The Leontief Open Economy Production Model

Similar documents
The Leontief Open Economy Production Model

: œ Ö: =? À =ß> real numbers. œ the previous plane with each point translated by : Ðfor example,! is translated to :)

Æ Å not every column in E is a pivot column (so EB œ! has at least one free variable) Æ Å E has linearly dependent columns

Example: A Markov Process

solve EB œ,, we can row reduce the augmented matrix

B œ c " " ã B œ c 8 8. such that substituting these values for the B 3 's will make all the equations true

solve EB œ,, we can row reduce the augmented matrix

The Spotted Owls 5 " 5. = 5 " œ!þ")45 Ð'!% leave nest, 30% of those succeed) + 5 " œ!þ("= 5!Þ*%+ 5 ( adults live about 20 yrs)

1. (3pts) State three of the properties of matrix multiplication.

Chapter 2: Matrix Algebra

Here are proofs for some of the results about diagonalization that were presented without proof in class.

Systems of Equations 1. Systems of Linear Equations

Elementary Linear Algebra

Introduction to Diagonalization

Application of linear systems Linear Algebra with Computer Science Application

All of my class notes can be found at

LINEAR ALGEBRA W W L CHEN

Inner Product Spaces. Another notation sometimes used is X.?

Solution Set 3, Fall '12

Inner Product Spaces

Definition Suppose M is a collection (set) of sets. M is called inductive if

Math 140, c Benjamin Aurispa. 2.1 Matrices

Matrices 2. Slide for MA1203 Business Mathematics II Week 4

ECON 331 Homework #2 - Solution. In a closed model the vector of external demand is zero, so the matrix equation writes:

MATH 54 - WORKSHEET 1 MONDAY 6/22

MATH 1003 Review: Part 2. Matrices. MATH 1003 Review: Part 2. Matrices

Exam 3 Review Math 118 Sections 1 and 2

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

Math x + 3y 5z = 14 3x 2y + 3z = 17 4x + 3y 2z = 1

Matrix Factorization Reading: Lay 2.5

Chapter 2: Systems of Linear Equations and Matrices

Linear Algebra Practice Problems

PART I. Multiple choice. 1. Find the slope of the line shown here. 2. Find the slope of the line with equation $ÐB CÑœ(B &.

GAUSSIAN ELIMINATION AND LU DECOMPOSITION (SUPPLEMENT FOR MA511)

STAT 2122 Homework # 3 Solutions Fall 2018 Instr. Sonin

Relations. Relations occur all the time in mathematics. For example, there are many relations between # and % À

Matrices (Ch.4) MATH 1003 Review: Part 2. Matrices. Matrices (Ch.4) Matrices (Ch.4)

This operation is - associative A + (B + C) = (A + B) + C; - commutative A + B = B + A; - has a neutral element O + A = A, here O is the null matrix

Chapter 3. Linear Equations. Josef Leydold Mathematical Methods WS 2018/19 3 Linear Equations 1 / 33

Focusing Learning on Concepts of Introductory Linear Algebra using MAPLE Interactive Tutors

University of Ottawa

Introduction to Systems of Equations

MTH Linear Algebra. Study Guide. Dr. Tony Yee Department of Mathematics and Information Technology The Hong Kong Institute of Education

Matrices. In this chapter: matrices, determinants. inverse matrix

1. Determine by inspection which of the following sets of vectors is linearly independent. 3 3.

Solutions to Exam I MATH 304, section 6

The Gauss-Jordan Elimination Algorithm

DATABASE AND METHODOLOGY

TOPIC III LINEAR ALGEBRA

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Suggestions - Problem Set (a) Show the discriminant condition (1) takes the form. ln ln, # # R R

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

Introduction to General Equilibrium

2 Systems of Linear Equations

Math E-21b Spring 2018 Homework #1 Problems due in class on Thurs, Feb 1 or online by Sat, Feb 3, 11:59pm EST: Section 1.1:

Chapter 9 Input-Output Model Based on Ordered Fuzzy Numbers

Proofs Involving Quantifiers. Proof Let B be an arbitrary member Proof Somehow show that there is a value

4 Elementary matrices, continued

Formelsammlung zu Wirtschaftstheorie IV

Introduction to Algebra: The First Week

EQ: How do I convert between standard form and scientific notation?

