Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

Similar documents
Lecture Notes for January 8, 2009; part 2

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Competitive Equilibrium

Second Welfare Theorem

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

2.9. V = u(x,y) + a(x-f(l x,t x )) + b(y-g(l y,t y )) + c(l o -L x -L y ) + d(t o -T x -T y ) (1) (a) Suggested Answer: V u a 0 (2) u x = -a b 0 (3)

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

Short correct answers are sufficient and get full credit. Including irrelevant (though correct) information in an answer will not increase the score.

Public Economics Ben Heijdra Chapter 9: Introduction to Normative Public Economics

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

Adding Production to the Theory

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics

Notes on General Equilibrium

; p. p y p y p y. Production Set: We have 2 constraints on production - demand for each factor of production must be less than its endowment

Introductory Microeconomics

Lecture 1: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Problem Set Suggested Answers

1 General Equilibrium

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations

Introduction to General Equilibrium

First Welfare Theorem

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Lecture #3. General equilibrium

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture VII: Equilibrium in a Competitive Market

Short correct answers are sufficient and get full credit. Including irrelevant (though correct) information in an answer will not increase the score.

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

x 1 1 and p 1 1 Two points if you just talk about monotonicity (u (c) > 0).

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Partial Differentiation

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Econ 58 Gary Smith Spring Final Exam Answers

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu

Economics 604: Microeconomics Deborah Minehart & Rachel Kranton

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12

Alp Simsek (MIT) Recitation Notes: 1. Gorman s Aggregation Th eorem2. Normative Representative November 9, Household Theorem / 16

Problem set 2 solutions Prof. Justin Marion Econ 100M Winter 2012

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

Welfare Economics: Lecture 12

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Econ 401A: Economic Theory Mid-term. Answers

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

INTRODUCTORY MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS MSCS. LECTURE 3: MULTIVARIABLE FUNCTIONS AND CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. HUW DAVID DIXON CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL.

1 General Equilibrium in the Robinson Crusoe Economy.

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Basic Techniques. Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis. January 2018

STRUCTURE Of ECONOMICS A MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS

Advanced Microeconomics Problem Set 1

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Lecture Notes for January 23, 2012: Existence of general equilibrium in an economy with an excess demand function

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Queen s University. Department of Economics. Instructor: Kevin Andrew

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

School of Business. Blank Page

18 U-Shaped Cost Curves and Concentrated Preferences

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Market Failure: Externalities

University of Pittsburgh Department of Economics Econ 1720: Advanced Macroeconomics Handout 3

3. THE EXCHANGE ECONOMY

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

ANSWERS TO ODD NUMBERED EXERCISES IN CHAPTER 3

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics ARE 251/Econ 270A, Fall Household Models

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

The Heckscher-Ohlin Model: Brief Review

1. Basic Model of Labor Supply

The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Answers Econ 805

Applications I: consumer theory

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

1 Second Welfare Theorem

Economics th April 2011

a. This is an inequality constrained maximization problem. The Lagrangian is µ 1 q 1 = 0 µ 2 q 2 = 0 1 (q 1 ) φ φ c 2 (q 2) p 1 c 1(q 1 ) = 0

Transcription:

Lecture Notes October 18, 2012 Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I. Economic General Equilibrium Partial and General Economic Equilibrium PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM S k (p o ) = D k k (po ), with k po > 0 (or possibly, k po k = 0), or p o = 0 if S k k (po ) > D k k (po ). k GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM For all i = 1,...,N, D i (p o, 1 po 2,...,po ) = S N i (po 1,..,po ), N po i 0, and p o = 0 for goods i such that D i i (po 1,...,po ) < S N i (po 1,...,po ). N Partial equilibrium comparative statics assumes "other things being equal," that the variations considered are all local and interactions are negligible. What's wrong with partial equilibrium? Suppose there's no consistent choice of (p o 1,..,po N ). Then there would be (apparent) partial equilibrium --- viewing each market separately --- but no way to sustain it, because of cross-market interaction. Competitive equilibrium is supposed to make efficient use of resources by minimizing costs and allowing optimizing consumer choice. But to verify this notion in partial equilibrium we must assume (without proof) that prices in other markets reflect underlying scarcity. If not, then apparently efficient equilibrium allocation may be wasteful. A valid notion of equilibrium and efficiency needs to take cross-market interaction into account. Three big ideas Equilibrium: S(p) = D(p), where S, D, and p are all N-dimensional vectors Decentralization Efficiency The Edgeworth Box and the Robinson Crusoe model are two oversimplied examples in which most principal observations of the general equilibrium theory can be illustrated. October 18, 2012 1

