TECHNICAL APPENDIX. 7. Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case

Similar documents

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

14.05: Section Handout #1 Solow Model

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Topics in Trade: Slides

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

Income Distribution Dynamics with Endogenous Fertility. By Michael Kremer and Daniel Chen

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Answers Econ 805

Dynare Class on Heathcote-Perri JME 2002

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Does Pleasing Export-Oriented Foreign Investors Help Your. Balance of Payments? A General Equilibrium Analysis. (Available on Request Appendix)

Addendum to: New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?

The Harris-Todaro model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Team Production and the Allocation of Creativity across Global and Local Sectors

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Eaton Kortum Model (2002)

Online Appendix The Growth of Low Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market. By David H. Autor and David Dorn

Technological Spillovers and Dynamics of Comparative Advantage

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

External Economies of Scale and International Trade: Further Analysis

One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

4.4 The functional distribution of income

Notes on Winnie Choi s Paper (Draft: November 4, 2004; Revised: November 9, 2004)

The General Neoclassical Trade Model

Masanori Yokoo. 1 Introduction

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Florian Hoffmann. September - December Vancouver School of Economics University of British Columbia

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Monopolistic Competition when Income Matters

On the dynamics of the Heckscher-Ohlin theory

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Train the model with a subset of the data. Test the model on the remaining data (the validation set) What data to choose for training vs. test?

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

The Case of the Missing Trade and other Mysteries: Comment. Data Appendix

Blocking Development

The Solow Model in Discrete Time Allan Drazen October 2017

The Heckscher-Ohlin model: Mathematical treatment*

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach

AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES

The Hansen Singleton analysis

Internation1al Trade

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

f( x) f( y). Functions which are not one-to-one are often called many-to-one. Take the domain and the range to both be all the real numbers:

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation

Lecture 4: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model With Many Goods and Factors

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION

5. Externalities and Public Goods

Under-Employment and the Trickle-Down of Unemployment - Online Appendix Not for Publication

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 2 : Balance Growth Paths

Adding Production to the Theory

Preferences and Utility

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

A Harris-Todaro Agent-Based Model to Rural-Urban Migration

( )! ±" and g( x)! ±" ], or ( )! 0 ] as x! c, x! c, x! c, or x! ±". If f!(x) g!(x) "!,

Professor: Alan G. Isaac These notes are very rough. Suggestions welcome. Samuelson (1938, p.71) introduced revealed preference theory hoping

arxiv:physics/ v1 [physics.soc-ph] 27 Oct 2005

International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath

Internet Appendix for: Social Risk, Fiscal Risk, and the Portfolio of Government Programs

Economic Growth: Lecture 12, Directed Technological Change

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

The Lucas Imperfect Information Model

Online Appendix: Property Rights Over Marital Transfers

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Econ 8601: Industrial Organization (Thomas J. Holmes) Lecture 1. Part 1: The Cost of Monopoly in General Equilibrium. μ 1

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Gravity Models, PPML Estimation and the Bias of the Robust Standard Errors

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

EconS Cost Structures

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Walrasian Equilibrium Computation, Network Formation, and the Wen Theorem

Transcription:

TECHNICAL APPENDIX 7 Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case A closed form solution for production and trade obtains if we assume that utility is a Cobb-Douglas function of the consumption bundle: u x x Here, x denotes consumption With some judicious substitution, we obtain a closed form solution for the quantities in four steps First, we obtain a solution for the import relative share The combination of the efficiency conditions (5) for imports and (6) for output implies u ( )u p B a / a p For the Cobb-Douglas case this implies x ( / x ) ( ) (x B / x ) p a / a p ( ) x B B / x Here, we have used the fact that x y +m in each state Now note that x B / x y /(y + m ) Solving this expression for the import relative share m we obtain /( ) m (7) ( )p f ( p,,, ), y ( a / a p) where a /a The import relative share is undefined at π, as is appropriate since in that case the classic Ricardian model obtains and production will either be equal to zero or indeterminate It is defined everywhere else, which means that with Cobb-Douglas preferences, complete specialization is never optimal in the presence of predation Second, we obtain the consumption ratio in the two states in terms of the import relative share and the production ratio We substitute into the ratio of consumption in the two states using m -pm to solve in terms of m and y B x x y B and y + m y pm x x y + m + m y + m y pm Third, we solve for the production ratio Substituting the preceding expressions for the consumption ratios into the efficiency condition for imports and using f(p) for the import relative share m we obtain:

9/9/97 Trade and Security 33 + f( ) u u B +( )u p y pf ( ) + f ( ) ( ) + ( )( ) y pf( ) y pf ( ) This expression may be solved for y to yield: y p { ( ) [ + f ( ) ] +( )( )} y + f( ) [ ] + pf ( ) p + pf + p ( + f ) p f + pf + Finally, in combination with the full employment constraint a' y l S the production ratio yields the closed form solution for y, m,y,m as functions of the exogenous variables p and and the technology parameter l S /a (7) y pf (p,,, ) + Then in turn: (73) m f (p,,, ) pf (p,,, ) + l S / a (74) y l / a l S / a pf(p,,, ) + (75) m pf( p,,, ) l S / a f( p,,, ) + Now we are in a position to consider the partial equilibrium comparative statics of system (7)-(75) It is immediate that a rise in effective size l /a will raise trade volume, as is intuitive We anticipate that a rise in π will raise the level of trade m and the degree of specialization measured by y A rise in α should also raise trade as it increases the gap between the autarky price ratio and the price available through trade To develop these ideas it is necessary as a preliminary step to differentiate the import relative share function f(p,, ) f (p,,, ) p( ) /( ) ( p), hence (76) f p + f f + f f + f [ / p+/( p) ] < 0 [ / +/( )] > 0 [ /( p) ] > 0

9/9/97 Trade and Security 34 Now we are in a position to analyze the properties of the per capita import demand function m ( p,,a) Differentiating (73) with respect to p: f (77) m p m p pf < 0 f pf + pf + The negative sign follows from noting that the square bracket term is negative for positive imports As for the response of m to a rise in, we can show that this is positive and approaches zero as complete specialization is approached: p (78) m m f >0 pf + f Deriving the foreign economy s excess demand functions in the Cobb- Douglas case simply replicates the steps above, recognizing that the role of goods and is switched, and recognizing that the relative price of imports for the foreigner is /p and that the marginal rate of transformation relevant to the steps above is that for the import good in terms of the export good, so * a * / a * All properties are the same, mutatis mutandis

8 The Effect of Continuous Defense Choice For the referees, not for publication Agents choose whether to commit anything to defense by solving the binary choice problem: max l max{d(l)v S (l),[ d(l)]v A,[ d(l)]v B }, where d(l) is a dummy variable equal to if l>0 and equal to zero if l0 This problem serves to sort all agents into specialized producers on the one hand and either bandits or autarkic producers on the other hand Now consider the choice of level of defense for a specialized producer The individual s probability of successful exchange is equal to (l/ l ) ' > 0 for 0 l < l, ' 0 forl > l (), (0) 0 Here, π is the social success rate for exchange and φ is the individual success rate for initiating shipment of exports This specification is rationalized by thinking of the process of exchange in parts Each shipment must depart the producer s location and then travel to an exchange point Bandits are diffused in the initial stage, covering all producer locations Under our assumptions, the producer can guarantee successful initial shipment with a defense commitment equal to l In the exchange stage, bandits are more concentrated around the exchange points and the probability of successful exchange is equal to π The specialized agent s choice of the interior level of defense must satisfy: l (l) 0; where l < l and v S < 0 l If this condition cannot be satisfied at the interior, then l l and v S is decreasing for decreases in defense effort 8 Determination of defense effort When the derivative is examined in detail, the corner solution l l need not obtain even with the simple case in which l/ l Here, the indirect utility function for specialized producers is: v S l + f l pf + + l l l, pf + a where f f (p,,, ) p( ) ( p) /( )

