Stability of Limit Cycle in a Delayed IS-LM Business Cycle model

Similar documents
FLUCTUATIONS IN A MIXED IS-LM BUSINESS CYCLE MODEL

Hopf Bifurcation Analysis of a Dynamical Heart Model with Time Delay

Hamad Talibi Alaoui and Radouane Yafia. 1. Generalities and the Reduced System

A comparison of delayed SIR and SEIR epidemic models

A modification of Kaldor-Kalecki model and its analysis

Delay Kaldor-Kalecki Model Revisited. September 2014

Direction and Stability of Hopf Bifurcation in a Delayed Model with Heterogeneous Fundamentalists

HOPF BIFURCATION CONTROL WITH PD CONTROLLER

Stability and Hopf Bifurcation for a Discrete Disease Spreading Model in Complex Networks

Reaction-Diffusion Models and Bifurcation Theory Lecture 11: Bifurcation in delay differential equations

Dynamic IS-LM model with Philips Curve and International Trade

ON THE EXISTENCE OF HOPF BIFURCATION IN AN OPEN ECONOMY MODEL

Phase Synchronization

THE ANALYSIS OF AN ECONOMIC GROWTH MODEL WITH TAX EVASION AND DELAY

Stability and nonlinear dynamics in a Solow model with pollution

Nonlinear IS-LM Model with Tax Collection*

AN AK TIME TO BUILD GROWTH MODEL

STABILITY AND HOPF BIFURCATION OF A MODIFIED DELAY PREDATOR-PREY MODEL WITH STAGE STRUCTURE

Extreme Values Theory for Dynamical Systems: Analysis of Stability Behavior in Delayed. Kaldor-Kalecki Model

Research Article Hopf Bifurcation Analysis and Anticontrol of Hopf Circles of the Rössler-Like System

HOPF BIFURCATION ANALYSIS OF A PREDATOR-PREY SYSTEM WITH NON-SELECTIVE HARVESTING AND TIME DELAY

2 The model with Kaldor-Pasinetti saving

Hopf Bifurcation Analysis of Pathogen-Immune Interaction Dynamics With Delay Kernel

Hopf Bifurcation of a Nonlinear System Derived from Lorenz System Using Centre Manifold Approach ABSTRACT. 1. Introduction

5.2.2 Planar Andronov-Hopf bifurcation

Dynamics on a General Stage Structured n Parallel Food Chains

Analysis of a lumped model of neocortex to study epileptiform ac

Stability and bifurcation of a simple neural network with multiple time delays.

The Cai Model with Time Delay: Existence of Periodic Solutions and Asymptotic Analysis

BIFURCATION DIAGRAM OF A CUBIC THREE-PARAMETER AUTONOMOUS SYSTEM

BIFURCATION ANALYSIS ON A DELAYED SIS EPIDEMIC MODEL WITH STAGE STRUCTURE

Production, Capital Stock and Price Dynamics in A Simple Model of Closed Economy *

Stability and bifurcation analysis of Westwood+ TCP congestion control model in mobile cloud computing networks

Stability and Hopf bifurcation in a mathematical model of pluripotent stem cell dynamics

HOPF BIFURCATION CALCULATIONS IN DELAYED SYSTEMS

Delayed Dynamics in Heterogeneous Competition with Product Differentiation

ASYMPTOTIC BEHAVIOUR AND HOPF BIFURCATION OF A THREE-DIMENSIONAL NONLINEAR AUTONOMOUS SYSTEM

Bifurcations in Delayed Lotka-Volterra Intraguild Predation Model

Andronov Hopf and Bautin bifurcation in a tritrophic food chain model with Holling functional response types IV and II

Stability Analysis And Maximum Profit Of Logistic Population Model With Time Delay And Constant Effort Of Harvesting

Delayed Dynamics in Heterogeneous Competition with Product Differentiation

Research Article Stability and Hopf Bifurcation in a Computer Virus Model with Multistate Antivirus

EXISTENCE THEOREMS FOR FUNCTIONAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS IN BANACH SPACES. 1. Introduction

The Foley Liquidity / Profit-Rate Cycle Model Reconsidered

Math Ordinary Differential Equations

A Generalized Solow Nonautonomous Model with Delay and Bounded Population Growth

Existence of permanent oscillations for a ring of coupled van der Pol oscillators with time delays

Linearized geometric dynamics of Tobin-Benhabib-Miyao economic flow

Dynamical Systems. Pierre N.V. Tu. An Introduction with Applications in Economics and Biology Second Revised and Enlarged Edition.

