Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 12 Price discrimination (ch 10)-continue

Similar documents
Answer Key: Problem Set 1

x ax 1 2 bx2 a bx =0 x = a b. Hence, a consumer s willingness-to-pay as a function of liters on sale, 1 2 a 2 2b, if l> a. (1)

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

EconS Vertical Integration

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Y j R L divide goods into produced goods (outputs) > 0 output, call its price p < 0 input, call its price ω

Advanced Microeconomics

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

Targeted Advertising and Social Status

A) Graph the data on the scatter plot and draw a line of best fit for the data. FLOWER SALES Sales

Lecture 1: Introduction to IO Tom Holden

MTH 65-Steiner Exam #1 Review: , , 8.6. Non-Calculator sections: (Solving Systems), Chapter 5 (Operations with Polynomials)

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

NATURAL RESOURCE ECONOMICS LECTURE PLAN 16: APRIL 21, 2011 Hunt Allcott

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Optimization, constrained optimization and applications of integrals.

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Solutions. ams 11b Study Guide 9 econ 11b

Pre-Test. 1. Determine the solution to each system of equations. a. 3x 2 y 5 5 2x 1 7y b. 22x 5 210y x 1 8y 5 5

EconS Sequential Competition

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Econ Slides from Lecture 10

Part I: Exercise of Monopoly Power. Chapter 1: Monopoly. Two assumptions: A1. Quality of goods is known by consumers; A2. No price discrimination.

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

Optimal Product Design for a Linear Pricing Monopolist

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395

Scatter plot, Correlation, and Line of Best Fit Exam High School Common Core: Interpret Linear Models

Competitive Equilibrium

Electronic Companion to Tax-Effective Supply Chain Decisions under China s Export-Oriented Tax Policies

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Mathematics Level D: Lesson 2 Representations of a Line

1.4 Linear Functions of Several Variables

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Solutions for Assignment #2 for Environmental and Resource Economics Economics 359M, Spring 2017

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Systems of Equations. Red Company. Blue Company. cost. 30 minutes. Copyright 2003 Hanlonmath 1

x 4 = 40 +2x 5 +6x x 6 x 1 = 10 2x x 6 x 3 = 20 +x 5 x x 6 z = 540 3x 5 x 2 3x 6 x 4 x 5 x 6 x x

Technical Appendix for: Complementary Goods: Creating, Capturing and Competing for Value

Economics th April 2011

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Bresnahan, JIE 87: Competition and Collusion in the American Automobile Industry: 1955 Price War

Notes on Mechanism Designy

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

3. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilibrium

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

NON-CALCULATOR: I. Decide whether or not the following information defines a function. Explain/support your answer x y

LINEAR EQUATIONS Modeling Linear Equations Common Core Standards

Technical Appendix: When To Fire Customers? Customer Cost Based Pricing

Lecture 2F: Hotelling s Model

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Overview. Producer Theory. Consumer Theory. Exchange

A Review of Auction Theory: Sequential Auctions and Vickrey Auctions

= $ m. Telephone Company B charges $11.50 per month plus five cents per minute. Writing that mathematically, we have c B. = $

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Online Supplementary Appendix B

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

A General Bundling Theory; an Application to Complementary Demand and Separate Sellers

Partial derivatives, linear approximation and optimization

Durable goods monopolist

Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018

A Note of Caution on Using Hotelling Models in Platform Markets

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Section 11.3 Rates of Change:

Credence Goods and Vertical Product Differentiation: The Impact of Labeling Policies* Ian Sheldon (Ohio State University)

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

y = F (x) = x n + c dy/dx = F`(x) = f(x) = n x n-1 Given the derivative f(x), what is F(x)? (Integral, Anti-derivative or the Primitive function).

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

3.1 NOTES Solving Systems of Linear Equations Graphically

Adding Production to the Theory

Industrial Organization

Econ 201: Problem Set 3 Answers

Microeconomic Theory. Microeconomic Theory. Everyday Economics. The Course:

EXAMINATION #4 ANSWER KEY. I. Multiple choice (1)a. (2)e. (3)b. (4)b. (5)d. (6)c. (7)b. (8)b. (9)c. (10)b. (11)b.

