How did forecasters respond to the American growth slowdown since the mid-2000s? Daniel Kirwin 1 and Gabriel Mathy 2 American University

Similar documents
The Making Of A Great Contraction. With A Liquidity Trap And A Jobless Recovery. Columbia University

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap

A NEW APPROACH FOR EVALUATING ECONOMIC FORECASTS

The Central Bank of Iceland forecasting record

Business Cycle Dating Committee of the Centre for Economic Policy Research. 1. The CEPR Business Cycle Dating Committee

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Topic 4 Forecasting Exchange Rate

As good as the rest? Comparing IMF forecasts with those of others

Forecast Errors Before and During the Great Moderation

WORKING PAPER NO DO GDP FORECASTS RESPOND EFFICIENTLY TO CHANGES IN INTEREST RATES?

Assessing recent external forecasts

Are 'unbiased' forecasts really unbiased? Another look at the Fed forecasts 1

Random Matrix Theory and the Failure of Macro-economic Forecasts

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor David Romer LECTURE 10

GDP forecast errors Satish Ranchhod

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Why Has the U.S. Economy Stagnated Since the Great Recession?

The Peril of the Inflation Exit Condition

Research Brief December 2018

Productivity Growth in Canada and the United States, Recent Trends and Determinants

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

S ince 1980, there has been a substantial

GDP growth and inflation forecasting performance of Asian Development Outlook

Introduction to Forecasting

Source: US. Bureau of Economic Analysis Shaded areas indicate US recessions research.stlouisfed.org

How Useful Are Forecasts of Corporate Profits?

Can a subset of forecasters beat the simple average in the SPF?

FORECAST ERRORS IN PRICES AND WAGES: THE EXPERIENCE WITH THREE PROGRAMME COUNTRIES

Interest Rate Determination & the Taylor Rule JARED BERRY & JAIME MARQUEZ JOHNS HOPKINS SCHOOL OF ADVANCED INTERNATIONAL STUDIES JANURY 2017

The Experimental Design - Helen s Love Life

OLD AND NEW CHALLENGES FOR FORECASTING: RECESSIONS, BOOMS, AND BIG DATA

The Making Of A Great Contraction With A Liquidity Trap and A Jobless Recovery

ESRI Research Note Nowcasting and the Need for Timely Estimates of Movements in Irish Output

The Making Of A Great Contraction With A Liquidity Trap and A Jobless Recovery

Chapter 3 economic growth and unemployment theoretical. Chapter 3 economic growth and unemployment theoretical.zip

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

A Textual Analysis of Bank of England Growth Forecasts

WORKING PAPER NO FISCAL SURPRISES AT THE FOMC

To understand the behavior of NR prices across key markets, during , with focus on:

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Citation Working Paper Series, F-39:

life. Each economic expansion has ultimately brought greater inflation, War II period, spending increases have persistently exceeded output

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

The Superiority of Greenbook Forecasts and the Role of Recessions

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data

Next week Professor Saez will discuss. This week John and I will

A Comparison of Business Cycle Regime Nowcasting Performance between Real-time and Revised Data. By Arabinda Basistha (West Virginia University)

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

Growth: Facts and Theories

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Volume Title: Dating Postwar Business Cycles: Methods and Their Application to Western Germany,

An Empirical Analysis of RMB Exchange Rate changes impact on PPI of China

Learning and Global Dynamics

A Discussion of Arouba, Cuba-Borda and Schorfheide: Macroeconomic Dynamics Near the ZLB: A Tale of Two Countries"

Euro-indicators Working Group

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

PubPol 201. Module 3: International Trade Policy. Class 4 Outline. Class 4 Outline. Class 4 China Shock

Fiscal Surprises at the FOMC

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

PJM Long-Term Load Forecasting Methodology: Proposal Regarding Economic Forecast (Planning Committee Agenda Item #5)

Nowcasting gross domestic product in Japan using professional forecasters information

Supplementary Materials for. Forecast Dispersion in Finite-Player Forecasting Games. March 10, 2017

NASCUS Summit August dwightjohnston.com

Looking for the stars

Inflation traps, and rules vs. discretion

LECTURE 3 The Effects of Monetary Changes: Statistical Identification. September 5, 2018

Urban Foundations. Early American Cities. Early American Cities. Early American Cities. Cities in America to 1945

Stellenbosch Economic Working Papers: 23/13 NOVEMBER 2013

GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT FOR NIGERIA

Early action simulations

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

MEASURING THE ECONOMIC MASS THE ALBANIAN CASE

Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method

Blocking Development

Lecture on State Dependent Government Spending Multipliers

Perceived productivity and the natural rate of interest

MA Macroeconomics 4. Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

Fresh perspectives on unobservable variables: Data decomposition of the Kalman smoother

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

NOWCASTING REPORT. Updated: July 20, 2018

NOWCASTING REPORT. Updated: August 17, 2018

Panel Discussion on Uses of Models at Central Banks

Quarterly Journal of Economics and Modelling Shahid Beheshti University SVAR * SVAR * **