Stability and Hopf Bifurcation Analysis of the Delay Logistic Equation

A two-sector Keynesian model of business cycles

STABILITY AND BIFURCATION ANALYSIS ON DELAY DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Xihui Lin. Master of Science. Applied Mathematics

Restrictions and unfolding of double Hopf bifurcation in functional differential equations

Hopf bifurcations analysis of a three-dimensional nonlinear system

(8.51) ẋ = A(λ)x + F(x, λ), where λ lr, the matrix A(λ) and function F(x, λ) are C k -functions with k 1,

Models Involving Interactions between Predator and Prey Populations

Business Cycle Model on the Basis of Method of Systems Potential.

DYNAMIC LECTURE 1 UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600

Absolute Stability and Conditional Stability in General Delayed Differential Equations

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

A Dynamic Model of Unemployment with Migration and Delayed Policy Intervention

Bifurcation Analysis of a Population Dynamics in a Critical State 1

Some Dynamical Behaviors In Lorenz Model

Discrete and continuous dynamic systems

A Note on the Ramsey Growth Model with the von Bertalanffy Population Law

Hopf bifurcation analysis for a model of plant virus propagation with two delays

Analysis of a delayed predator-prey model with ratio-dependent functional response and quadratic harvesting. Peng Feng

Research Paper 252 July Market Stability Switches in a Continuous-Time Financial Market with Heterogeneous Beliefs

Additive resonances of a controlled van der Pol-Duffing oscillator

6. Well-Stirred Reactors III

STABILITY AND HOPF BIFURCATION IN A SYMMETRIC LOTKA-VOLTERRA PREDATOR-PREY SYSTEM WITH DELAYS

One Frequency Asymptotic Solutions to Differential Equation with Deviated Argument and Slowly Varying Coefficients

Research Article Stability Switches and Hopf Bifurcations in a Second-Order Complex Delay Equation

HOPF BIFURCATION IN A DELAYED MODEL FOR TUMOR-IMMUNE SYSTEM COMPETITION WITH NEGATIVE IMMUNE RESPONSE

On the stability and Hopf bifurcation of the non-zero uniform endemic equilibrium of a time-delayed malaria model

Master Thesis. Equivariant Pyragas control. Isabelle Schneider Freie Universität Berlin Fachbereich Mathematik und Informatik Berlin

Asynchronous oscillations due to antigenic variation in Malaria Pf

Masanori Yokoo. 1 Introduction

Economics 2: Growth (Growth in the Solow Model)

A Time Since Recovery Model with Varying Rates of Loss of Immunity

University of Utrecht

Qualitative analysis of the Tobin-Benhabib-Miyao dynamical system

Routes to Complexity in a Macroeconomic Model Described by a Noninvertible Triangular Map

Lotka Volterra Predator-Prey Model with a Predating Scavenger

Lecture Note #6 (Chap.10)

Physics: spring-mass system, planet motion, pendulum. Biology: ecology problem, neural conduction, epidemics

GLOBAL STABILITY AND HOPF BIFURCATION OF A DELAYED EPIDEMIOLOGICAL MODEL WITH LOGISTIC GROWTH AND DISEASE RELAPSE YUGUANG MU, RUI XU

Holographic Entanglement Entropy for Surface Operators and Defects

UNCERTAINTY FUNCTIONAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR FINANCE

ZERO-HOPF BIFURCATION FOR A CLASS OF LORENZ-TYPE SYSTEMS

Deterministic and stochastic Cournot duopoly games with tax evasion.

The Invariant Curve in a Planar System of Difference Equations

Massera-type theorem for the existence of C (n) -almost-periodic solutions for partial functional differential equations with infinite delay

Analysis of a predator prey model with modified Leslie Gower and Holling-type II schemes with time delay

The exponential asymptotic stability of singularly perturbed delay differential equations with a bounded lag

University of Bristol - Explore Bristol Research. Early version, also known as pre-print

Some notes on the structure of limit sets in IS-LM models

Bifurcation and Stability Analysis of a Prey-predator System with a Reserved Area

Inverted Pendulum Stabilization Via a Pyragas-Type Controller: Revisiting the Triple Zero Singularity

