Economics 472. Lecture 10. where we will refer to y t as a m-vector of endogenous variables, x t as a q-vector of exogenous variables,

Similar documents
Economics 508 Lecture 12 Introduction to Dynamic Simultaneous Equation Models

Chapter 6. Panel Data. Joan Llull. Quantitative Statistical Methods II Barcelona GSE

4.8 Instrumental Variables

Notes on Time Series Modeling

Linear Algebra (part 1) : Vector Spaces (by Evan Dummit, 2017, v. 1.07) 1.1 The Formal Denition of a Vector Space

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs.

Time Series Analysis for Macroeconomics and Finance

ECON 4160, Spring term 2015 Lecture 7

Dealing With Endogeneity

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs.

Economics 536 Lecture 7. Introduction to Specification Testing in Dynamic Econometric Models

Instrumental Variables

Linear Regression and Its Applications

Lecture Notes on Measurement Error

Multivariate Time Series Analysis and Its Applications [Tsay (2005), chapter 8]

ECON 616: Lecture 1: Time Series Basics

Chapter 30 Minimality and Stability of Interconnected Systems 30.1 Introduction: Relating I/O and State-Space Properties We have already seen in Chapt

Multivariate Time Series

plim W 0 " 1 N = 0 Prof. N. M. Kiefer, Econ 620, Cornell University, Lecture 16.

VAR Model. (k-variate) VAR(p) model (in the Reduced Form): Y t-2. Y t-1 = A + B 1. Y t + B 2. Y t-p. + ε t. + + B p. where:

Structural VAR Models and Applications

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 4th ed. Chapter 15: Instrumental variables and two stage least squares

VII Selected Topics. 28 Matrix Operations

1 Introduction. 2 Determining what the J i blocks look like. December 6, 2006

Lecture 2: Review of Prerequisites. Table of contents

1 Vectors. Notes for Bindel, Spring 2017 Numerical Analysis (CS 4220)

EMERGING MARKETS - Lecture 2: Methodology refresher

Essentials of Intermediate Algebra

only nite eigenvalues. This is an extension of earlier results from [2]. Then we concentrate on the Riccati equation appearing in H 2 and linear quadr

Econometrics Problem Set 11

ECON 4160, Autumn term 2017 Lecture 9

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

Introduction to the Simultaneous Equations Model

Chapter Robust Performance and Introduction to the Structured Singular Value Function Introduction As discussed in Lecture 0, a process is better desc

Linear Regression. Junhui Qian. October 27, 2014

ECO 310: Empirical Industrial Organization Lecture 2 - Estimation of Demand and Supply

Multivariate Models. Christopher Ting. Christopher Ting. April 19,

[y i α βx i ] 2 (2) Q = i=1

1 What does the random effect η mean?

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

The BLP Method of Demand Curve Estimation in Industrial Organization

Title. Description. var intro Introduction to vector autoregressive models

1 Outline. 1. Motivation. 2. SUR model. 3. Simultaneous equations. 4. Estimation

Vector Time-Series Models

A Note on the Correlated Random Coefficient Model. Christophe Kolodziejczyk

Financial Econometrics

The Linear Regression Model

Homogeneous Linear Systems and Their General Solutions

Chapter 14: Finding the Equilibrium Solution and Exploring the Nature of the Equilibration Process

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models. An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory

14 EE 2402 Engineering Mathematics III Solutions to Tutorial 3 1. For n =0; 1; 2; 3; 4; 5 verify that P n (x) is a solution of Legendre's equation wit

The Fast Fourier Transform

Multivariate Statistical Analysis

Simultaneous Equation Models Learning Objectives Introduction Introduction (2) Introduction (3) Solving the Model structural equations

Lecture: Simultaneous Equation Model (Wooldridge s Book Chapter 16)

Problem Set 9 Due: In class Tuesday, Nov. 27 Late papers will be accepted until 12:00 on Thursday (at the beginning of class).