Basics of Game Theory

3 288 organisations in poll, over 39,000 customer responses

0 Review: Lines, Fractions, Exponents Lines Fractions Rules of exponents... 4

Algebra 1 STAAR EOC Review #7 Reporting Category 4: Linear Equations and Inequalities

SI Information Economics, Winter 2007

Solve each absolute value equation x 7 = x 9 = (3x 12) = - 12

Linear Equations. Additional Options: Hide Multiple Choice Answers (Written Response) Open in Microsoft Word (add page breaks and/or edit questions)

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

MA 181 Lecture Chapter 7 College Algebra and Calculus by Larson/Hodgkins Limits and Derivatives

Algebra I Practice Exam

Can quadratic functions tell us whether. Brendan Nelson is really trying. to save taxpayers money?

5, 0. Math 112 Fall 2017 Midterm 1 Review Problems Page Which one of the following points lies on the graph of the function f ( x) (A) (C) (B)

Econ 110: Introduction to Economic Theory. 8th Class 2/7/11

Math 112 Spring 2018 Midterm 1 Review Problems Page 1

ALGEBRA UNIT 5 LINEAR SYSTEMS SOLVING SYSTEMS: GRAPHICALLY (Day 1)

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Economics 312: Urban Land Economics University of Victoria Midterm Examination #1 VERSION 1 SOLUTIONS Spring 2018 Instructor: Martin Farnham

Environmental Economics Lectures 11, 12 Valuation and Cost-Benefit Analysis

56:171 Operations Research Midterm Exam - October 26, 1989 Instructor: D.L. Bricker

Study Unit 3 : Linear algebra

Transcription:

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 12 Price discrimination (ch 10)-continue 2 nd degree price discrimination We have discussed that firms charged different prices to consumers with different characteristics. Called 1 st and 3 rd price discrimination. The whole purpose of this is to charge higher prices to consumers with higher willingness to pay. What if consumer 1 has WTP 1 >WTP 2 where WTP 2 is 2 s willingness to pay? And there are no observable differences between 1 and 2? i.e. the firm cannot offer consumer 2 a discount for being a senior citizen. If the firm sets p1=wtp 1 and p2=wtp 2 and asks the consumers to reveal their identities, consumer 1 will claim to be #2 in order to pay a lower price. This class we will explain how firms engage in price discrimination when consumers have private information about their willingness to pay for a product. The firm s goal is the same: make a sale to a low WTP consumer without having to lower prices charged to high WTP consumers. But now, firm has to get consumers to admit their preferences. It does this by offering different types of products (large vs small, high quality vs low quality) and pricing carefully One way that firms do this is through quantity discounting: low per unit price when larger quantities purchased. An example of quantity discounting is drink sizes and prices. At Starbuck s: Small coffee is 12 oz and costs $1.75 $0.15/ounce Large coffee is 20 oz and costs $1.95 $0.010/ounce What we can show that this pricing policy is an attempt at 2 nd degree price discrimination. Consider demand curve for an arbitrary cup of coffee. 1