Transcription:

Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 2, 28, no. 5, 2459-247 Stability of Limit Cycle in a Delayed IS-LM Business Cycle model A. Abta, A. Kaddar H. Talibi Alaoui Université Chouaib Doukkali Faculté des Sciences Département de Mathématiques et Informatique B.P:2, El Jadida, Morocco a.kaddar@yahoo.fr, talibi @hotmail.fr Abstract In this paper, we extend the work of J. Cai [] in the nonlinear case using the investment function of the Kaldor-type. Actually we investigate the direction of the Hopf bifurcation the stability or instability of the bifurcating branch of periodic solutions using the methods presented by O. Diekmann et al. in [3]. In the end we show numerical application. Mathematics Subject Classification: 37G5, 9B62 Keywords: IS-LM business cycle, delayed differential equations, Hopf bifurcation, periodic solutions Introduction mathematical models Kaldor was probably the first economist to realize the importance of the nonlinear mechanism of the economy to introduce his first model (in 94, [7]) by an ordinary differential equations as follows { dy = α[i(y (t),k(t)) S(Y (t),k(t))], = I(Y (t),k(t)), dk where Y is the gross product, K is the capital stock, α is the adjustment coefficient in the goods market, I(Y,K) is the investment function S(Y,K) is the saving function. In this model the nonlinearity of investment saving function leads to limit cycle solution (see also [2, 5, 3] for more information). In (977, [2]) Torre revised updated this model by replacing the capital

246 A. Abta, A. Kaddar H. Talibi Alaoui stock K(t) with the interest rate R(t) to formulate the following stard IS-LM business cycle model { dy = α[i(y (t),r(t)) S(Y (t),r(t))], = β[l(y (t),r(t)) M], dr where M is the constant money supply, β is the adjustment coefficient in money market L is the dem for money. In (989, [4]), Gabisch Lorenz considered an augmented IS-LM business cycle model as follows dy = α[i(y (t),k(t),r(t)) S(Y (t),r(t))], dk = I(Y (t),k(t),r(t)) δk(t), = β[l(y (t),r(t)) M], dr where δ is the depreciation rate of capital stock. Based on the Kalecki s idea of time delay (see [8,, ] for more information), Cai (in 25, []) presented the following delayed IS-LM model: dy = α[i(y (t),k(t),r(t)) S(Y (t),r(t))], dk = I(Y (t τ),k(t),r(t)) δk(t), = β[l(y (t),r(t)) M], dr with τ is the time delay needed for new capital to be installed, he investigated the local stability the local Hopf bifurcation for () in the linear case (the functions I, S, L are linear). In the following analysis we will consider the nonlinear case by using the investment function of the Kaldor-type. The dynamics are studied in terms of local stability of the description of the Hopf bifurcation, that is proven to exists as the delay (taken as a parameter of bifurcation) cross some critical value. Additionally we establish an explicit algorithm for determining the direction of the Hopf bifurcation the stability or instability of the bifurcating branch of periodic solutions using the methods presented by O. Diekmann et al. in [3]. In the end, we give some numerical simulations which show the existence the nature of the periodic solutions. 2 Steady state local stability analysis As in [9], we assume that the investment function I, is given by I(Y,K,R)=I(Y ) δ K β R. The saving function S, the dem for money L are given by S(Y,R)=l Y + β 2 R, ()

delayed IS-LM business cycle model 246 L(Y,R) =l 2 Y β 3 R, with δ,l,l 2,β,β 2,β 3 are positive constants. Then system () becomes: dy = α[i(y (t)) δ K (β + β 2 )R(t)) l Y ], dk = I(Y (t τ)) (δ + δ )K(t)) β R(t), = β[l 2 Y (t) β 3 R(t) M]. dr (2) 2. Steady state In the following proposition, we give a sufficient conditions for the existence uniqueness of positive equilibrium E of the system (2). Proposition 2. Suppose that (i): There exists a constant L> such that I(Y ) L for all Y R. (ii): I (Y ) ρ< for all Y R, where ρ is given by ρ = ((δ + δ )β 2 + δβ )l 2 + (δ + δ )l. (3) δβ 3 δ Then there exists a unique equilibrium E =(Y,K,R ) of system (2), where Y is the positive solution of K,R are given by I(Y ) ρy + [(δ + δ )β 2 + δβ ] M δβ 3 = (4) K = β 2l 2 + l β 3 δβ 3 Y β 2 δβ 3 M, (5) R = l 2Y M. (6) β 3 proof. (Y,K,R) is a steady-state of (2) if dy = dk = dr =, that is I(Y ) δ K (β + β 2 )R l Y =, I(Y ) (δ + δ )K β R =, l 2 Y β 3 R M =, (7)

