Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018

Similar documents
Moral Hazard: Part 2. April 16, 2018

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

Teoria das organizações e contratos

Introduction: Asymmetric Information and the Coase Theorem

Economics th April 2011

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Game Theory, Information, Incentives

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Module 16: Signaling

Government Outsourcing: Public Contracting with Private Monopoly

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

Practice Questions for Math 131 Exam # 1

Competitive Equilibrium

Notes on Mechanism Designy

Moral Hazard: Hidden Action

Endogenous Matching: Adverse Selection & Moral Hazard On-Demand

1.1 A Simple Model of Price Discrimination Full Information Benchmark: First-Best Outcome or Perfect Price

Durable goods monopolist

The Principal-Agent Problem

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Lecture 8: Incomplete Contracts

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1

This is designed for one 75-minute lecture using Games and Information. October 3, 2006

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana

Advanced Microeconomics

Contracts in informed-principal problems with moral hazard

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Basics of Game Theory

Economics 2102: Final Solutions

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Quadratic function and equations Quadratic function/equations, supply, demand, market equilibrium

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Introduction to Game Theory

The Monopolist. The Pure Monopolist with symmetric D matrix

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Advanced Microeconomics

Lecture Notes: Industrial Organization Joe Chen 1. The Structure Conduct Performance (SCP) paradigm:

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Department of Economics, University of California, Davis Ecn 200C Micro Theory Professor Giacomo Bonanno ANSWERS TO PRACTICE PROBLEMS 18

5. Externalities and Public Goods

Simplifying this, we obtain the following set of PE allocations: (x E ; x W ) 2

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Name: Final Exam EconS 527 (December 12 th, 2016)

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Game Theory and Economics of Contracts Lecture 5 Static Single-agent Moral Hazard Model

Welfare Analysis in Partial Equilibrium.

Adverse Selection, Signaling, and Screening in Markets

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version)

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

Lecture 5: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Monopoly Regulation with Non-Paying Consumers

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Insurance Markets with Interdependent Risks

A Computational Method for Multidimensional Continuous-choice. Dynamic Problems

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

EC721B FINAL EXAMINATION SOLUTIONS, FALL 2018

The Mathematics of Continuous Time Contract Theory

Chapter 5. Transmission networks and electricity markets

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Moral Hazard. Felix Munoz-Garcia. Advanced Microeconomics II - Washington State University

Optimal Mechanism Design with Aftermarket Interactions

Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Adverse selection, signaling & screening

SECTION 5.1: Polynomials

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

NON-CALCULATOR: I. Decide whether or not the following information defines a function. Explain/support your answer x y

The Real Business Cycle Model

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation

Moral Hazard. EC202 Lectures XV & XVI. Francesco Nava. February London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC202 Lectures XV & XVI Feb / 19

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation

Decision Models Lecture 5 1. Lecture 5. Foreign-Currency Trading Integer Programming Plant-location example Summary and Preparation for next class

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

An Introduction to Moral Hazard in Continuous Time

The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias. Web Appendix

Concave programming. Concave programming is another special case of the general constrained optimization. subject to g(x) 0

Hidden information. Principal s payoff: π (e) w,

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 16 Feb 2012

Perfect Competition in Markets with Adverse Selection

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time

Field Exam: Advanced Theory

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Externalities and PG. MWG- Chapter 11

EconS Sequential Competition

Transcription:

Moral Hazard: Part 1 April 9, 2018

Introduction In a standard moral hazard problem, the agent A is characterized by only one type. As with adverse selection, the principal P wants to engage in an economic transaction with A, i.e. delegating a task; buying or selling a commodity... The crucial difference is that P does not observe the action performed by A, i.e. how much effort A exerts; how much time A devotes to the task... The P only observes the outcome, which is jointly determined by the action of A and by a random component. P wants to design the best way in order to incentivize A to: engage in the economic transaction; perform the action which is optimal from the P s perspective.

A simple example Mark is buying a house insurance. There are two possible outcomes: in G (good) nothing happens; in B (bad) the house burns down. The probability of G is p (0, 1). The utility of Mark is u (y) if G and u (y L) if B, with u > 0 and u < 0.

A simple example Mark can purchase an insurance coverage C at unit price π. The insurance coverage pays C to Mark if B happens. Independently of the state, Mark pays the premium πc. The utility with coverage C is u (y πc) if G and u (y πc L + C) if B, with u > 0 and u < 0.

A simple example The insurance company has the following revenues: πc if G; πc C if B. Assume perfect competition. Then zero profit condition implies that: p (πc) + (1 p) (πc C) = 0, which requires π = 1 p. It is easy to show that the consumer would optimally choose full coverage, i.e. C = L. The optimal choice problem of Mark is: or, setting π = 1 p max pu (y πc) + (1 p) u (y πc L + C) C max pu (y (1 p) C) + (1 p) u (y (1 p) C L + C) C The FOC requires that p (1 p) u (y (1 p) C ) = (1 p) pu (y + pc L).