Animal Spirits, Fundamental Factors and Business Cycle Fluctuations

CAN SOLAR ACTIVITY INFLUENCE THE OCCURRENCE OF RECESSIONS? Mikhail Gorbanev January 2015

Forecasting Australian Transport

Measuring the natural rate of interest: Alternative Specifications

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

Comments on A Model of Secular Stagnation by Gauti Eggertsson and Neil Mehrotra

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Differential Interpretation in the Survey of Professional Forecasters

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007

Johns Hopkins University Fall APPLIED ECONOMICS Regional Economics

NOWCASTING REPORT. Updated: January 4, 2019

Transcription:

How did forecasters respond to the American growth slowdown since the mid-2000s? Daniel Kirwin 1 and Gabriel Mathy 2 American University Abstract: Byrne et al. (2016) found that worldwide growth slowed down in the mid-2000s. This paper both confirms this result for the United States and looks at how forecasters responded to this slowdown in GDP growth. GDP is unambiguously and consistently below its forecasted level and so forecasts errors are persistently positive, consistent with a growth slowdown that is not forecasted in advance. In response to this slowdown, IMF and CBO forecasters adjusted their forecasts downwards while the Survey of Professional Forecasters made overoptimistic forecasts. We discuss the recent recession and its potential contribution to the current secular stagnation. Keywords: Forecast errors, growth slowdown, secular stagnation, hysteresis JEL Codes: E17, E37, O47 1 4400 Massachusetts Avenue NW, Washington, DC, 20016, dk9805a@student.american.edu. 2 Corresponding Author, 4400 Massachusetts Avenue NW, Washington, DC, 20016, mathy@american.edu.. The support of the Institute of New Economic Thinking is much appreciated. Portions of this paper were written when this author was visiting at George Washington University s Research Program on Forecasting and their hospitality is much appreciated.

Introduction Since the mid-2000s, the global economy has seen weak GDP growth (Cette et al., 2016), even in economies recovering from one of the worst global recessions since the Great Depression. A literature has developed to explain this growth slowdown, which some have labeled secular stagnation (Summers, 2015; Gordon, 2015). Some of this may be due to hysteresis, as the deep recession may have reduced potential output in the United States (Summers, 2014). We define this slowdown in potential GDP growth as secular stagnation, and we look at how forecasters dealt with this growth slowdown. Firstly, we document how much lower GDP is relative to forecasts, and we show that the loss of GDP is significant, consistent with the secular stagnation hypothesis. Secondly, we decompose this growth slowdown into forecast errors and downward revisions in forecasts. If potential GDP is growing more slowly than it had before, then forecasters can do one of two things. If forecasters continue to base their forecasts on potential GDP growth that prevailed before the slowdown, then these forecasters will make consistently positive (overoptimistic) forecast errors. If forecasters reduce their average forecasts then the forecasts will not be overoptimistic. 3 As forecasters tend to use recent experience to forecast trend growth, they make persistent forecast errors during the early phases of the slowdown. If forecasters can realize that trend growth has slowed, then they will revise their (average) growth forecasts downward. The larger the revision to the forecasts, the smaller the forecast error, and vice versa. We analyze data from the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), International Monetary Fund (IMF), and Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF), and find that the CBO and IMF primarily downgraded their growth forecasts and did not made persistently overoptimistic forecasts, while the SPF significantly over-estimated growth initially before making downward revisions as well. Finally, we discuss whether forecasters were aware of this change or not, and when they became aware that growth had slowed. The remainder of this paper is structured as follows: section one provides background on the topics discussed in this paper; section two 3 Naturally an overcorrection would be possible where forecasters would downgrade their forecasts so much they make persistently pessimistic forecasts for GDP, but we do not find evidence of such an overshooting.

contains the results of my data analysis; section three discusses the results of the data analysis; section four concludes the paper. I. Background In his 1939 Presidential address to the American Economic Association, Alvin Hansen put forward an explanation for the United States tepid recovery from the Great Depressions as being caused by inadequate aggregate demand and excess savings, which was primarily the result of slowing population growth. It was in this speech that Hansen coined the term secular stagnation. The idea never received lasting prominence in the 20 th century most likely because the postwar boom that followed the Great Depression and World War II turned out very differently than Hansen s prediction (Eggertsson & Mehrotra, 2014). However, the idea of secular stagnation has returned to the forefront of debates in the wake of the tepid recovery from the Great Recession. Summers (2013) revived the idea of secular stagnation as the cause of the slow recovery from the Great Recession. Summers (2015) builds upon his original IMF speech, arguing that the United States may have been in a secular stagnation equilibrium for some time and that the economy only recovered to potential output due to extraordinary increases in demand stemming from the dot-com stock bubble and the housing bubble. Summers (2015) builds on Hansen s (1939) original argument regarding declining population growth. However, he extends the argument by showing that global inflation and real interest rates have been steadily declining; this has lead investment demand to fall while global savings increase as a result of stricter capital requirements, increasing inequality, tax policies and the increasing costs of financial intermediation. Eichengreen (2015) agrees with this approach using similar explanations for why the U.S. is facing secular stagnation. Krugman (2014) extends Summer s (2013) arguments by connecting the zero-lower bound on interest rates and the liquidity trap to secular stagnation. Krugman (2014) postulates, and Eggertsson and Mehrotra (2014) formalize, that fiscal stimulus may be the only way to propel the U.S. out of a secular stagnation equilibrium, due to a reluctance by central bankers to produce sufficient inflation. Finally, Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2012) and Benigno and Fornaro (2015) model the interactions between the zero-lower bound with negative confidence shocks as