2462 A. Abta, A. Kaddar H. Talibi Alaoui Let us assume that Y>, K>, R> satisfy (5). Then K = β 2l 2 + l β 3 δβ 3 Y β 2 δβ 3 M, (8) R = l 2Y M, (9) β 3 I(Y ) ρy + [(δ + δ )β 2 + δβ ] M = () δβ 3 where ρ is defined in (3). In view of hypotheses i) ii) of proposition 2. it s clear that equation () has a unique solution Y >. This concludes the proof. 2.2 Local stability analysis of E We will study the stability of the positive equilibrium E. Firstly we recall that E is asymptotically stable if all roots of the characteristic equation associated to the linearized system of (2) have negative real parts, the stability is lost only if characteristic roots cross the imaginary axis, that is if purely imaginary roots appear. Let y = Y Y,k= K K r = R R. By linearizing system (2) around E =(Y,K,R ), we obtain dy = α(i (Y ) l )y(t) αδ k(t) α(β + β 2 )r(t), dk = I (Y )y(t τ) (δ + δ )k(t) β r(t), dr = βl 2y(t) ββ 3 r(t), () The characteristic equation associated to system () takes the general forme with where P (λ) + Q(λ)exp( λτ) = (2) P (λ) =λ 3 + Aλ 2 + Bλ + C Q(λ) =Dλ + E, A = δ + δ + ββ 3 α(i (Y ) l ), B =(δ + δ )[ββ 3 α(i (Y ) l )] + αβ[(β + β 2 )l 2 β 3 (I (Y ) l )], C = αβ[β δl 2 + β 2 (δ + δ )l 2 β 3 (δ + δ )(I (Y ) l )], D = αδ I (Y ),

delayed IS-LM business cycle model 2463 E = αββ 3 δ I (Y ). Recall that the equilibrium of (2) is asymptotically stable if all roots of (2) have negative real parts, the stability is lost only if characteristic roots cross the imaginary axis, that is if pure imaginary roots appear. In order to investigate the local stability of the steady state, we begin by considering the case without delay τ =. This case is of importance, because it can be necessary that the nontrivial positive equilibrium of (2) is stable when τ = to be able to obtain the local stability for all nonnegative values of the delay, or to find a critical values which could destabilize the equilibrium. When τ = the characteristic equation (9) reads as λ 3 + Aλ 2 +(B + D)λ +(C + E) =, (3) hence, according to the Routh-Hurwitz criterion, we have the following lemma. Lemma 2. For τ =, the equilibrium E is locally asymptotically stable if only if (H): A>; (H2): C + E>; (H3): A(B + D) (C + E) > ; where A, B, C, D, E, are defined in (2). We assume in the sequel, that hypotheses (H), (H2), (H3) are true, we return to the study of equation (2) with τ>. Let λ = iω, ω R, rewrite (2) in terms of its real imaginary parts as Aω 2 C = E cos(ωτ)+dω sin(ωτ) (4) ω 3 Bω = Dω cos(ωτ) E sin(ωτ) (5) It follows by taking the sum of squares that ω 6 + aω 4 + bω 2 + c =, (6) with a = A 2 2B, b = B 2 2AC D 2,c= C 2 E 2, where A; B; C; D; E are given in (2). Then equation (6) becomes h(z) :=z 3 + az 2 + bz + c =, (7) with z = ω 2. Suppose that equation (7) has simple positive roots. Without loss of generality, assume that it has three positive roots, denoted by z,z 2 z 3, respectively. Then equation (3) has three positive roots, say ω = z ; ω 2 = z 2 ; ω 3 = z 3

