Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Similar documents
Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Lecture 5: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

A Note on the Welfare Evaluation of Tax Reform with Non-Convex Preferences and Discrete Labor Supply

Public Economics Ben Heijdra Chapter 9: Introduction to Normative Public Economics

The Design of a University System

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Lecture 1: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions)

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Optimal Income Taxation with Unemployment and Wage Responses: A Sufficient Statistics Approach

Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides Model

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

A Theory of Optimal Inheritance Taxation

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

1 Static (one period) model

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Simplifying this, we obtain the following set of PE allocations: (x E ; x W ) 2

OPTIMAL TAXATION: LESSONS FOR TAX POLICY

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Module 16: Signaling

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Economic Growth: Lectures 10 and 11, Endogenous Technological Change

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

Optimal Income Taxation: Mirrlees Meets Ramsey

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Top 10% share Top 1% share /50 ratio

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Economics th April 2011

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

Lecture 2 Optimal Indirect Taxation. March 2014

Market Failure: Externalities

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 2, Review of Endogenous Growth: Expanding Variety Models

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial Insurance Economy

Advanced Macroeconomics

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Under-Employment and the Trickle-Down of Unemployment - Online Appendix Not for Publication

Answers to Spring 2014 Microeconomics Prelim

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Optimal age-dependent income taxation in a dynamic extensive model: The case for negative participation tax to the young people

AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Taxes and Employment Subsidies in Optimal Redistribution Programs

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Optimal Tax Progressivity: An Analytical Framework

Online Appendix for Optimal Taxation with Behavioral Agents Emmanuel Farhi and Xavier Gabaix August 2015

Expanding Variety Models

Optimal taxation with monopolistic competition

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Optimal Mirrleesian Income Taxation with Tax Avoidance

Online Appendix The Growth of Low Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market. By David H. Autor and David Dorn

Equality of Opportunity

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

PROPERTY RIGHTS IN GROWTH THEORY

Optimal Tax Progressivity: An Analytical Framework

Asymmetric Information in Economic Policy. Noah Williams

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Problem Set Suggested Answers

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Florian Hoffmann. September - December Vancouver School of Economics University of British Columbia

A Theory of Income Taxation under Multidimensional Skill Heterogeneity

Should Robots Be Taxed?

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Self-test for applicants M.Sc. Economics

Problem 1 (30 points)

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Chapter 5. The Engine of Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Incorporating a Simple DMP Version of the Labor Market and Rediscovering the Shimer Puzzle

Answer Key: Problem Set 1

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Optimal Income, Education and Bequest Taxes in an Intergenerational Model

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

U b (x b ) = xb 1x b 2 x a 1. means the consumption of good i by an h-type person.

Advanced Macroeconomics

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

Transcription:

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation Matteo Paradisi November 1, 2016 In this Section we develop a theoretical analysis of optimal minimum wage policy in a perfectly competitive labor market following Lee and Saez (2012). 1 Optimal Minimum Wage We study a model with extensive and intensive margin labor supply responses where wages are endogenous. Suppose output is produced through a constant return to scale production function F (h 1,h 2 )whereh 1 and h 2 are low and high-skilled workers respectively. Profits are given by = F (h 1,h 2 ) w 1 h 1 w 2 h 2 and wages are equal to the marginal product of labor: w i = @F (h 1,h 2 ) @h i (1) A mass 1 of individuals has three labor supply options: i) not work and earn zero income, ii) work in occupation 1 and get w 1, iii) work in occupation 2 and earn w 2. Individuals are heterogeneous in their tastes for work. Every individual faces a vector =( 1, 2 ) of work costs that is smoothly distributed across the entire population according to H ( ) with support. The government perfectly observes the wage w i, but does not observe the cost of working. There are no savings and after tax income equals consumption such that c i = w i T i. Suppose there are no income e ects and utility is linear in consumption: u i = c i i The subset of individuals choosing occupation i is i = { 2 u i = max j u j }. The fraction of the population working in occupation i is h i (c) = i and is a function of c =(c 0,c 1,c 2 ). The tax system defines a competitive equilibrium (h 1,h 2,w 1,w 2 ). Equation (1) implies that w 2 /w 1 = F 2 (1,h 2 /h 1 ) /F 1 (1,h 2 /h 1 ). Constant returns to scale along with decreasing marginal productivity along each skill implies that the right- hand-side is a decreasing function of h 2 /h 1. Therefore, the function is invertible and the ratio h 2 /h 1 can be written as a function of the wage ratio w 2 /w 1 : h 2 /h 1 = (w 2 /w 1 )with ( ) a decreasing function. Constant returns to scale also imply that there are no profits in equilibrium. Hence = F (h 1,h 2 ) w 1 h 1 w 2 h 2 = 0 so that w 1 + w 2 (w 2 /w 1 )= F (1, w 2 /w 1 ), which defines a decreasing mapping between w 1 and w 2 so that we can express w 2 as a decreasing function of w 1 : w 2 (w 1 ). Labor supply and demand for the low-skilled labor market are D 1 (w 1 ) and S 1 (w 1 )withd1 0 (w 1 ) apple 0 and S1 0 (w 1 ) 0 and are defined assuming that the market clears in the high-skilled labor market. The low-skilled labor demand elasticity is: 1 = w 1 h 1 D 1 (w 1 ) 1