In the figure above, there are two types of consumers, high WTP and low WTP. The monopolist would like to be able to charge the high WTP consumers a high price and the low WTP consumers a low price. That way the firm can extract lots of surplus from the high types and still be able to sell to the low types. Assume that the monopolist knows that there are high WTP consumers and low WTP consumers, but the monopolist is unable to distinguish between the two types, i.e. 1 st and 3 rd price discrimination is not possible. Instead the monopolist will engage in 2 nd degree price discrimination. He will design two products: a large cup of coffee with a high price. This product will be aimed at high WTP consumers. The high price will enable the monopolist to extract lots of surplus from high WTP consumers. And a small cup of coffee with a low price aimed at the low WTP consumers. The low price will ensure that they purchase coffee. Setup: A cup of coffee has a size (q ounces) and a price (p) Consumers set untility u = θln (q) p where θ reflects consumers WTP for extra coffee. du dq = θ q so high θ consumers have a high MU from an extra ounce. There are two types of consumers, θ H and θ L, with θ H > θ L. Starbucks wants to engage in 2 nd degree price discrimination. Will offer two cups of coffee. A large (q H, p H ) aimed at θ H and a small (q L, p L ) aimed at θ L. Q ounces of coffee costs Starbucks cq dollars. Starbuck s problem: design two cups of coffee such that θ H purchases (q H,p H ), θ L purchases (q L,p L ) and profits are maximized. max π Starbucks = p q H, q H, q L, q H cq H + p L cq L L Such that (1) θ H ln q H p H 0 (2) θ L ln q L p L 0 2

(3) θ H ln q H p H θ L ln q L p L (4) θ L ln q L p L θ L ln q H p H Constraints (1) and (2): θ H and θ L prefers to buy coffee instead of buying nothing. Constraints (3) and (4): consumers buy the product designed for them. θ H prefers (q H, p H ) to (q L, p L ) and θ L prefers (q L, p L ) to (q H, p H ). This problem can be simplified: Claim (1): Constraint (1) can be ignored. θ H consumers must get positive utility from (q L, p L ) since θ H > θ L and θ L q L q L 0 implies θ H q L, p L > 0. Therefore θ H must get positive utility from (q H, p H ) because of constraint (3) θ H ln q H p H θ H ln q L p L > 0 Claim 2: Constraint (2) is binding. We know that θ H ln q H p H 0. If it is also true that θ L ln q L p L 0 then Starbucks is not maximizing profits. Can increase p H and p L by a tiny amount, increase profits and all of the constraints are still satisfied. Starbuck s problem is now: Such that Claim 3: Constraint (3) is binding. π = max (p H cq H + p L cq L ) (2) θ L ln q L p L = 0 (3) θ H ln q H p H θ H ln q L p L (4) θ L ln q L p L θ L ln q H p H If it is not binding then θ H ln q H p H > θ H ln q L p L. Starbucks can decrease q H by a little bit, increase profits, and constraints 92) and (4) still hold. Claim 4: We can ignore constraint (4). If constraint (3) is binding, then θ H ln q H p H = θ H ln q L p L or θ H (ln q H ln q L ) = p H p L. Since θ L < θ H, θ L ln q H ln q L < p H p L or θ L ln q L p L > θ L ln (q H ) p H So, Starbuck s problem becomes: Such that π = max (p H cq H + p L cq L ) θ L ln q L p L = 0 θ H ln q H p H = θ L ln q L p L 3

Intuition: Starbuck s wants to design a low quality and a high quality product. θ L is just indifferent between purchasing the low quality product and nothing. The monopolist extracts all of their surplus. The monopolist must design the high quality product so that θ H sets positive utility because otherwise θ H will purchase the low quality product. But to maximize profits, the high quality product is designed so that θ H is indifferent between the two products. Now we just plug the constraints into the profit function and solve: max q, p (p H cq H + p L cq L ) Such that θ L ln q L p L = 0 p L = θ L ln (q L ) θ H ln q H p H = θ H ln q L p L p H = θ H ln q H ln q L + θ L ln (q L ) max (q q H, q H ln q H θ H ln q L + θ L ln q L cq H + θ L ln q L cq L ) L dπ = θ H c = 0 dq H q H dπ = 2θ L θ H c = 0 dq L q L We observe a Starbuck s menu: q H = θ H c q L = 2θ L θ H c p H = θ H ln q H ln q L + θ L ln q L p L = θ L ln (q L ) Can our model duplicate this? q L = 12 oz p L = $1.75 q H = 20 oz p H = $1.95 If c = 0.04, θ L = 0.647, and θ H = 0.804, our model predicts q L = 12.26, p L = 1.62, q H = 20.1, p H = 2.02 4