PROOF OF TWO MATRIX THEOREMS VIA TRIANGULAR FACTORIZATIONS ROY MATHIAS

08 Endogenous Right-Hand-Side Variables. Andrius Buteikis,

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions

Economics 620, Lecture 15: Introduction to the Simultaneous Equations Model

Our goal is to solve a general constant coecient linear second order. this way but that will not always happen). Once we have y 1, it will always

Economics 620, Lecture 7: Still More, But Last, on the K-Varable Linear Model

ECON 331 Homework #2 - Solution. In a closed model the vector of external demand is zero, so the matrix equation writes:

A primer on Structural VARs

Single Equation Linear GMM

Econometrics. Week 11. Fall Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague

Stock Prices, News, and Economic Fluctuations: Comment

Linear Algebra (MATH ) Spring 2011 Final Exam Practice Problem Solutions

Lecture 4: Applications of Orthogonality: QR Decompositions

Notes on Random Variables, Expectations, Probability Densities, and Martingales

Simultaneous Equation Models

TAKEHOME FINAL EXAM e iω e 2iω e iω e 2iω

Asymptotic Properties and simulation in gretl

Econometrics. Week 8. Fall Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague

Econ 510 B. Brown Spring 2014 Final Exam Answers

Spurious Chaotic Solutions of Dierential. Equations. Sigitas Keras. September Department of Applied Mathematics and Theoretical Physics

Chapter 14. Simultaneous Equations Models Introduction

Ordinary Least Squares Regression

2. An Introduction to Moving Average Models and ARMA Models

Lecture Notes Part 7: Systems of Equations

Next, we discuss econometric methods that can be used to estimate panel data models.

LECTURE 15 + C+F. = A 11 x 1x1 +2A 12 x 1x2 + A 22 x 2x2 + B 1 x 1 + B 2 x 2. xi y 2 = ~y 2 (x 1 ;x 2 ) x 2 = ~x 2 (y 1 ;y 2 1

1 Motivation for Instrumental Variable (IV) Regression

A framework for monetary-policy analysis Overview Basic concepts: Goals, targets, intermediate targets, indicators, operating targets, instruments

We begin by thinking about population relationships.


1 Outline Part I: Linear Programming (LP) Interior-Point Approach 1. Simplex Approach Comparison Part II: Semidenite Programming (SDP) Concludin

FREE PROBABILITY THEORY

Slope Fields: Graphing Solutions Without the Solutions

Robust linear optimization under general norms

G METHOD IN ACTION: FROM EXACT SAMPLING TO APPROXIMATE ONE

Econometrics Summary Algebraic and Statistical Preliminaries

Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series

1 Last time: least-squares problems

MAT 22B - Lecture Notes

Introduction to Linear Regression Analysis Interpretation of Results

A. Recursively orthogonalized. VARs

LECTURE 10 LINEAR PROCESSES II: SPECTRAL DENSITY, LAG OPERATOR, ARMA. In this lecture, we continue to discuss covariance stationary processes.

LECTURE NOTES IN CRYPTOGRAPHY

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Transcription:

University of Illinois Fall 998 Department of Economics Roger Koenker Economics 472 Lecture Introduction to Dynamic Simultaneous Equation Models In this lecture we will introduce some simple dynamic simultaneous equation models. Problem Set 4 will deal with two classical examples of this class of models which are typically used in studying partial equilibrium models of a single market. Let's begin by considering a rather general class of models of this form, (),y t = A(L)y t, + B(L)x t + u t where we will refer to y t as a m-vector of endogenous variables, x t as a q-vector of exogenous variables, and A(L) and B(L) denote matrix polynomials in the lag operator L, as usual. We will assume that given vectors y t,, and x t, a realization of the vector u t determines a unique realization of the response vector y t, given the exogenous variables x t and the past. This uniqueness requires that the matrix, be invertible. We may then \solve" the structural form of the model, (), to obtain the reduced form, (2) y t = (L)y t, +(L)x t + v t where (L) =,, A(L); (L) =,, B(L) and v t =,, u t. We can think of the structural form as representing an idealized version of how the model \really works", while the reduced form is a cruder version of the model which could be used for forecasting, for example. It is helpful at this stage to have a more concrete example so let's consider the cobweb model from part one of PS 4. (3) Q t = + 2 P t, + 3 z t + u t P t = + 2 Q t + 3 w t + v t To connect this model with the notation of () we may write, x t = B@ z t w t C A exogenous variables