ECON5110: Microeconomics

Sometimes the domains X and Z will be the same, so this might be written:

University of Ottawa

Elementary matrices, continued. To summarize, we have identified 3 types of row operations and their corresponding

4 Elementary matrices, continued

The scope of the midterm exam is up to and includes Section 2.1 in the textbook (homework sets 1-4). Below we highlight some of the important items.

1. (7pts) Find the points of intersection, if any, of the following planes. 3x + 9y + 6z = 3 2x 6y 4z = 2 x + 3y + 2z = 1

Problems for M 8/31: and put it into echelon form to see whether there are any solutions.

Review of matrices. Let m, n IN. A rectangle of numbers written like A =

Finite Mathematics. Linear Equations (Chapter 4) Optimization (Chapter 5) Finite Probability (Chapter 6) Markov Chains (Chapter 9) Finite Mathematics

Linear Algebra for Beginners Open Doors to Great Careers. Richard Han

Numerical Methods Lecture 2 Simultaneous Equations

Linear Algebra March 16, 2019

MATH 221: SOLUTIONS TO SELECTED HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

SIMULATION - PROBLEM SET 1

MA 0540 fall 2013, Row operations on matrices

Systems of Linear Equations in two variables (4.1)

Alternating Series, Absolute and Conditional Convergence Á + s -1dn Á + s -1dn 4

MATH240: Linear Algebra Review for exam #1 6/10/2015 Page 1

Dr. H. Joseph Straight SUNY Fredonia Smokin' Joe's Catalog of Groups: Direct Products and Semi-direct Products

Gene expression experiments. Infinite Dimensional Vector Spaces. 1. Motivation: Statistical machine learning and reproducing kernel Hilbert Spaces

MTH 464: Computational Linear Algebra

8œ! This theorem is justified by repeating the process developed for a Taylor polynomial an infinite number of times.

Span and Linear Independence

College Algebra. Systems of Equations and Inequalities with Matrices addendum to Lesson2. Dr. Francesco Strazzullo, Reinhardt University

Handout 1 EXAMPLES OF SOLVING SYSTEMS OF LINEAR EQUATIONS

Marginal Functions and Approximation

3 is an eigenvector of A.

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

TECHNICAL APPENDIX. 7. Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case

Math 205B Exam 02 page 1 03/19/2010 Name /7 4/7 1/ /7 1/7 5/ /7 1/7 2/

Matrices, Row Reduction of Matrices

Math 54 HW 4 solutions

MTH 2032 Semester II

EC5555 Economics Masters Refresher Course in Mathematics September 2014

Integrating Input-Output and Life Cycle Assessment: Mathematical Foundations

Next topics: Solving systems of linear equations

Systems and Matrices CHAPTER 7

Transcription:

The Leontief Open Economy Production Model We will look at the idea for Leontief's model of an open economy a term which we will explain below. It starts by looking very similar to an example of a closed economy that we saw near the beginning of this course. Here, however, we start with a matrix whose columns represent consumption (rather than production as in the earlier example). In the case of simple examples, we can solve the equations that we will set up. However, proofs of the deeper and more interesting theorems about what happens in general are beyond the scope of this course. Assume that an economy has 8 sectors W" ß ÞÞÞß W8. Amounts consumed or produced by each sector are measured in $ (value of goods consmbed or produced). We begin with a consumption matrix G: the 4 >2 column lists the amount of goods (in $) consumed Ðor demanded Ñ by sector W4 from sectors W" ß W# ß ÞÞÞß W8 to produce one unit ($) of its product.. Columns of G are consumption vectors by sectors W" â W â W 4 8 to produce 1 unit of product (measured in $) Æ Æ Æ W" Ä -"" â -"4 â -"8 Consumed from W3 Ä -3" â -34 â -38 œg W Ä - â - â - 8 8" 84 88 Of course, each - 34!Þ -"" For example, Column " œ -3" lists the consumption (demands) of Sector 1 from - 8" Sectors W",..., W8 to produce one unit ($) of product. Of course, we could also think of this as a list of costs ($) for Sector 1 to produce one unit of product, and the sum of the entries gives the total cost of all products consumed (demanded) by Sector 1 to produce one unit of its product.