a way to explain the lackluster recovery that United States has seen since the global financial crisis. Robert Gordon takes a supply-side approach to explaining secular stagnation. In Gordon (2012) he argues that lower future growth will occur in part because it was major technological advancements that propelled growth in the past century and a half, and there are no longer any meaningful advancements to be made. Gordon (2014) also argues that it is plateauing educational attainment, labor productivity rates, and stagnating wages that are causing secular stagnation. Gagnon et al. (2016) also find that declining population growth and the end of the IT boom will lead to a new normal of slower growth. In a paper closely related to ours, Ball (2014) shows how potential output across the globe was revised downward since the Great Recession. Using OECD and IMF forecasts for potential output growth, Ball (2014) finds that the crisis and ensuing recession caused a 4.7% loss in potential output and that the current gap between potential and actual output as of 2014 was 3.4% of current potential output. 4 II. Empirics In order to gauge the existence of a slowdown in growth and whether the forecasters are aware of any slowdown, we looked at growth forecast data from three sources: the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), the International Monetary Fund (IMF) s World Economic Outlook (WEO), and the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF). Dominguez and Shapiro (2013) found that IMF and SPF forecasts had been consistently revised downward in the years since the recovery began. For the CBO, we also look at potential GDP forecasts, while for the others we use actual GDP forecasts. We build on the results of Dominguez and Shapiro (2013) with regard to the IMF WEO forecast revisions, to observe the extent to which the CBO, IMF, and SPF produce over-optimistic or pessimistic forecasts, and whether or not there are any meaningful revisions to the CBO and SPF forecasts. CBO 4 It is interesting to note that Ball s (2014) results for U.S. losses of potential GDP were actually lower than most other countries.

For the CBO we compare the published forecasts for potential output growth to the actual path of GDP. In 8 of 12 observations of the difference between the one-year ahead forecast and the historic value is an overestimate of economic growth. Furthermore, all ten observations of the difference between two-year ahead forecast and the historic value were over-estimates as well. We also looked at the revision history of the available forecasts from the first forecast to the last, which provided 22 observations from 2004 through 2025. Of the 22 observations, 15 have been revised downwards reflecting lower expected growth. Furthermore, all but two years between 2015 and 2025 have been revised downward. For the CBO Potential GDP forecasts, revisions are consistently downward throughout most of the time period, consistent with Ball (2014). 5 Not only is the consistency of downward revisions notable, but the adjustment to the potential growth rate is as well. As has also been documented before, the downward movement in potential GDP is also staggering (Figure 1). Save for the forecast in February of 2014, every year the CBO has revised their forecast for potential GDP significantly downward. The first forecast for potential GDP in 2016Q1 was released in 2006Q1. In the time between the two forecasts, the CBO revised their outlook for potential GDP downward by nearly 13%. IMF The IMF proved to have very accurate forecasts. The summary mean of their historical World Economic Outlook database growth forecast was over-estimated by 0.1315%, and the median was over-estimated by 0.14%. Neither of these values were statistically significant. We also looked at the revision history in order to see if Dominguez & Shapiro s (2013) result would hold and there would be consistent downward revisions. 6 Of the 51 observations of the difference between the two years ahead forecast and the one-year ahead forecast, 27 (53%) were downward (Figure 2). What is more striking, however, is the number of times that the IMF revised their forecasts downward in the period between 2005 and 2015. Out of 22 forecasts in the sample, forecasts were revised downward 73% of the time between the two-year ahead forecast and the one year-ahead forecast. Furthermore, between the three- and four-year ahead forecasts 6 It is important to note that we use both the second and the fourth quarter WEO forecasts in order to have as much data as possible. On the other hand, Dominguez & Shapiro (2013) use only the second quarter forecasts in order to analyze the Eurozone crisis between 2010 and 2012.