2464 A. Abta, A. Kaddar H. Talibi Alaoui Let τ l = [arccos( (Aω2 l C)(F Dωl 2)+(ω3 l Bω l )Eω l )],l =, 2, 3. ω l (Dω l F ) 2 + E 2 ωl 2 Then ±iω l is a pair of purely imaginary roots of equation (3) with τ = τ l, l=,2,3. Define τ = τ l = min (τ l),ω = ω l. (8) l=,2,3 We have the following theorem. Theorem 2.2 Assume that (H), (H2) (H3) hold (see lemma 2.). If one of the following hypotheses is true: (H4) c< h (ω ) ;(H5) a<, b, c>, a 2 > 3b, Δ < ; (H6) b<, c>, Δ < ; where Δ is defined by Δ= 4 27 b3 27 a2 b 2 + 4 27 a3 c 2 3 abc + c2. (9) ω is defined by (8). Then τ > when τ [,τ ) the steady state E is locally asymptotically stable, when τ = τ, system (2) will undergo a Hopf bifurcation. Moreover, we have Re( dλ dτ )(τ ) >. Proof. Similar to the proof in []. 3 Direction of Hopf Bifurcation In the last section we have a Hopf bifurcation at a critical value τ of the delay. Thus (see [6]), there exists ɛ > such that for each ɛ<ɛ, system (2) has a family of periodic solutions p(ɛ) with period T = T (ɛ), for the parameter values τ = τ(ɛ) such that p() =, T () = 2π ω τ = τ(), where τ = ω arccos (Aω2 C)+(ω3 Bω )Dω, with A; B; C; D; E are given in (2) ω E 2 ω 2 is the least simple positive root of (6). In this section we use a formula on the direction of the Hopf bifurcation given by Diekmann in [3] to formulate an explicit algorithm about the direction the stability of the bifurcating branch of periodic solutions of (4). Normalizing the delay τ by scaling t t effecting the change U(t) = τ Y (τt), V(t) =K(τt), W (t) =R(τt), the system (4) is transformed into du = ατ[i(u(t)) δ V (t) (β + β 2 )W (t) l U(t)], dv = τ(i(u(t )) (δ + δ )V (t)) β W (t), = βτ(l 2 U(t) β 3 W (t) M). dw (2)

delayed IS-LM business cycle model 2465 By the translation Z(t) =(U, V, W ) (Y,K,R ), system (2) is written as a functional differential equation in C := C([, ], R 3 ), Z(t) =L(τ)Z t + h(z t,τ), (2) where L(τ) :C R 3 the linear operator h: C R R 3 the nonlinear part of (2) are given respectively by: L(τ)ϕ = τ h(ϕ, τ) =τ Let α[i (Y ) l )ϕ () δ ϕ 2 () (β + β 2 )ϕ 3 ()] I (Y )ϕ ( ) (δ + δ )ϕ 2 () β ϕ 3 () β[l 2 ϕ () β 3 ϕ 3 ()] α[i(ϕ () + Y ) I (Y )ϕ () δ K (β + β 2 )R l Y )] I(ϕ ( ) + Y ) I (Y )ϕ () (δ + δ )K β R βl 2 Y ββ 3 R β M) L := L(τ ):C R 3. Using the Riesz representation theorem (see [6]), we obtain Lϕ = dη(θ)ϕ(θ) (22) where, dη(θ) =τ α(i (Y ) l )δ(θ) αδ δ(θ) α(β + β 2 )δ(θ) I (Y )δ(θ +) (δ + δ )δ(θ) β δ(θ) βl 2 δ(θ) ββ 3 δ(θ) (23) δ(.) denotes the Dirac function. Let A(τ) denotes the generator of semigroup generated by the linear part of (2) A = A(τ ). Then, { dϕ (θ) for θ [, ) Aϕ(θ) = dθ (24) Lϕ for θ = for ϕ =(ϕ,ϕ 2 ) C. From Theorem 2., a Hopf bifurcation occurs at the critical value τ = τ. By the Taylor expansion of the time delay function τ(ε) near the critical value τ, we have τ(ε) =τ + τ 2 ε 2 + o(ε 2 ). (25) The sign of τ 2 determines either the bifurcation is supercritical (if τ 2 > ) periodic orbits exist for τ > τ, or it is subcritical (if τ 2 < ) periodic