The resource constraint of the economy is: h 0 c 0 + h 1 c 1 + h 2 c 2 apple h 1 w 1 + h 2 w 2 (2) The government weights individual utilities through a social welfare function G ( ) and we can write the social welfare of the economy as: SW =(1 h 1 h 2 ) G (c 0 )+ G (c 1 1 1 ) dh ( )+ G (c 2 2 ) dh ( ) (3) We define social marginal welfare weights as usual g 0 = G 0 (c 0 ) / and g i = i G 0 (c i i ) dh ( ) / ( h i ), where is the marginal value of public funds. The concavity of the SWF implies g 0 >g 1 and g 1 >g 2. Since there are no income e ects the value of transferring $1 to everyone in the economy is $1 and we have = g 0 h 0 + g 1 h 1 + g 2 h 2 = 1. Minimum Wage with No Taxes Suppose there are no taxes and transfers, we have c 0 = 0, c 1 = w 1 and c 2 = w 2. Suppose the economy is at the equilibrium and the government introduces a small minimum wage above the equilibrium wage of the low-skilled market such that w = w1 +. The change will generate a drop in employment h 1. The workers who drop out of the low-skilled sector will move either to unemployment or to the high-skilled sector depending on their preferences. We will assume e cient rationing: the workers who involuntarily lose their low-skilled jobs due to the minimum wage are those with the least surplus from working in the low-skilled sector. 1 This is clearly the most favorable case to minimum wage policy. We establish the first result of the paper: Proposition 1: With no taxes/transfers, if (i) e cient rationing holds; (ii) the government values redistribution from high-skilled workers toward low-skilled workers (g 1 >g 2 ); (iii) the demand elasticity 1 for low-skilled workers is finite; and (iv) the supply elasticity of lows-killed workers is positive, then introducing a minimum wage increases social welfare. Consider the changes dw 1, dw 2, dh 1 and dh 2 following the increase in the minimum wage, we have d = P i [(@F/@h i) dh i w i dh i h i dw i ]= h 1 dw 1 h 2 dw 2 and the no profit condition implies: h 1 dw 1 + h 2 dw 2 = 0 (4) Therefore, the earnings gain for low-skilled people h 1 dw 1 > 0 is compensated by a loss in the earnings of high-skilled workers h 2 dw 2 < 0. The government values the transfer of resources [g 1 g 2 ] h 1 dw 1. Under e cient rationing, positive supply elasticity and finite demand elasticity, the welfare loss due to low-skilled individuals moving to unemployment is second-order (see Figure 1). More formally, the first order condition wrt is: dsw = apple dh1 + dh 2 G (0) + dh 1 G (0) + dh 2 G (0) + 1 G 0 (c 1 1 ) dh ( )+ dw 2 G 0 (c 2 2 ) dh ( ) The second and third terms come from the assumption of perfect rationing: the workers moving to unemployment from the two occupations are those with zero surplus from working therefore the welfare loss associated to the change of occupation is zero. Also, those who drop out of occupation 1 and move to 2 are indi erent between the two and we can ignore the welfare e ect associated to the change by envelope theorem. Using (4) we have dw 2 / = h 1 /h 2 and the FOC becomes: 1 The assumption can be relaxed and a working paper version of the paper shows how the model can be derived under the assumption of uniform rationing. 2

Figure 1: which proves Proposition 1. dsw = h 1 [g 1 g 2 ] > 0 Minimum Wage with Taxes and Transfers transfers jointly with the minimum wage policy. We now assume that the government can use taxes and Proposition 2: Under e cient rationing, assuming 1 < 1, ifg 1 > 1 at the optimal tax allocation (with no minimum wage), then introducing a minimum wage is desirable. Furthermore, at the joint minimum wage and tax optimum, we have: (i) g 1 =1(Full redistribution to low-skilled workers); (ii) h 0 g 0 + h 1 g 1 + h 2 g 2 =1(Social welfare weights average to one). Suppose there was no minimum wage, an attempt to increase c 1 by dc 1 while keeping c 0 and c 2 constant through an increased work subsidy provides incentives for some of the non-workers to start working in occupation 1 (extensive labor supply response) and for some of workers in occupation 2 to switch to occupation 1 (intensive labor supply response). This leads to a reduction in w 1 through demand side e ects (as long as 1 < 1). See Figure 2. Consider the same increase in c 1 when the minimum wage was initially set at w = w1 T,where wi T,cT i is the the optimal tax and transfer system which maximizes social welfare absent the minimum wage. Since w 1 cannot fall, labor supply responses are e ectively blocked (Figure 3). E cient rationing guarantees that individuals willing to leave occupation 1 are precisely those with the lowest surplus from working in occupation 1 relative to their next best option. Therefore, the dc 1 change is like a lump-sum tax reform and its net welfare e ect is simply [g 1 1] h 1 dc 1.Ifg 1 > 1, the introduction of the minimum wage improves upon the tax/transfer optimum allocation. This result shows that under the minimum wage policy, redistribution to low-skilled workers can be made lump-sum. Furthermore, raising the lump-sum transfer to occupation 1 improves welfare as long as g 1 > 1 and therefore the government will find optimal 3