and the one-year-ahead forecasts, the IMF downgraded their growth outlook 91% of the time in the same time period (Figures 3 and 4). What is more, there were downward revisions in the all but two of the differences forecasts between the three years ahead and one year ahead forecasts and in all of differences between four years ahead forecasts and the one-year ahead forecast beginning in 2006. Altogether, the cumulative downward revisions between the four years ahead forecast and the one-year ahead forecast are striking. Between 2000 and 2015, the IMF downgraded their growth outlook by almost 26.5%. When the sample is limited to the time period between 2005 and 2015, the cumulative negative revisions total nearly a 30% decline in forecasted growth. Between the three years ahead forecast and the one-year ahead forecast, the cumulative downward revisions total nearly 26% and 26.5% for the 2000-2015 and 2005-2015 time periods, respectively. Finally, the cumulative revisions downward between the two years ahead forecast and the one-year ahead forecast are 8.4% and 9.9% for the two time periods. SPF The SPF data paints a more nuanced picture of private forecaster s expectations for the economy. Dominguez and Shapiro (2013) discuss the revision history of the SPF forecast data in some depth, so our focus is on the differences between forecaster s expectations and reality. Based on our hypothesis that the errors do not begin to surface until after the 1990 s, the data are split into two sub periods. First we tested to see if the errors or revisions begin in 2000, so the data are broken into the subgroups 1990-1999 and 2000-present. We then test the 1990-2004 and 2005-present periods to see if we can confirm the finding in Byrne et al. (2016) that economic growth slowed in in 2004. Recessions are difficult to forecast and thus tend to generate overestimates (Fildes and Stekler, 2002), so we exclude those periods in our analysis, as we would find overestimates even without a growth slowdown. In all of the subgroups, once recessions are removed, there is statistical significance for the forecast errors being different from zero for both the initial value of growth and the final value of growth. 7 Somewhat surprisingly, the forecast errors are consistently of larger magnitude and thus more statistically significant for the final value of GDP than the initial value of GDP

(Figures 5b, 6b, 7b, and 8b). We suspect this is due to revisions in GDP growth related to changes in the growth of potential GDP, such that the revisions are negative when growth is slowing (and forecasters over predict growth) and vice versa. Interestingly, the forecast errors for the earlier subgroups, 1990-1999 and 1990-2004 contain statistically significant underestimates of growth (Tables 1 and 3). Based on the differences between the significance statistics of the data in the 1990-1999 and 1990-2004 subgroups and qualitative analysis of figures 5-8, it seems fair to say that forecasters underestimated growth in the United States for the latter half of the 1990's. This is unsurprising, as the effects of computers and IT manifested themselves as surprisingly rapid productivity growth during that period (Jorgenson et al., 2008). On the other hand, the subgroups from 2000-2016 and 2005-2016 contain significant overestimates of growth (Tables 1 and 3; Figures 7a-8b). It appears that the forecasts become consistently tilted towards over-optimistic growth outlooks around the fourth quarter of 2004 or the first quarter of 2005. What is even more interesting is that the SPF are continuing to make errors even with revised data that more accurately reflects the underlying state of the economy. The revisions for the overall sample from 1991-present are statistically significantly different from zero both with and without recessions included in the data series. However, when the data are broken in to the subgroups described above, only the 2000-present and 2005-present subgroups remain statistically significantly different from zero. When recessions are removed from the data set, the revisions to forecasts in the 2005-present subgroup are the most statistically significant of all of the revision results in being different than zero. III. Discussion There are three main results to be drawn from the data. First, the combination of forecast errors and downward revisions from all three sources we considered point to a significant slowdown in potential and realized growth consistent with the secular stagnation hypothesis. Second, there does not seem to be a significant difference between private sector forecasters and public sector and NGO forecasts. Finally, the data suggests that secular stagnation is not a characteristic of the U.S. economy brought about by the Great Recession, but rather has been present since around the middle of the last decade. Furthermore, there does not appear to be any

reason to believe that over-optimism is a characteristic of private sector forecasters. While the IMF was the first of the sources we looked at to become aware of the slowdown, all three have begun to revise growth forecasts downward. Though our findings regarding the revision histories of the IMF and SPF are not novel, we extend this question to forecast errors and the CBO and shed new light on the secular stagnation hypothesis. It is fairly clear that economic growth, both realized and potential, is significantly lower than what was expected at the turn of the century. As shown by CBO forecasts of potential growth (Figure 1), the output gap is shrinking only because potential growth forecasts have been revised consistently downward. The consistent downward revisions to the IMF and SPF actual growth forecasts, as well as the SPF's forecast errors at the longer time horizons, are all consistent with a new, lower growth equilibrium for the U.S. economy once the output gap is fully closed. What is even more interesting is that we can pinpoint an approximate time period in which we find that secular stagnation began to affect the U.S. economy. The revision and error data seem to become particularly significant around the end of 2004 or beginning of 2005. Not only is this where Byrne et al. (2016) found that growth had slowed down, it is also around this time that Laubach and Williams (2003[2016]) (LW) estimated that the natural rate of interest began to fall consistently, another symptom of secular stagnation. 89 As LW shows, in the aftermath of the 2001 recession, the natural rate was trendless rather than rising as it had in previous recoveries. Afterwards, the natural rate fell further still, surpassing its previous nadir. The start of the natural rate's downward march corresponds to around the middle of 2004, at the same time as forecasters made persistent errors and begin to revise downward their forecasts. Furthermore, it is also in this 2003-2005 period that productivity peaked (Figure 9). Based on these factors, it appears plausible that secular 8 Laubauch and Williams (2015) describe the natural rate of interest as the real short-term interest rate consistent with the economy operating at its full potential once transitory shocks to aggregate supply or demand have abated. The original paper provides a more comprehensive definition than is present here. 9 While Gordon (1979) found that productivity does tend to slow down toward the end of expansions are firms continue to hire even as output growth begins slowing, 2004 is roughly the midpoint between the end of the 2001 recession and the start of the 2007-2009 recession and so is early to see an end of expansion effect.