The same is true for each column: the entries in Column 4 represent the consumption (demands, or costs) of sector W from sectors W ß W ß ÞÞÞß W in order for W to produce unit ($) of product. 4 " # 8 4 one Each column sum represents the costs for that sector to produce one unit. If a column sum is ", we say that sector is profitable.) -"4 B4 -"4 If we weight Column 4 with a scalar B 4 0, then the vector B4-34 œ B4-34 lists - B - 84 4 84 the consumption (demand, cost) by sector W4 from other sectors to produce B4 units of its own product. Suppose B" ß B# ß ÞÞÞß B 8 (! ) are amounts to be produced by sectors W" ß W# ß ÞÞÞß W8. We B" B# call Bœ is called a production vector. Then what does the vector GB mean? B 8 It is a linear combination of the columns of G with the B 3 's as weights: -"" -"# -"8 - B ÞÞÞ- B GB œ B" -31 B# -3# ÞÞÞB8-38 œ -3" B" ÞÞÞ - B - - - - B ÞÞÞ- B 81 8# 88 "" " "8 8 38 8 8" " 88 8 total demanded from sector W" by sectors W" ß ÞÞÞ ß W to produce B œ total demanded from sector W# by sectors W" ßÞÞÞ ß W8 to produce B total demanded from sector W,C sectors W ß ÞÞÞ ß W to produce B 8 " 8 In other words, GB lists the demands that must be supplied from each sector to the others to deliver the production vector B Þ The equation GB œ B asks for an equilibrium value an production vector B for which everything is in balance, where the list B of products (in $) from each sector œ the list GB of total demands ($) from the sectors. For equilibrium, the production from each sector must be not too large, not too small, but just right. This is a closed economy everything is just exchanged among the sectors.

Now we add another feature to the economic model: an open sector. It is nonproductive, that is, it produces nothing that sectors W" ß ÞÞÞß W8use. The open sector simply demands the prodcuts of sectors W" ß ÞÞÞß W8Þ (For example, these could be demands of the government, demands for foreign export, for individual consumption, for charitable groups,...). ".# Supppose. œ tells how many units (in $) the open sector demands from each. 8 sector Wß ÞÞÞß W8 Þ The vector. is called the final demand vector We want to know if it is possible to set a level of production B so that both the productive and open sectors are satisfied, with nothing left over. That is, we want to find an B so that Leontief Open Economy Production Model B œ GB. (***) Å Å Å Total production œ Demand from + Demand from productive sectors open sector to produce B ( called intermediate ( called final demand ) demand ) If M is the identity matrix, we can rewrite this equation as : MB œ GB. MB GB œ. or ÐM GÑ B œ. To take a simple example, suppose the economy has 4 productive sectors the consumption matrix is Consumption vectors for W" W# W$ W% Æ Æ Æ Æ Þ"! Þ!& Þ$! Þ#! Þ"& Þ#& Þ!& Þ"! Gœ Þ$! Þ"! Þ"! Þ#& Þ"& Þ#! Þ"! Þ#! ÐThe column sums in G are all ", so each sector is profitable. ) W ß ÞÞÞW " % and

Then ÐM GÑ œ Þ*! Þ!& Þ$! Þ#! Þ"& Þ(& Þ!& Þ"! Þ$! Þ"! Þ*! Þ#& Þ"& Þ#! Þ"! Þ)! #&!!! "!!!! If the demand from the open sector is. œ, then we want to solve $!!!! &!!!! Þ*! Þ!& Þ$! Þ#! #&!!! Þ"& Þ(& Þ!& Þ"! "!!!! ÐM GÑB œ B œ œ. Þ$! Þ"! Þ*! Þ#& $!!!! Þ"& Þ#! Þ"! Þ)! &!!!! Row reducing the augmented matrix gives Þ*! Þ!& Þ$! Þ#! #&!!! "!!! )&&)! Þ"& Þ(& Þ!& Þ"! "!!!!! "!! &!'#! µ Þ$! Þ"! Þ*! Þ#& $!!!!!! "! *'"'! Þ"& Þ#! Þ"! Þ)! &!!!!!!! " "!$##! These calculations were carried out to many decimal places, but the displayed numbers are rounded, at the end, to the nearest unit ($) The equation (***) will be satisfied if )&&)! &!'#! B œ, that is, *'"'! "!$##! if W " produces 85580 units ($), W produces 50620 units ($), # ÞÞÞ etc. Notice: the row reduced echelon form shows that MGis invertible, so the solution for " B is actually unique: B œðmgñ. Þ ( We could have solved the matrix equation " ÐM GÑB œ. in the first place by trying to find M GÑ, but that's even more work. ) This theorem is too hard for us to prove, but we can give an intuitive argument for it. Theorem ( using the same notation as above) If G and. have nonnegative entries and the column sums in G are all "( that is, if every sector is profitable), then ÐM GÑ must be invertible and therefore there is a unique production vector satisfying the " equation ÐM GÑB œ., namely B œ ÐM GÑ.. Moreover, this B is economically feasible in the sense that all its entries are!þ