Our model is not perfect because of utility assumptions, restricting to 2 sizes instead of 3, but can do a pretty good job of duplicating Starbuck s pricing pattern. The 2 nd degree price discrimination was able to explain Starbuck s nonlinear pricing policy as an attempt to extract surplus from high WTP consumers while still making sales to low WTP consumers. The Starbuck s model was one of quantity discounting. We can redefine q and explain lots of other real world phenomenon: 1. q= quality electronics companies offer two versions of the same product, one with extra feature (q H ), the other basic one (q L ) insurance companies offer menus of insurance plans, some with low coverage (q L ) others with high coverage 2. q= rewards programs restaurants offer deals: buy 10 sandwiches, get your 11 th free. Here q L =3 sandwiches over a given period of time q H =10 sandwiches +1 free over same period of time. Per unit price is lower q H than q L. Pricing policy sets people who eat out for lunch a lot to always come to your restaurant. Same thing for airlines, hotel reward/loyalty programs 3. q=time some people really value having the newest products. Other people do not care. Charge a high price for a product immediately after it is introduced. Then lower price slowly. Airlines: business travelers have higher WTP and also make plans later than other travelers. Airlines charge lower prices for tourists when ticket is for date far in the future. 5

In the previous discussion on price discrimination, consumers either purchase a good or they don t. For many goods, consumers buy multiple units (example: cell phone minutes. Consumers enroll in a plan, and then choose how many minutes to consume). For these types of products firms often use two part tariffs to price discriminate/extract surplus from consumers. Two part tariff: A firm charge a consumer a fee (tariff 1) for the right to buy as many units of the product as the consumer wants at a specific price (tariff 2). Examples: Cell phone plans membership discount retailers: Costco amusement parks The price a consumer pays for q units = F + pq where F is tariff 1 p is tariff 2 This is nonlinear pricing since each unit cost ( F + p) depends on q. q First, let s show that a monopolist can use two part tariffs to extract more surplus from consumers. Suppose a consumer demands q D (p) units of output if the monopolist charges a price p. 6

The monopolist can either use a one part tariff (F = 0, p 0) or a two part tariff (F 0, p 0). Assume the monopolist has constant marginal costs c. 1) monopolist uses a 1 part tariff. π = max p p q p cq(p) Just like standard monopoly problem. Set MR=MC. When monopolist force to set F = 0, he charges a markup (p > c) and there is too little output produced q 1p < q and DWL>0. 2) Monopolist uses a 2 part tariff Now the monopolist has two instruments it can use (F and p) to extract surplus from consumers. Surplus is maximized at q. If the monopolist is able to choose a F, p so that profits=total surplus at q, this must be the profit maximizing solution. Suppose the monopolist sets p=c. then the consumer will demand q units of output and surplus is maximized. Now, the monopolist will choose F to extract as much surplus as possible from the consumer: Figure 10.e7 shows that if monopolist sets p=c, surplus is maximized. If monopolist then sets F=total surplus (red shaded area), consumers will still purchase the good and firms extracts all surplus. Optimal two part tariff: Set p=mc to get efficient allocation Set F=Area between demand curve and price to extract all surplus from consumers 7

This analysis explains many real pricing policies. For example, gym memberships usually have a monthly fee and unlimited free visits to the gym. This reflects the fact that the marginal cost of a gym visit=0. Are two part tariffs good? We see a familiar trade off. Two part tariffs yield the efficient outcome since firms don t need to use high per unit prices to extract surplus on the first few units of q that are sold. But on the other hand, firms collect all of the surplus. Now assume that there are two types of consumers. Type H consumers value output a lot. Type L consumers value output a little. For example U q = θ ln q p q F du dq = θ q p = 0 q p = θ p p = θ q Let θ H > θ L. Then the high θ consumers demand curve lies on top of the low θ consumers demand curve (in Figure 10.e8 below): Similarly, we can lot indifference curves. MU q = θ q MU other comsumption = 1 Since utility linear in price. 8

Therefore MRS = θ q. 9