,= @, 2 y t = A ; A(L) = @ 2 B(L) = @ 3 @ Q t P t A endogenous variables A,, = @ 2 A ; (L) = @ 2 2 2 A A ; (L) = @ 3 3 2 + 2 3 A 3 Now consider solving the model for an equilibrium form. This would yield, in the general case (4) y e =(I, ()), ()x e In the specic model (3) form, we would have so I, () = (I, ()), = In this case we must check to be sure that converges in order to assure stability. @, 2, 2 2 A @, 2 2 2 (I, ), = I + + 2 + A =(, 2 2 ) Having derived the equilibrium form of the model it is now an opportune moment to discuss forecasting. This is again conveniently done using the reduced form. The one-step ahead forecast in the simple case where (L) and (L) are matrices independent of L, yields and thus two-steps ahead, ^y n+ = y n +x n+ ^y n+2 = ( y n +x n+ )+x n+2 = 2 y n + x n+ +x n+2 and thus for s steps ahead, s, ^y n+s = s y n X + i= i x n++i 2

Note that, although it might not be immediately obvious, this is completely consistent with the previous discussion of equilibrium. Suppose x n+i = x e for all i ; then presuming that s! as is obviously required for stability, we have as previously discussed. ^y n+s! ( X i= i )x e =(I, ), x e Estimation of Dynamic Simultaneous Equation Models Estimation of simultaneous equation models pose some new problems which we will now gradually introduce. It is convenient to begin with the simple case of recursive models which bring us just to the edge of simultaneity, without quite plunging into it. Denition Model () is recursive if the following conditions hold, or if the endogenous variables can be reordered so that these conditions are met: (i) The matrix, is lower triangular, and (ii) The covariance matrix = Eu t u is diagonal, and t fu tg is iid over time. We hasten to point out that condition (i) is satised by the cobweb model (3), so provided we assume, in addition, in that model that Eu t v t = so that it satises (ii),we can say that it is in recursive form. What is so special above recursive models? Closer examination reveals that recursivity implies an explicit causal ordering in the model. In our cobweb model (3) this is illustrated in the following diagram. Given an initial price p, supply determines the next periods quantity, Q. Demand in period one then determines a price that will clear the market and this, then, triggers a supply response for period two and the model continues to operate. In the gure we see that for xed supply and demand functions (recall that in the constantly model as specied in (3), these functions are shifting around due both to changes in the exogenous variables x t and w t as well the random eects u t and v t ), this leads to convergence to an equilibrium (P t ;Q t ) pair that looks a little like a spider web as it oscillates around the equilibrium point. At this point you might explore what happens if the demand curve is quite steep, i.e., inelastic, and supply is quite at, i.e., elastic. Explain how this connects with the algebraic formulation of the model and the stability of equilibrium. The crucial observation about causal ordering and estimation of recursive models concerns the orthogonality of the errors and explanatory variables in models of this form. Note that in model (3) p t, is clearly orthogonal to u t provided the fu t g are iid, and in the demand equation Q t is orthogonal to v t provided that v t and u t are orthogonal. Clearly, Q t depends upon u t,soifu t and v t were 3