A simple example Assume now that p is endogenous and depends on Mark s choices, i.e. Mark can take precautions (devices) or avoid making a barbeque in the living room or using candles. Moreover, effort is costly for Mark: utility is now u (y) e; effort is not observable by the insurance company (moral hazard). Assume that p (e) satisfies: p > 0 and p < 0; p (0) = a 0. Assume again perfect competition in the insurance market. Then, if companies expect the effort level e: π = 1 p (e) and C = L

A simple example Note, however, that the optimal effort of Mark when C = L is e = 0. max u (y πl) e e Then, p (0) = a and π = 1 a. The insurance premium is so large that Mark might be better off without an insurance: Assume a = 0. Then π = 1 and Mark s utility is u (y L)! No demand for insurance means that the market breaks down! What happens? Insurance companies cannot punish those consumers that exert little effort and, thus, cannot incentivize good behavior!

Other examples A firm hiring a worker who may spent his time working or on Facebook A bank financing an entrepreneur who can invest in his project, or run away with the money. An insurance company providing car-insurance to drivers who can drive safely, or recklessly A government agency regulating a natural monopoly who could invest in reducing its costs, or not The shareholders of a company delegating the managment to a CEO who can instead act in its own interest

The basic model P wants to delegate the production of q units of a good to A The output q could be low or high, {q, q} and depends on: the effort e {0, 1} exerted by A; a stochastic component. Effort e is costly for A: the cost function is ψ (1) = ψ > 0 = ψ (0). Effort makes the high output more likely: P ( q = q e = 1 ) = p1 > p 0 = P ( q = q e = 0 ) Utility functions: P s utility is V = S(q) t with S > 0 and S < 0 A s utility is U = u(t) ψ (e) with u > 0 and u < 0 Asymmetric information: Effort exerted by A is not observable by P

The basic model: parenthesis Remember that P ( q = q e = 1) = p 1 > p 0 = P ( q = q e = 0) Thus, the distribution of production quantity conditional on high effort first order stochastically dominates the distribution of production quantity conditional on low effort. Thus, the P (due to S > 0) strictly prefers that A exerts high efforts. Finally, define π π 1 π 0.

The basic model: the contract A contract between P and A specifies the transfer t ( q) conditional on the realized outcome q: { t (q) = t q = q t ( q) = t ( q) = t q = q. Output q is ex-post observable and verifiable by a court of law / judge. We assume that the contract is enforced by the law. Important: effort e is neither observed by P nor by a court of law / judge. Thus, the contract cannot depend on it!

The basic model: the timing First. P offers a contract t ( q) = {t, t} to A. Second. A decides whether to accept the contract or not. Third. A exerts the chosen level of effort e = {0, 1}. Fourth. The outcome q realizes. Fifth. The contract is executed: A gives q to P; P transfers t ( q) to A.

The basic model: complete information We assume that P (and court of law) observe the level of effort. P offers a contract t ( q) conditional on A exerting high level of effort in order to maximize S ( q) t ( q). (any deviation from exerting high effort can be severely punished) A chooses whether to accept or not based on utility maximization. Her outside option is equal to 0. By backward induction, A accepting the contract means she will exert high effort. A will accept a contract t ( q) only if π1u ( t) + (1 π 1) u (t) ψ 0 (the partecipation constraint of A)

The basic model: complete information The problem of P can be written as: max π 1 (S ( q) t) + (1 π 1 ) (S (q) q) t, t s.t.π 1 u ( t) + (1 π 1 ) u (t) ψ 0 Clearly, the constraint has to hold with equality: P needs to pay just enough to ensure A accepts the high-effort contract. Thus: max π 1 (S ( q) t)+(1 π 1 ) (S (q) t)+µ [π 1 u ( t) + (1 π 1 ) u (t) ψ], t, t where µ is the Lagrangean multiplier.

The basic model: complete information The FOCs are: π 1 = µπ 1 u ( t ) (1 π 1 ) = µ (1 π 1 ) u (t ) Thus, t = t = t! A gets the same transfer independently of the outcome q and is fully insured! The optimal transfer is given by the participation constraint: u (t ) = ψ or, inverting, t = u 1 (ψ)

The basic model: complete information The indirect utility of P is given by: V 1 = π 1 S ( q) + (1 π 1 ) S (q) u 1 (ψ) P has the alternative to incentivize A to participate but to exert no effort. The indirect utility of P is then: V 0 = π 0 S ( q) + (1 π 0 ) S (q) Incentivizing high effort gives the benefit of π (S ( q) S (q)). The cost of doing so is u 1 (ψ). So, P chooses the high-effort contract iff: π (S ( q) S (q)) u 1 (ψ).