2466 A. Abta, A. Kaddar H. Talibi Alaoui orbits exist for τ < τ. formula, The term τ 2 may be calculated (see [3]) using the τ 2 = Re(c) Re(qD 2 M (iω,τ )p, (26) where M is the characteristic matrix of the linear part of (2), M (λ, τ) = λ τα(i (Y ) l ) ταδ τα(β + β 2 ) τi (Y ) exp( λ) λ + τ(δ + δ ) τβ τβl 2 λ + τββ 3, (27) D 2 M (iω,τ ) denotes the derivative of M with respect to τ at τ = τ, the constant c is defined as follows c = 2 qd3 h(,τ )(P 2 (θ), P (θ)) +qd 2 h(,τ )(e. M (,τ )D 2 h(,τ )(P (θ), P(θ)),P(θ)) + 2 qd2 h(,τ )(e 2iω. M (2iω,τ )D 2 h(,τ )(P (θ),p(θ)), P(θ)) where D i h, i =2, 3, denotes the i th derivative of h with respect to ϕ, P (θ) denotes the eigenvector of A, P (θ) denotes it conjugate eigenvector p, q are defined later. To study the direction of Hopf bifurcation, one needs to calculate the second third derivatives of nonlinear part of (2)with respect to ϕ, D 2 h(ϕ, τ)ψχ = τ αi (ϕ () + Y )ψ ()χ () I (ϕ ( ) + Y )ψ ( )χ ( ) (28) D 3 h(ϕ, τ)ψχυ = τ αi (ϕ () + Y )ψ ()χ ()υ () I (ϕ ( ) + Y )ψ ( )χ ( )υ ( ) (29) Then Dh(,τ 2 )ψχ = τ αi (Y )ψ ()χ () D 3 h (,τ )ψχυ = [ τ αi (Y )ψ ()χ ()υ () ( ) + τ I (Y )ψ ( )χ ( ) + τ I (Y )ψ ( )χ ( )υ ( ) ( (3) )]. (3)

delayed IS-LM business cycle model 2467 ψ =(ψ,ψ 2,ψ 3 ),χ=(χ,χ 2,χ 3 ),υ =(υ,υ 2,υ 3 ) C([, ], R 3 ). As iω is a solution of (2) at τ = τ, then iω is an eigenvalue of A there exist a corresponding eigenvector of the form P (θ) =pe iω θ where p = (p,p 2,p 3 ) C 2, satisfy the equations: with Then one may assume calculate p 2 = Mp = M = M (iω,τ ). (32) p =, [ τ 2αβl 2(β + β 2 )( iω + τ ββ 3 ) + iω τ αδ ω 2 + τ 2 β 2 β3 2 τ α(i (Y ) l )], p 3 = τ βl 2 ( iω + τ ββ 3 )). ω 2 + τ 2 β 2 β3 2 So, from (3) (3), we have Dh(,τ 2 )(P (θ), P(θ)) = τ I (Y ) D 2 h(,τ )(P (θ),p(θ)) = τ I (Y ) D 3 h(,τ )(P 2 (θ), P (θ)) = τ I (Y ) α α exp( 2iω ) α exp( iω ) (33) (34). (35) Now, consider A, a conjugate operator of A, A : C([, ], R 2 ) R 2, defined by, { A dψ (s), for s (, ] ψ(s) = ds ψ( s)dη(s), for s = (36) ψ =(ψ,ψ 2 ) C([, ], R 2 ). Let Q(s) =qe iω s be the eigenvector for A associated to the eigenvalue iω, q =(q,q 2,q 3 ) T. One needs to choose q such that the inner product (see [6]), <Q,P >=,

2468 A. Abta, A. Kaddar H. Talibi Alaoui where <Q,P >= Q()P () If we take q 2 =, q 3 =, then θ q = from (35), we have Q(ξ θ)dη(θ)p (ξ)dξ. 2 qd3 h(,τ )(P 2 (θ), P (θ)) = ατ I (Y ) 2 (37) From (27), (3),(33), we deduce, qd 2 h(,τ )(e. M (,τ )D 2 h(,τ )(P (θ), P (θ)),p(θ)) = τ 4 α 2 ββ 3 δi (Y ) 2, det M (,τ ) (38) where det M (,τ )=τ 3 αβ[ β 3(I (Y ) l )(δ+δ )+β 3 δ I (Y ) β δ l 2 +l 2 (β +β 2 )(δ+δ )] where 2 qd2 h(,τ )(e 2iω. M (2iω,τ )D 2 h(,τ )(P (θ),p(θ)), P(θ)) = α 2 τ 2 I (Y ) 2 2(C 2 + C 2 2) [(C C 3 + C 2 C 4 )+i(c C 4 C 2 C 3 )], (39) C = τ α(i (Y ) l )(4ω 2 τ 2 (δ + δ )ββ 3 ) 4ω 2 τ (ββ 3 + δ + δ ) +τ 2 αδ I (Y )[τ ββ 3 cos(2ω )+2ω sin(2ω )]+τ 3 αβ(β +β 2 )l 2 (δ+δ ) τ 3 βl 2αδ β, C 2 =2ω (τ 2 ββ 3 (δ + δ ) 4ω 2 ) 2ω τ 2 α(ββ 3 + δ + δ )(I (Y ) l ) +τ 2 αδ I (Y )[2ω cos(2ω ) τ ββ 3 sin(2ω )] + 2τ 2 αβ(β + β 2 )l 2 ω, C 3 = 4ω 2 + τ 2 ββ 3 (δ + δ ) τ 2 ββ 3 δ cos(2ω ) 2τ δ ω sin(2ω ), C 4 =2ω τ (ββ 3 + δ + δ ) 2τ δ ω cos(2ω )+τ 2 δ ββ 3 sin(2ω ).