9/9/97 Trade and Security Differentiating with respect to reductions in l l at the limit value (using the convention that φ has a left hand derivative at l l and using a minus sign to denote left hand differentiation) and simplifying, l ll f v S l + l v pf + pf + p + f pf + l a + vs f f l, where (+ f ) + f ( )p ( pf + ) Multiplying both sides by l /v S and using φ at the limit value of defense, we obtain: l (8) l v S l l + (+ f ) + ( ) + f v S f f f l l Now we are ready to sign this derivative Ignoring the effect of changing f, the net effect of the first three terms on the right hand side will be positive for sufficiently large f, but negative at f close to zero This is simply the effect of gains from trade too small to outweigh the fixed cost of defense As for the effect of changing f, the elasticity of f with respect to the success rate is greater than one, while / f can be shown to have the sign of (p ) f + 5 For α<, since p<α, we know the effect via changes in f must be negative For α> and small f, or for p>, the effect via changing f is positive From these considerations, there is some presumption that the left hand elasticity of utility with respect to defense effort is positive: ie, utility will fall with a decrease in defense effort This shows that the binary form of choice used in the text is somewhat more general than it at first appears However, the analysis also shows that in some cases utility will rise with a cut in defense effort, meaning that an interior solution will be optimal For interior solutions to the defense effort problem, l must satisfy: (8) v S l l + v S l l pf + a + vs f f l 0 This does not have a closed form solution 8 The general equilibrium model with continuous defense effort choice When defense effort is at an interior solution, our general equilibrium model contains 4 simultaneously determined variables: L D, L B, pand Their values are determined by (8), the labor market entry conditions, the 5 Note that from the definition of f we can write ( + f ) ( )p ( p) Substituting into the expression for v / f and simplifying results in a series of positive factors multiplying the term above

9/9/97 Trade and Security 3 international market clearance condition and the requirement of rational expectations The model we have used in the text avoids the complexity of interior defense effort choice, and we maintain that our results are robust with respect to this simplification Our key results are in two groups Our first set of results are that (i) autarky is likely in a wide range of the parameter space, and (ii) that this likelihood is positively affected by relative effectiveness of predation (θ) and negatively affected by the effectiveness of defense (β) We furthermore found that (iii) within some range of parameter values for θ and β, the likelihood of a trading equilibrium was first increased by increases in l and then decreased As for the robustness of finding (i), since we impose limit levels of personal defense effort we may have somewhat widened the range of parameter values for which trade can be supported relative to the more realistic specification in which personal defense is continuously variable Thus our finding (i) that autarky is widely prevalent is all the more sharp by being biased upward There is no reason to expect finding (ii) to be affected by the inclusion of continuous defense effort As for the robustness of finding (iii), for corner solutions even when defense choice is continuous the analysis is identical whereas for interior solutions for defense choice in a trading equilibrium it will no longer necessarily be true that increases in l smoothly reduce the net gains from trade and shift the economy from a trading equilibrium into autarky However, a sufficiently large increase in l must once again return the economy to autarky Thus finding (iii) is also basically robust to continuous defense choice The second key group of results concerns immiserizing security The mechanisms we identify which deliver this outcome --- larger countries tend suffer terms of trade deterioration and poorer countries tend to suffer terms of trade deterioration when security improves --- are still present in a model of continuous defense effort choice However, they are augmented by a supply side effect as labor flows between production and defense in interior solutions of defense effort If both countries defense efforts always move in the same direction as security parameters change, this has ambiguous effects on the terms of trade, but implies that the larger country s import demand and export supply functions shift by more (as a given percent of defensive labor is multiplied by a larger base) Thus there is a presumption that common rises in defense effort will cause a terms of trade deterioration of the larger country, both directly through the labor supply effect and indirectly through the improvement in security Essentially this effect is picked up in our simulations which vary l The final possibility, however, is that defense efforts may move in opposite directions in the two countries This opens up a richer menu of possible labor supply effects on the terms of trade, which are missing from our model of discrete defense effort choice Nevertheless, our findings are robust because seems unlikely for this mechanism to be able to rule out immiserizing security