The Edgeworth Box 2 person, 2 good, pure exchange economy Fixed positive quantities of X and Y, and two households, 1 and 2. Household 1 is endowed with X 1 of good X and Y 1 of good Y, utility function U 1 (X 1, Y 1 ). Household 2 is endowed with X 2 of good X and Y 2 of good Y, utility function U 2 (X 2, Y 2 ) X 1 + X 2 = X 1 + X 2 X, Y 1 + Y 2 = Y 1 + Y 2 Y. Each point in the Edgeworth box represents an attainable choice of X 1 and X 2, Y 1 and Y 2. 1's origin is at the southwest corner; 1's consumption increases as the allocation point moves in a northeast direction; 2's increases as the allocation point moves in a southwest direction. Superimpose indifference curves on the Edgeworth Box. Competitive Equilibrium (p o, x po ) so that y (Xo1, Y o1 ) maximizes U 1 (X 1, Y 1 ) subject to (p o, x po y )(X1, Y 1 ) (p o, x po ) and y (X1, Y 1 ) (X o2, Y o2 ) maximizes U 2 (X 2, Y 2 ) subject to (p o, x po y )(X1, Y 1 ) (p o, x po ), and y (X2, Y 2 ) (X o1, Y o1 ) + (X o2, Y o2 ) = (X 1, Y 1 )+(X 2, Y 2 ) or (X o1, Y o1 ) + (X o2, Y o2 ) (X 1, Y 1 )+ (X 2, Y 2 ), where the inequality holds co-ordinatewise and any good for which there is a strict inequality has a price of 0. Pareto efficiency: An allocation is Pareto efficient if all of the opportunities for mutually desirable reallocation have been fully used. The allocation is Pareto efficient if there is no available reallocation that can improve the utility level of one household while not reducing the utility of any household. Assuming convexity and monotonicity of preferences (quasi-concavity and non-satiation of utility functions) and an interior solution, Pareto efficiency is achieved at an allocation where there is tangency of 1 and 2's indifference curves. October 18, 2012 2

Pareto efficient allocation: (X o1, Y o1 ), (X o2, Y o2 ) maximizes U 1 (X 1, Y 1 ) subject to U 2 (X 2, Y 2 ) U o2 (typically --- assuming non-satiation --- equality will hold and U o2 =U 2 (X o2, Y o2 ) ) and subject to the resource constraints X 1 + X 2 = X 1 + X 2 X ; Y 1 + Y 2 = Y 1 + Y 2 Y. Equivalently, X 2 = X - X 1, Y 2 = Y - Y 1. Solving for Pareto efficiency (Assuming differentiability and an interior solution): Lagrangian L U 1 (X 1, Y 1 ) + λ[u 2 ( X -X 1, Y -Y 1 ) - U o2 ] = U1 λ U2 = 0 Y 1 = U1 Y 1 λ U2 Y 2 = 0 = U 2 (X 2, Y 2 ) - U o2 = 0 λ This gives us then the condition U 1 U 2 MRS 1 = X xy = 2 =MRS2 xy U 1 U 2 Y 1 Y 2 or equivalently MRS 1 = Y 1 xy U1 =constant = Y2 U2 =constant =MRS2 xy Pareto efficient allocation in the Edgeworth box: the slope of 2's indifference curve at an efficient allocation will equal the slope of 1's indifference curve; the points of tangency of the two curves. Exception: corner solutions, non-convex preferences (utility functions not quasi-concave). Pareto efficient set = locus of tangencies of indifference curves contract curve = individually rational Pareto efficient points October 18, 2012 3