price 2 4 6 8 4 2 4 6 8 2 4 quantity Figure : A simple linear cobweb model of supply and demand correlated, then this orthogonality (i.e., EQ t v t =)would fail and ordinary least squares estimation would be biased. Obviously, the conditions for recursivity are rather delicate. We need, not only that the matrix, be triangular, a condition which itself is rather questionable, but we also rely on strong assumptions about the unobservable error eects in the system of equations. An illustration of how delicate things really are is provided by the eect of autocorrelation in u t in the rst equation of model (3). Note that if we perturb the model slightly and consider the possibility that u t = u t, + " t with f" t g iid, now u t, clearly inuences u t, but it also helps to determine Q t,, thus p t,, so Eu t p t, = fails in this case and we need a more general estimation strategy that is capable of dealing with these failures of orthogonality. We will introduce a test for this kind of eect in the next lecture. Instrumental Variables and Two Stage Least Squares If correlation (read: lack of orthogonality) between X and u is a potential problem lurking in the shadows of recursive models, it is fully armed and dangerous in the classical simultaneous equations 4

model. For general, in (), the model is truly simultaneous in that the realization of the error vector u t jointly determines all of the endogenous variables and therefore, any contemporaneous endogenous variable appearing on the right hand side of an equation is bound to be correlated with the error term in that equation. The remedy for this, fortunately, is rather simple. We must nd, as we have already seen in discussion of estimating models with lagged dependent variables and autocorrelated errors, instrumental variables, z i, that satisfy the conditions that (i) they are (asymptotically) uncorrelated with the errors in the equation of interest, and (ii) they are (asymptotically) correlated with the included endogenous variables in the equation. Consider the problem of estimating one of a system of simultaneous equations, say the rst one, which we might write as, (3) y = Y + X + u = Z + u : To connect this with our apparently more general class of models () take the rst row ofthe matrix, in () to be, =(;, ; ) where the corresponds to all of the endogenous variables that do not appear in the rst equation. Let's begin by considering the simplest case in which (5) is exactly identied. Partition the full set of exogenous variables as X =(X. ~ X ) where X is the set of included exogenous variables for equation one and ~ X and the excluded exogenous variables. In this case we may view ~ X as immediately available IV's for the Y 's, since we have exactly, the same number of ~X 's as Y 's. Consider two apparently dierent instrumental variable estimators: ^ =(^Z Z ), ^Z y that we will call the two stage least squares estimator, and ~ =(~ Z Z ), ~ Z y which is usually called the \indirect least squares" estimator, where ^Z = P X Z = X(X X), X Z ; and ~ Z =(X. ~ X )=X: We will show that ^ = ~ : We may write the claim more explicitly as (Z P XZ ), Z P Xy =(X Z ), X y 5

Now note that by assumption X Z is invertible so we can rewrite the lhs as (ZP X Z ), ZP X y = (X Z ), X X(ZX), ZX(X X), X y = (X Z ), X y To explore the general case in which wehave \more than enough" instrumental variables we consider the two stage least squares estimator in a bit more detail. Consider the model y = Y + X + u = Z + u : and dene instrumental variables Z ~ = XA: Then it is easy to show that the instrumental variables estimator ~ =(~ Z Z), Z ~ y has the asymptotic linear representation p n( ~, ) =(n, A X Z), n,=2 A X u and therefore, p n( ~, ) D!N(; 2 (A MD), AMA(A MD), ) where 2 = Eu 2 i ;M = lim n, X X; D =[. ];X = X ; and is the Y partition of the matrix of reduced form coecients. The following result shows that among all possible choices of the matrix A, the two stage least squares choice has a claim to optimality. Theorem The two stage least squares choice, ^ with A =(X X), X Z is optimal, i.e., V (^) V ( ) ~ for all A. Proof Note A! D since, (X X), X Y = ^ P! and (X X), X Z =. Thus, avar(^) lim V ( p n(^, )) = 2 (D MD),. Wewould like to show that for all 2 R p +q (V (^), V ( )) ~ : It is equivalent, and slightly easier, to argue that for all 2 R p +q, (V (^),, V ( ) ~, ). Factor M = NN (Cholesky decomposition) and set h = N, D as h h = D MD and V (^), = D MA(A MA), A MD = h G(G G), G h where G = NA; so we may write (V ( ) ~,, V (^), ) = h (I, G(G G), G )h as required, since the matrix in parentheses is a projection and therefore positive semidenite. 6