stagnation did affect the U.S. economy prior to the Great Recession, likely between 2003 and 2005. It also seems quite plausible that there is a link between the global savings glut (GSG) (Bernanke 2005) and secular stagnation in the United States, though a full discussion is beyond the scope of this paper. Bernanke (2005) outlines several factors that led to large capital inflows to the U.S. in the late 1990 s and early 2000 s. While the popping of the stock bubble decreased the demand for these savings 10, the supply of savings remained relatively unchanged, which pushed down real interest rates (Bernanke, 2005). Indeed, this is consistent with the picture that Summers (2015) draws about the factors that have led the U.S. towards secular stagnation, with bubbles necessary to keep growth going. Summers (2013) also discusses the slowdown in growth after the end of the bubbles in Japan is the late 1980s, which lead to a similar slowdown and secular stagnation for two decades (Fukao et al.,2015). Japan also experienced a liquidity trap during this period, consistent with a reduced natural rate of interest and low interest rates intended to accelerate growth (Krugman 1998). Again, the parallels to the United States are striking, with a slowdown in growth after the bursting of bubbles followed by liquidity trap conditions. The Great Recession absolutely appears to have exacerbated the issue: in the time period between 2007 and the second quarter of 2015, the natural rate of interest fell another 2.3% to levels around or below 1% (Laubauch and Williams, 2015). However, based on the trends of forecast errors and revisions, it appears likely that secular stagnation has been underlying the U.S. economy since well before the Great Recession with the Great Recession only made the issue worse. 11 The other primary conclusion that can be drawn from the data is that there seems to be no simple way to categorize the different reactions of forecasters between the forecasts. The SPF are initially unable to forecast slowing growth on longer time horizons and are consistently overoptimistic until around two quarters ahead when they revise their forecasts downwards. The IMF and the CBO revise their forecasts downward on a regular basis, which would suggest that they 10 Indeed, Cardella and Ueda (2006) of the IMF, among others, document the massive amount cash that large corporations hoarded in the aftermath of the dot-com bubble and early 2000 s recession. 11 The evidence of the Great Recession s effect comes from the LW (2015) model, which shows a drastic drop off in the natural rate. Ball s (2014) documented loss of output, and the magnitude of forecast errors and revisions by forecasters from the same event.

are aware of slowing growth trends. The CBO, like the IMF, has revised their forecasts consistently downward. IV. Conclusion This paper has several key findings. Firstly, growth did deaccelerate in the United States roughly in the past decade. This slowdown in growth has coincided with other features of secular stagnation such as a declining natural rate, as shown by LW (2016). However, it does not seem as though secular stagnation is only an illness born out of the Great Recession. Rather, secular stagnation arose a few years before the start of the Great Recession, as Cette et al. (2016) have also shown. We confirm these findings, using evidence from several forecasters. In response to this growth slowdown, forecasters either realized growth was slowing down, in which case they revised their forecasts downwards, or they assumed that growth would continue as before, in which case they made persistently optimistic forecasts. We find that the IMF largely did the former while the CBO and SPF largely continued to make overoptimistic forecasts. Between 2005 and 2015 the IMF downgraded their forecasts for American GDP by almost 26.5%, while the forecasts for 2016Q1 from the CBO are 13% lower than they were forecasted to be ten years before. As more data becomes available, we will see if secular stagnation will persistent in the American economy or if this was simply a decade-long slowdown. Based on the results of this paper, a series of over-pessimistic output forecasts or upward revisions in forecasts of growth will be one indicator that growth has accelerated, reversing previous trends, while an eventual end to overoptimistic forecasts and downward revisions will mean that forecasters have learned to accept the new normal: secular stagnation.

Date 2005Q2 2005Q4 2006Q2 2006Q4 2007Q2 2007Q4 2008Q2 2008Q4 2009Q2 2009Q4 2010Q2 2010Q4 2011Q2 2011Q4 2012Q2 2012Q4 2013Q2 2013Q4 2014Q2 2014Q4 2015Q2 2015Q4 2016Q2 2016Q4 2017Q2 2017Q4 2018Q2 2018Q4 2019Q2 2019Q4 2020Q2 2020Q4 2021Q2 2021Q4 2022Q2 2022Q4 2023Q2 2023Q4 2024Q2 2024Q4 2025Q2 2025Q4 2026Q2 Potential GDP (in billions) 22000 Appendix A: Graphs Figure 1: CBO Potential GDP 2006-2016 21000 20000 19000 18000 17000 16000 15000 14000 13000 Jan-06 Jan-08 Jan-10 Jan-12 Feb-14 Jan-16 Real GDP Notes: CBO Potential GDP from CBO Economic Outlook. Potential GDP is in 2009 chained dollars. The CBO s outlook for potential GDP has been consistently revised downward in the forecasts between 2005 and 2016.