Market allocation: general equilibrium p x, p y Household 1:Choose X 1, Y 1, to maximize U 1 (X 1,Y 1 ) subject to p x X 1 + p y Y 1 = p x X 1 + p y Y 1 = B 1 budget constraint is a straight line passing through the endowment point ( X 1, Y 1 ) px p y with slope. Similarly for Household 2. Lagrangian for Household 1's demand determination L = U 1 (X 1,Y 1 ) - λ [p x X 1 + p y Y 1 - B 1 ] X = U1 λp x = 0 = U1 λp y = 0 Y Y 1 Therefore, at the utility optimum subject to budget constraint we have MRS 1 xy U 1 = U 1 = px ; Similarly for household 2, p y Y 1 U 2 MRS 2 = xy U 2 = px p y. Y 2 Equilibrium prices: p* x and p* y so that X* 1 + X* 2 = X 1 + X 2 X Y* 1 + Y* 2 = Y 1 + Y 2 Y, (market clearing) where X* i and Y* i, i =1, 2, are utility maximizing mix of X and Y at prices p* x and p* y. October 18, 2012 4

Y1 p x p y = U 1 =U U 2 U 2 Y 2 1 = U1 U 1 = Y2 Y 1 = px p y U 2 =U 2 The price system decentralizes the efficient allocation decision. The Robinson Crusoe Model q = oyster production c = oyster consumption 168 (hours per week) endowment L = labor demanded R = leisure demanded 168-R =labor supplied q = F(L) (2.1) R = 168 - L (2.2) Centralized Allocation We assume second order conditions (convexity = concavity of production and utility functions= diminishing marginal product (in production) + diminishing marginal rate of substitution(in consumption)) so that local maxima are global maxima: F < 0, 2 u c 2 < 0, 2 u R 2 < 0. (Concavity, 2 nd order conditions) u(c,r) = u(f(l), 168 - L) (2.3) max u(f(l), 168 L) L (2.4) October 18, 2012 5

d dl u(f(l), 168 L)=0 u c F u R = 0 dq dr u=u max = u R u c = F (2.5) (2.6) (2.7) Pareto efficient MRS R,c = MRT R,q (= RPT R,q ) General Equilibrium: Decentralized Market Allocation Π=F(L) wl = q wl Income: Y = w 168 +Π Budget constraint: (2.8) (2.9) Y = wr + c (2.10) Equivalently, c = Y- wr = Π + wl = Π + w(168-r), a more conventional definition of a household budget constraint. Firm profit maximization in the market economy: Π=q wl dπ dl = F w = 0, so F (L0 )=w Household budget constraint: wr + c = Y =Π 0 + w168 (2.11) (2.14) (2.15) Household utility optimization in the market economy: Choose c, R to maximize u(c, R) subject to (2.15). The Lagrangian is V = u(c,r) - λ (Y - wr - c) October 18, 2012 6

V c = u c +λ=0 V = u +λw = 0 R R Dividing through, we have u MRS R,c = dc = R = w (2.19) dr u=cons tan t u c Definition : Market equilibrium. Market equilibrium consists of a wage rate w 0 so that at w 0, q = c and L = 168 R, where q, L are determined by firm profit maximizing decisions and c, R are determined by household utility maximization. (in a centralized solution L=168-R by definition; in a market allocation wages and prices should adjust so that as an equilibrium condition L will be equated to 168-R). Profit maximization at w 0 implies w 0 = F (L 0 ). (Recall (2.14)) Utility maximization at w o implies u R(c 0, R 0 ) u c(c 0, R 0 ) = w0 (Recall (2.19)) Market-clearing implies R 0 = 168 L 0, c 0 = F(L 0 ). So combining (2.14) and (2.19), we have F = u R u c (2.25) which implies Pareto efficiency. The market general equilibrium decentralizes the efficient allocation. October 18, 2012 7