Figure 2: to do it until g 1 = 1. With no behavioral responses an increase of $1 has a welfare e ect of h 0 g 0 +h 1 g 1 +h 2 g 2 and at the optimal the two are equal. Figure 3: To prove it formally, rewrite consumption in occupation i as c i = c i c 0 and the resource constraint as h 1 (w 1 c 1 )+h 2 (w 2 c 2 ) c 0. The Lagrangian of the problem is: L = SW + [h 1 (w 1 c 1 )+h 2 (w 2 c 2 ) c 0 ] Suppose there is a minimum wage and the government introduces a change dc 1, the wage of occupation 1 does not change because of the minimum wage and so does w 2 given that w 2 (w 1 ) (as we showed above). 4

As a consequence, there is no change in h 1 /h 2 = (w 2 /w 1 ) and no change in the levels of h 1 and h 2 since they cannot increase simultaneously. Therefore: dl = G 0 (c 0 + c 1 1 ) dh ( ) h 1 = [g 1 1] h 1 dc 1 1 At the optimum it must be g 1 = 1. Taking the FOC wrt c 0 we have: dl = (1 h 1 h 2 ) G 0 (c 0 )+ G 0 (c 0 + c 1 1 ) dh ( )+ dc 0 1 = [h 0 g 0 + h 1 g 1 + h 2 g 2 1] which proves Proposition 2. G 0 (c 0 + c 2 2 ) dh ( ) Pareto Improving Reform In this section we review the last result in Lee and Saez (2012) that shows how minimum wage and low-skilled labor subsidies can be complementary. Suppose there are extensive margin responses only, the participation tax rate of low-skilled workers 1 is 1 1 =(c 1 c 0 ) /w 1,such that c 1 = c 0 +(1 1 ) w 1. Proposition 3: In a model with extensive labor supply responses only, a binding minimum wage associated with a positive tax rate on minimum wage earnings ( 1 > 0) is second-best Pareto ine cient. This result remains a-fortiori true when rationing is not e cient. Suppose the government reduces the minimum wage by <0whilekeepingc 0, c 1 and c 2 constant. The change incentivizes unemployed individuals to enter occupation 1 generating a change dh 1 > 0 and increasing revenues since 1 > 0. The change dh 1 > 0 induces a change dw 2 > 0. However, since h 1 + h 2 dw 2 = 0 the mechanical e ect of changes in wages is zero. Since c 0, c 1 and c 2 are constant the total e ect of the government policy is only given by the increase in revenues, which is positive. Proposition 3 implies that, when labor supply responses are concentrated along the extensive margin, a minimum wage should always be associated with low-skilled work subsidies such as the EITC. To prove it formally notice that since consumption does not change at any occupation, the utility of those who do not switch jobs is not a ected. From the demand side, we have w 2 (w 1 )withdw 2 /dw 1 = h 1 /h 2 < 0 and hence dw 2 > 0. This implies that relative demand for high-skilled work h 2 /h 1 = (w 2 /w 1 ) decreases as ( ) is decreasing. Because c 2 c 0 remains constant, and labor supply is only along the extensive margin, the supply of high-skilled workers is unchanged so that dh 2 = 0, which then implies that dh 1 > 0. The dh 1 individuals shifting from no work to low-skilled work are weakly better-o because they were by definition rationed by the minimum wage (strictly better o in case of ine cient rationing). The government budget is h 1 (w 1 c 1 )+h 2 (w 2 c 2 ) c 0 0. Therefore, the net e ect of the reform on the budget is: dh 1 (w 1 c 1 )+h 1 dw 1 + h 2 dw 2 = dh 1 1 w 1 > 0. Thus, with 1 > 0, the reform creates a budget surplus which can be used to increase c 0 and improve everybody s welfare (with no behavioral response e ects), a Pareto improvement. References [1] David Lee & Emmanuel Saez, 2012. Optimal minimum wage policy in competitive labor markets, Journal of Public Economics, vol 96(9-10), pages 739-749. 5