Difference in Percent Figure 2: Difference between two years ahead and one year ahead forecast (IMF) 4 3 2 1 0-1 -2-3 -4 Year Note: IMF forecast data from IMF WEO. The spring forecasts are used as they have more information than the fall forecasts. Difference in Percent is percent difference between the initial forecasts at two, three, and four years ahead, respectively, and the oneyear ahead forecast. Forecast revisions have been primarily downward since 2005. The effect of the Great Recession is apparent in the large downward revisions in 2007-09 and the correction that followed in 2010. Black box is period of negative errors since 2005.

Difference in Percent Figure 3: Difference between three years ahead and one year ahead forecast (IMF) 4 3 2 1 0-1 -2-3 -4-5 -6-7 Year Note: IMF forecast data from IMF WEO. The spring forecasts are used as they have more information than the fall forecasts. Difference in Percent is percent difference between the initial forecasts at two, three, and four years ahead, respectively, and the oneyear ahead forecast. IMF forecast revisions were upward (positive) in the mid and late 1990 s. However, beginning in 2004, all but four WEO publications in the sample revised growth forecasts downwards. Black box is period of negative errors since 2005.

Difference in Percent Figure 4: Difference between four years ahead and one year ahead forecast (IMF) 4 3 2 1 0-1 -2-3 -4-5 -6-7 Year Note: IMF forecast data from IMF WEO. The spring forecasts are used as they have more information than the fall forecasts. Difference in Percent is percent difference between the initial forecasts at two, three, and four years ahead, respectively, and the oneyear ahead forecast. IMF forecast revisions were upward (positive) in the mid and late 1990 s. However, beginning in 2004, all but three WEO publications in the sample revised growth forecasts downwards. Black box is period of negative errors since 2005.

Error in Percent Figure 5a: 1990-2004 Survey of Professional Forecasters Nowcast Initial Errors 10 8 6 4 2 0-2 -4-6 -8-10 Quarter Note: Survey of Professional Forecasters errors from Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank. Throughout the mid and late 1990 s, forecasters fairly consistently had negative forecast errors (underestimated growth). The early-2000 s recession creates positive forecast errors and then an over-correction in the following two quarters.

Error in Percent Figure 5b: 1990-2004 Survey of Professional Forecasters Nowcast Final Errors 10 8 6 4 2 0-2 -4-6 -8-10 Quarter Note: Survey of Professional Forecasters errors from Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank. Throughout the mid and late 1990 s, forecasters fairly consistently had negative forecast errors (underestimated growth). This trend is more apparent in the errors of the forecasts compared to the final revision of GDP. The effect of the recession in the early-2000 s on forecast errors is also more apparent in the final errors, as shown by the errors in the 2000Q2 and 2001Q4.

Error in Percent Figure 6a: 1990-2004 Survey of Professional Forecasters 4 Quarters Ahead Initial Errors 10 8 6 4 2 0-2 -4-6 -8-10 Quarter Note: Survey of Professional Forecasters errors from Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank. The 4 quarters ahead forecasts produce larger and less volatile errors, both positive and negative. The larger errors make the overall trends more apparent and show clearly the under-estimates of growth in the mid and late 1990 s.

Error in Percent Figure 6b: 1990-2004 Survey of Professional Forecasters 4 Quarters Ahead Final Errors 10 8 6 4 2 0-2 -4-6 -8-10 Quarter Note: Survey of Professional Forecasters errors from Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank. The 4 quarters ahead forecasts produce larger errors, both positive and negative. The larger errors make the overall trends more apparent and show the under-estimates of growth in the mid and late 1990 s. In addition, the comparison of the forecasts to the final revision of GDP data produces larger errors as well that further amplify the trends.

Error in Percent 2005:01 2005:02 2005:03 2005:04 2006:01 2006:02 2006:03 2006:04 2007:01 2007:02 2007:03 2007:04 2008:01 2008:02 2008:03 2008:04 2009:01 2009:02 2009:03 2009:04 2010:01 2010:02 2010:03 2010:04 2011:01 2011:02 2011:03 2011:04 2012:01 2012:02 2012:03 2012:04 2013:01 2013:02 2013:03 2013:04 2014:01 2014:02 2014:03 2014:04 2015:01 2015:02 2015:03 2015:04 2016:01 Figure 7a: 2005-2016 Survey of Professional Forecasters Nowcast Initial Errors 10 8 6 4 2 0-2 -4-6 -8-10 Quarter Note: Survey of Professional Forecasters errors from Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank. Consistent with Byrne et al. (2016), forecast errors become consistently positive around 2005 indicating over-estimates of growth. Though the effect of the Great Recession on forecast errors is present, the over-estimations are still significant when recessions are removed.

Error in Percent 2005:01 2005:02 2005:03 2005:04 2006:01 2006:02 2006:03 2006:04 2007:01 2007:02 2007:03 2007:04 2008:01 2008:02 2008:03 2008:04 2009:01 2009:02 2009:03 2009:04 2010:01 2010:02 2010:03 2010:04 2011:01 2011:02 2011:03 2011:04 2012:01 2012:02 2012:03 2012:04 2013:01 2013:02 2013:03 2013:04 2014:01 2014:02 2014:03 2014:04 2015:01 2015:02 2015:03 2015:04 2016:01 Figure 7b: 2005-2016 Survey of Professional Forecasters Nowcast Final Errors 10 8 6 4 2 0-2 -4-6 -8-10 Quarter Note: Survey of Professional Forecasters errors from Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank. Also consistent with Byrne et al. (2016), the forecast errors turn positive in 2005 indicating over-estimation of growth. Furthermore, the final errors again are larger than the initial errors and show the trend more distinctly.