Here is an informal, imprecise discussion that might give you some confidence that the theorem is actually true. 1) Suppose G is any 8 8 matrix with entries all 0 and all column sums "Þ 7 Then G Ä! as 7 Ä. Å (the 8 8zero matrixñ This statement just means that each entry - in the matrix G 7 can be made as close to! as we like by choosing 7large enough. To keep things simple, we will only look at the case when G œ +,, -. a # # matrix. But the idea is similar when Gis 8 8. Let α œ the larger of the two column sums in G. By definition of α, +- Ÿ α and,.ÿα Ðone of the two actually equals α. ) By our assumptions above about G, we see that! Ÿ α ". An observation: suppose Bß Cß Dß A!Þ What happens to column sums when a # # matrix B C G is multiplied by on the left? B C +, B C +B,D +C,A G œ œ, -. -B.D -C.A so the column sums satisfy: Sum Column 1 œ Ð+ -ÑB Ð,.ÑD Ÿ αb αd œ α ÐB DÑ Sum Column 2 œ Ð+ -ÑC Ð,.ÑA Ÿ αc αa œ α ÐC AÑ In other words: for each column in the product G B C, column sum in product Ÿ α B C Ðold column sum in Ñ Use this fact, letting B C œgœ +, -. Þ Then B C # +, +, G œ G œ and -. -. # # sum for column " of G Ÿ α (old column 1 sum in G) œ αð+-ñ Ÿ α α œ α sum for column 2 of G Ÿ α (old column 2 sum in G) œ αð,.ñ Ÿ α α œ α. # #

B C Repeating the calculation again using, we see that in the matrix œg# G $ œ G G # +, œ G Ÿ -. #, the sum of each column is α $. 7 7 Continuing in this way, we get that each column sum in G is Ÿ α Þ Since all 7 the elements in G are nonnegative, this means that every individual entry - in the matrix G 7 satisfies! Ÿ - Ÿ α 7 Þ Since α 7 Ä! as 7 Ä (because 7!Ÿα "ß ) we get that each entry -in G approaches! as 7Ä Þ 7" 2) MG œðmgñðmgg ÞÞÞG Ñ Why? Just multiply it out to verify: ÐMGÑÐMGG ÞÞÞG Ñ œ ÐM GÑM ÐMGÑG ÐMGÑG ÞÞÞ ÐMGÑG œm GMMGG MG G ÞÞÞMG G œmggg G ÞÞ. ÞÞÞG G G œmg 7" # # # $ 7 7" # 7 7" 7 7" 3) Since G Ä! as 7 Ä, it follows that for large 7 G! and therefore M ÐMGÑÐMGG ÞÞÞG Ñ Å so ÐM G G ÞÞÞ G Ñ is approximately an inverse for ÐM GÑ, that is " ÐMGG ÞÞÞG Ñ ÐMGÑ This approximation suggests that MGreally is invertible, and, since ÐMGG ÞÞÞG Ñhas nonnegative entries, it also suggests that all the entries in the exact matrix ÐM GÑ " will be nonnegative. 4) If ÐM GÑ is invertible and ÐM GÑ " has all nonnegative elements, then of " " course there is a unique solution B œ ÐM GÑ. and ÐM GÑ. has all nonnegative entries.

