two-equation system (1) and () in u and π, the solution (4) and (5) is found. Equations (1) and () have a nice interpretation. Equation (), in fact, is the optimal policy rule: Given any possible unemployment rate, it describes the optimal reaction (inflation choice) of the policymakers, whereas equation (1) is the description of the economy. Graphically they are described in the following figure. 4

Inflation rate (π) 10 Policy rule E E B First best 4 Phillips curve after an adverse shock 0 1 3 4 5 7 9 10 Figure 4 Optimal policy rule Unemployment rate (u) Given the Phillips curve the optimal policy is described in point E (which is the only optimal combination of u and π feasible). Now consider an adverse shock in the Phillips cure (e.g., an increase in c) due to an oil shock. The optimal policy for the policymaker is to increase the inflation rate to about 7% and then the economy will face an unemployment rate of about 3.5% (point E ). If the policymaker would not chance his policy (keeping an inflation rate at about 5%), after the adverse shock the unemployment rate will raise to about 5.5% (point B), which clearly is not efficient as it is associated to an higher loss than point E. Exercise. Using Figure 4, discuss the effect of a change in the policymaker s preferences (a reduction of a) and a change in the Phillips curve coefficient α. Exercise 3. Consider the following model expressed in logs. Note that W / P (the real wage) in logs becomes log( W) log( P), we indicates log with lowercase letters; i.e., w p We assume that nominal wage (w) is set by a trade union. The trade union preferences increase in the real wage (w p) and fall in the unemployment rate (u): u = The unemployment rate is defined as follow: (9) U α ( w p) (10) u = 1 l i.e., labor force is normalized to unity. The first best for the union is clearly an infinite nominal wage and zero unemployment. However this solution is not feasible, as the union faces the following constraint: (11) l = η ( w p) Equation (11) is simply the firm s labor demand. 5

The idea is that the union (as a monopolist) sets the wage (price of labor) taking account of the labor demand (11) as constraint. The union problem is then (1) maxu α ( w p) w ( 1 l) = l = η w p subject to ( ) Assuming that the price level, p, is given, solve the above problem and comment the solution obtained. How the employment change if α increases, why?

Appendix A Iso-losses The representation of the policymaker s loss: (13) ( ) ( u u) L= a π π + in the π and u space is similar to the consumer utility representation by the indifference curves. The loss is defined in deviations of π and u from some (desired) targets π and u. Indeed, now we have to consider iso-losses instead of the indifference curves, as we are dealing with loss functions instead of utilities. An iso-loss curve represents all the π and u combinations that assure a certain given constant loss. Assuming for the sake of simplicity that the iso-losses are centered on zero (i.e., π = u = 0 ), if a=1, the iso-losses are concentric circles (panel (a)) centered on the fist best (π and u ), otherwise they are elliptic curves. In particular, for a<1 they have the form described by panel (b); for a>1 they have the form described by panel (c). π π π u u u Panel (a) Panel (b) Panel (c) Figure 5 Iso-losses We can refer to the case described in panel (b) as that of the populist central banker, i.e., a central bank that dislikes unemployment more than inflation. Hence large deviation of inflation (vertical axis) are compensate with smaller deviation in unemployment (horizontal axis). By contrast, panel (c) describes the case of a conservative central banker. In this case the central bank is more interested in stabilize inflation (as inflation is usually its institutional primary target), hence its isoloss curves are more concentrated along the horizontal axis (low inflation) implying an higher cost of inflation in terms of unemployment deviations). Appendix B Tinbergen-Theil approach * The policy problem presented here is an example of the more general Tinbergen and Theil approach to the economic policy. In the 50s, Tinbergen addressed in formal terms the issue of the controllability of a fixed set of independent targets by a policymaker facing an economy represented by a system of linear equations and endowed with a given set of instruments. He stated a well-known condition for policy existence in terms of number of instruments and targets. A similar approach was developed by Bent Hansen in roughly the same years. Tinbergen s approach to the policy problem has been further generalized by Theil. In particular, by prescribing that the policymaker should maximize a preference function, Theil solves the difficulties facing the * This appendix is optional. 7

policymaker when endowed with a lower number of instruments than the number of targets. In so doing, Theil arrived at a solution of the policy problem formally very similar to that predicated by Ragnar Frisch, who had first conceived policy problems in terms of maximizing a social preference function, to be derived by interviewing policymakers. Formally, the Tinbergen and Theil approach to the economic policy is based on the minimization of a loss function defined for deviations of the relevant variables from their target values is the following quadratic-matrix form: (14) U = ( y y) Q( y y) where y( i ) ; q y is the vector policymaker s q target variables, whose generic element is denoted by q y is the vector policymaker s (desired) targets; and Q is an appropriate symmetric positive semi-definite matrix. We refer to y and Q as the parameters of policymaker s preferences. 3 The economy is described by the following linear equation system (structural form of the economy): (15) Ay = Bu + K m where u is the vector of the m policymaker s instruments, whose generic element is denoted by u( j ) ; A and B are appropriate parameter matrices (i.e., the target and instrument coefficient matrices); and K is an appropriate vector of constants. 4 We assume that A and B are full-rank matrices, i.e., all targets and instrument variables are linearly independent (independence assumption). Intuitively, there are q distinct targets and m distinct instruments set by the policymaker. The linear reduced-form model can be written in matrix form as: (1) 1 1 y A = Bu+ A K = Cu+ C provided A is non-singular, as it is from our rank assumptions. Matrix C is a matrix of multipliers C i, j indicates the effect on target i of and is sometimes called the Jacobian matrix. Element ( ) changes in instrument j; that is, y( i) / u( j). The policy problem is to minimize equation (14) with respect to the vector of instruments, subject to equation (1). The corresponding first order condition is: (17) CQCu = CQ ( y C) which is m a equation system in m unknown, i.e., u. Existence of a solution of (17) is ensured if rank [ : K ] rank [ ] Φ = Φ, i.e., left invertibility of, where C QC K = CQ y C. Uniqueness requires the non-singularity of. If a solution or more exists, 5 the policy design problem implies the following optimal policy: Φ= and Φ ( ) Φ 3 Quadratic functions are used not only for their mathematical tractability, but also for their useful economic properties. In fact, deviations from the target are associated to increasing costs and, therefore, the marginal rate of substitution between any couple of target variables is never constant but depends on the values of the two variables in the point where it is computed. In addition, quadratic forms can be obtained as second-order Taylor approximations of more complex functions. 4 Each component of which is a linear combination of constants, exogenous variables and/or white noise shocks. 5 Note that we are solving a linear equation system, it thus will admit a unique solution, infinite solutions or no solutions at all.

(1) u * ( CQC) 1 = CQ ( y A 1 K) and outcomes (obtained by using (1) into (1)): (19) * ( ) 1 ( 1 ) If q y = C CQC CQ y A K + C = m, the above policy (1) reduces to * 1 (0) u = B ( Ay K ) which plugged in (1) gives (1) * y = y In this case ( q = m), the policymaker is able to obtain his first best. We refer tot this case as that where the policymaker can control the system (1); i.e., he is always able to achieve any possible vector of desired targets. In general, the policymaker can achieve any vector of independent targets by an appropriate vector of instruments if and only if the number of independent instruments is equal to, or greater than, the number of targets, q m (Tinbergen s Golden rule). 9