Error in Percent 2005:01 2005:02 2005:03 2005:04 2006:01 2006:02 2006:03 2006:04 2007:01 2007:02 2007:03 2007:04 2008:01 2008:02 2008:03 2008:04 2009:01 2009:02 2009:03 2009:04 2010:01 2010:02 2010:03 2010:04 2011:01 2011:02 2011:03 2011:04 2012:01 2012:02 2012:03 2012:04 2013:01 2013:02 2013:03 2013:04 2014:01 2014:02 2014:03 2014:04 2015:01 Figure 8a: 2005-2016 Survey of Professional Forecasters 4 Quarters Ahead Initial Errors 10 8 6 4 2 0-2 -4-6 -8-10 Quarter Note: Survey of Professional Forecasters errors from Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank. Consistent with Byrne et al. (2016), the forecast errors turn positive in 2005 indicating over-estimation of growth. The 4 quarters ahead forecast is shows the consistently over-estimation of growth by forecasters with less volatility than the nowcast. It also more clearly illustrates the effects of recessions on forecasts; there is a significantly large over estimation of growth in 2008Q1 followed by an over correction in the following few quarters.

Error in Percent 2005:01 2005:02 2005:03 2005:04 2006:01 2006:02 2006:03 2006:04 2007:01 2007:02 2007:03 2007:04 2008:01 2008:02 2008:03 2008:04 2009:01 2009:02 2009:03 2009:04 2010:01 2010:02 2010:03 2010:04 2011:01 2011:02 2011:03 2011:04 2012:01 2012:02 2012:03 2012:04 2013:01 2013:02 2013:03 2013:04 2014:01 2014:02 2014:03 2014:04 2015:01 Figure 8b: 2005-2016 Survey of Professional Forecasters 4 quarter Ahead Final Errors 10 8 6 4 2 0-2 -4-6 -8-10 Quarter Note: Survey of Professional Forecasters errors from Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank. Consistent with Byrne et al. (2016), the forecast errors turn positive in 2005 indicating over-estimation of growth. The error between the final revision of GDP and the forecast once again is larger and shows the consistent over-estimations of growth more clearly. The 4 quarters ahead forecasts have the same amplifying effect on the forecast errors.

Figure 9: Productivity 7.0 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0-1.0 Productivity Average productivity 1990-2005 Average productivity 2006-present One-sided r* Note: Bureau of Labor and Statistics data for Nonfarm Business Sector: Real Output Per Hour of All Persons retrieved from Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis with Laubach/Williams (2003[2016]) one-sided estimate of r*. Beginning in late 2003, productivity begins to fall rather rapidly. Though it recovers during the Great Recession, it has fallen again to historically low levels. This timing is consistent with Byrne et al. (2016) s timing of the productivity slowdown. The estimates of r* also begin to fall around the beginning of 2004 and have yet to recover, further supporting the assertion that the growth slowdown happened between 2003 and 2005.

Appendix B: Tables 1. Forecast errors of Survey of Professional Forecasters, Pre-2000 Forecast Horizon Initial p-value Initial t-stat Revised p-value Final t-stat Now 0.005939*** -2.92956 1.40E-05*** -5.02303 1Q 0.003347*** -3.14866 0.000354*** -3.94444 2Q 0.007732*** -2.82627 0.000911*** -3.61523 3Q 0.044752** -2.08166 0.01044** -2.70221 4Q 0.013416** -2.60445 0.00122*** -3.51112 2. Forecast errors of Survey of Professional Forecasters, 2000-Present Forecast Horizon Initial p-value Initial t-stat Revised p-value Final t-stat Now 0.729483 0.347647 0.206641 1.278507 1Q 0.098887* 1.680357 0.051833* 1.990245 2Q 0.010619** 2.652645 0.005905*** 2.873478 3Q 0.004242*** 2.996596 0.005647*** 2.89243 4Q 0.000475*** 3.745066 0.000393*** 3.805837

3. Forecast errors of Survey of Professional Forecasters, Pre-2005 Forecast Horizon Initial p-value Initial t-stat Revised p-value Revised t-stat Now 0.008768*** -2.72586 0.000338*** -3.83822 1Q 0.027251** -2.27329 0.009446*** -2.69547 2Q 0.069275* -1.85573 0.025203** -2.30479 3Q 0.26127-1.13599 0.096465* -1.69286 4Q 0.277178-1.09843 0.047636** -2.02859 4. Forecast errors of Survey of Professional Forecasters, 2005-Present Forecast Horizon Initial p-value Initial t-stat Revised p-value Revised t-stat Now 0.214569 1.2628 0.06569* 1.8967 1Q 0.092886* 1.7262 0.039901** 2.132 2Q 0.011638** 2.6625 0.015127** 2.5549 3Q 0.00099*** 3.6042 0.007849*** 2.8253 4Q 0.000108*** 4.396 0.000683*** 3.7483 Notes: Results for a statistical test for differences of mean from zero. * is <10% significance, ** is <5% significance level, *** is <1% significance level. All tables exclude NBER recession periods. Survey of Professional Forecasts data from Philadelphia Federal Reserve, various releases. We consider both the errors from the initial forecast as well as those from the revised (final) data.