Having done all this, we can also write: " ÐMGÑ ÐMGG ÞÞÞG Ñ, so " Bœ ÐMGÑ. ÐMGG ÞÞÞG Ñ. or B. G. G. ÞÞÞG. Does that make any sense? Think about it like this: we ask the sectors to meet the final demand., and they set out to do it. But producing the goods listed in. creates additional demands: each sector has demands from the others to be able to produce anything at all. In fact, the sectors must supply each other with the products listed in G. so that they can produce.. But then, to produce G. ß the sectors require an additional GÐG. ÑÑ in products and so on and so on... To make it all work, the needed production B is an infinite sum: B œ. G. G. ÞÞÞG. ÞÞÞ 7 But because G Ä! as 7Ä, we approximate B. G. G. ÞÞÞG. for large 7. The column vectors in ÐM GÑ " actually have an economic interpretation: see the remarks following the next example Example Here is an example with a slightly more realistic set of data involving the Leontief Open Economy Production Model. The data is from #13, p. 137 in the textbook. The consumption matrix G is based on input-output data for the U.S. economy in 1958, with data for 81 sectors grouped here (for manageability) into ( larger sectors: (1) nonmetal household and personal products (2) final metal products (such as autos) (3) basic metal products and mining (4) basic nonmetal products and agriculture (5) energy (6) services and (7) entertainment and miscellaneous products. Units are in millions of dollars. (From Wassily W. Leontief, The Structure of the US Economy, Scientific American, April 1965, pp. 30-32). 0.1588 0.0064 0.0025 0.0304 0.0014 0.0083 0.1594 0.0057 0.2645 0.0436 0.0099 0.0083 0.0201 0.3413 0.0264 0.1506 0.3557 0.0139 0.0142 0.0070 0.0236 G œ 0.3299 0.0565 0.0495 0.3636 0.0204 0.0483 0.0649 0.0089 0.0081 0.0333 0.0295 0.3412 0.0237 0.0020 0.1190 0.0901 0.0996 0.1260 0.1722 0.2368 0.3369 0.0063 0.0126 0.0196 0.0098 0.0064 0.0132 0.0012 It turns out that MGis invertible ( as it should be, according to the Theorem stated)

(%!!! &'!!! "!&!! For a final demand vector. œ #&!!!, the solution to BœGB. is easy with "(&!! "*'!!! &!!! computer software such as Matlab. Rounded to 4 places, Matlab gives ÐM GÑ " œ 1.2212 0.0271 0.0226 0.0677 0.0135 0.0227 0.2167 0.0432 1.4046 0.1244 0.0466 0.0404 0.0516 0.5103 0.0806 0.3387 1.5927 0.0555 0.0508 0.0326 0.1810 0.6732 0.1905 0.1763 1.6448 0.0948 0.1266 0.3265 0.0636 0.0531 0.1010 0.0897 1.5393 0.0575 0.0590 0.3409 0.2711 0.2953 0.3253 0.3842 1.3674 0.6371 0.0213 0.0303 0.0392 0.0231 0.0175 0.0211 1.0246 so (%!!! 99580 &'!!! 97700 "!&!! 51230 " " B œðmgñ. œðmgñ #&!!! œ 13157 "(&!! 49490 "*'!!! 32955 &!!! 13840 ( entries rounded to whole numbers) An economic interpretation for the columns of ÐM GÑ " Suppose G is an 8 8 consumption matrix with entries! and column sums each less than "Þ Let production vector that a final demand Ð Ñ B œ satisfies.? B œ production vector that satisfies a different final demand?. Ðfor the moment, just think of? B and? d as fancy names for two new production/final demand vectors having no connection to B ß. Ñ Then by (**) B œ G B.? B œ G? B?.

Adding the equations and rearranging, we get B? B œ GÐB? B ÑÐ.?. Ñ So production level ÐB? B Ñfulfils the final demand Ð.?. Ñ At this point you can think of?. as we would in calculus as a change in the final demand., and? B is the corresponding change made necessary in the production vector B to satisfy the new final demand. "! Suppose we let?. œ, that is, increase the final demand from sector W"! by 1 unit. Since? B œg? B?., we have ÐMGÑ? B œ?., or " "? B œðmgñ?. œðmgñ "!! col 1 col 2 col 8 of of of œ" "! " ÞÞÞ! " ÐM GÑ ÐM GÑ ÐM GÑ œ col 1 of ÐM GÑ " "! " So the? B corresponding to?. œ is the first column of ÐM GÑ Þ! In other words: a change of one unit in the final demand from sector W " requires a change? B in the production vector required to satisfy the new demand, and? B œ the first column of ÐM GÑ ". Similarly, you can show that a change of one unit in the demand of sector W # causes a " change in the production vector?b œthe second column of ÐMGÑ à etc.

The column vectors in ÐM GÑ " are not just accidental vectors that pop up in computing the inverse; they have economic meaning. "! So, in the preceding example: a change of?. œ ß that is a change of 1 unit! Ðœ " million dollars Ñin the demand for goods from sector W" forces the necessary production vector 99580 97700 51230 Bœ 13157 to change to B? B, 49490 32955 13840 1.2212 0.0432 0.0806 => " where?b œ" column of ÐMGÑ œ 0.6732 0.0636 0.3409 0.0213