Referenced works Laurence Ball, (2014). "Long-term damage from the Great Recession in OECD countries," European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies: Intervention, Edward Elgar, vol. 11(2), pages 149-160, September. Benhabib, Jess, and Yi Wen. "Indeterminacy, aggregate demand, and the real business cycle." Journal of Monetary Economics 51.3 (2004): 503-530. Benigno, Gianluca and Fornaro, Luca. (2015), Stagnation Traps, No 832, Working Papers, Barcelona Graduate School of Economics. Bernanke, B. (2005). The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit, Remarks at the Sandridge Lecture, 19 March. Byrne, David M., Fernald, John G. and Reinsdorf, Marshall B., (2016), Does the United States Have a Productivity Slowdown or a Measurement Problem? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 47, issue 1 (Spring), p. 109-182. Cardarelli, Roberto, and Kenichi Ueda. "Awash with Cash: Why Are Corporate Savings So High?." World Economic Outlook April 2006 (2006): 135-59. Cette, Gilbert, John Fernald, and Benoît Mojon. "The pre-great Recession slowdown in productivity." European Economic Review (2016). Council of Economic Advisers. (2015), Long-Term Interest Rates: A Survey, July. Dominguez, Kathryn ME, and Matthew D. Shapiro. "Forecasting the Recovery from the Great Recession: Is This Time Different?" The American Economic Review 103.3 (2013): 147-152. Eggertsson, Gauti B., and Neil R. Mehrotra. A model of secular stagnation. No. w20574. National Bureau of Economic Research, 2014. Eichengreen, B. (2014), Secular stagnation: A review of the issues. In C. Tueling and R. Baldwin (Eds.), Secular stagnation: Facts, causes and cures (pp. 41-46). London, UK: Centre for Economic Policy Research Press. Eichengreen, Barry. "Secular stagnation: the long view." The American Economic Review 105.5 (2015): 66-70. Fildes, Robert, and Herman Stekler, "The state of macroeconomic forecasting." Journal of macroeconomics 24.4 (2002): 435-468. Fukao, K., Ikeuchi, K., Kwon, H. U., Kim, Y., Makino, T., & Takizawa, M., 2015."Lessons from

Japan's Secular Stagnation," Discussion papers 15124, Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI). Gagnon, Etienne, Benjamin Kramer Johannsen, and J. David Lopez-Salido, "Understanding the New Normal: The Role of Demographics." FEDS Working Paper No. 2016-080 (2016). Gordon, Robert J. "The" End-of-Expansion" Phenomenon in Short-Run Productivity Behavior." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1979.2 (1979): 447-461. Gordon, Robert J. Is US economic growth over? Faltering innovation confronts the six headwinds. No. w18315. National Bureau of Economic Research, 2012. Gordon, Robert J. (2014), The turtle s progress: Secular stagnation meets headwinds. In C. Tueling and R. Baldwin (Eds.), Secular stagnation: Facts, causes and cures (pp. 47-59). London, UK: Centre for Economic Policy Research Press. Gordon, Robert J. "Secular stagnation: A supply-side view." The American Economic Review 105.5 (2015): 54-59. Hansen, Alvin H. "Economic progress and declining population growth." The American Economic Review 29.1 (1939): 1-15. Jorgenson, Dale W., Mun S. Ho, and Kevin J. Stiroh. "A retrospective look at the US productivity growth resurgence." The Journal of Economic Perspectives 22.1 (2008): 3-24. Krugman, Paul R., Kathryn M. Dominquez, and Kenneth Rogoff. "It's baaack: Japan's slump and the return of the liquidity trap." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1998.2 (1998): 137-205. Krugman, P. (2014). Four observations on secular stagnation. In C. Tueling and R. Baldwin (Eds.), Secular stagnation: Facts, causes and cures (pp. 61-68). London, UK: Centre for Economic Policy Research Press. Laubach, Thomas, and John C. Williams. "Measuring the natural rate of interest." Review of Economics and Statistics 85.4 (2003): 1063-1070. Laubach, Thomas & Williams, John C., 2015. "Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest Redux," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2016-11, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.). Lo, Stephanie and Rogoff, Kenneth, (2015), Secular stagnation, debt overhang and other rationales for sluggish growth, six years on, No 482, BIS Working Papers, Bank for International Settlements. Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie, and Martín Uribe. The making of a great contraction with a liquidity

trap and a jobless recovery. No. w18544. National Bureau of Economic Research, 2012. Summers, Lawrence H. "US economic prospects: Secular stagnation, hysteresis, and the zero lower bound." Business Economics 49.2 (2014): 65-73. Summers, Lawrence H. "Demand side secular stagnation." The American Economic Review 105.5 (2015): 60-65.