delayed IS-LM business cycle model 2469 Then Re(c) = ατ I (Y ) + τ 2α2 I (Y ) 2 2 2(C 2 + C2) (C C 2 3 + C 2 C 4 )+ α2 τ 4ββ 3δI (Y ) 2. (4) det M (,τ ) Now, from (27) we have Re(qD 2 M (iω,τ )p) =Re( dλ dτ )(τ ), from theorem 2., we have Re( dλ dτ )(τ ) >. Consequently we deduce the following result : Theorem 3. Assume (H), (H2), (H3). If one of the previous conditions (H4), or (H5) or (H6) (see theorem 2.2)holds, then, (a) the Hopf bifurcation occurs as τ crosses τ to the right (supercritical Hopf bifurcation) if Re(c) > to the left (subcritical Hopf bifurcation) if Re(c) < ; (b) the bifurcating periodic solutions is stable if Re(c) > unstable if Re(c) < ; where Re(c) is given by (4). Note that, Theorem 3. provides an explicit algorithm for detecting the direction stability for the Hopf bifurcated branch of periodic solution given by theorem 2.. 4 Application From section 3, we can determine the direction of a Hopf bifurcation the stability of the bifurcating periodic solutions through the formula (4). In this section, we give a numerical simulation supporting the theoretical analysis. Consider the following Kaldor-type investment function: I(Y )= exp(y ) + exp(y ). When α =3;β =2;δ =.; δ =.5; M =.5 l =.2; l 2 =.; β = β 2 = β 3 =.2, the system (2) has the positive equilibrium E =(.534,.44,.67). It follows from section 3, that τ =.797542549 Re(c) =.35573676. Thus from theorem 2. we know that when τ<τ,e is asymptotically stable, this property is depicted in the numerical simulation by Fig.. When τ passes through the critical value τ,e loses its stability a family of unstable periodic solutions bifurcating from E occurs (see Fig.2).

247 A. Abta, A. Kaddar H. Talibi Alaoui 2.5.5.5 2 4 6 8 t Figure : The steady state E of (2) is stable when τ =. 2.5 2.5.5.5 2 4 6 8 t Figure 2: A family of periodic solution bifurcating from E occurs when τ =.7975.

delayed IS-LM business cycle model 247 References [] Cai J.P.; Hopf bifurcation in the IS-LM business cycle model with time delay, Electronic Journal of Differential Equations, 25(5):-6. [2] Chang W.W. Smyth D.J.; The existence persistence of cycles in a nonlinear model: Kaldor s 94 model re-examined, Review of Economic Studies, 97 Vol. 38, 37-44. [3] Diekmann O., Van Giles S., Verduyn Lunel S. Walter H., Delay equations. Springer-Verlag, New-York (995). [4] Gabisch G. Lorenz H.W. (987) Business Cycle Theory: A survey of methods concepts. 989 edition Berlin:Springer-Verlag. [5] Grasman J. Wentzel J.J.; Co-Existence of a limit cycle an equilibrium in Kaldor s business cycle model it s consequences. Journal of Economic Behavior Organisation. 24. 994. P. 369-377. [6] Hale J. K. Verduyn Lunel S M; Introduction to Functional Differential Equations, Springer- Verlag, New York, 993. [7] Kaldor N.; A Model of the Trade Cycle, Economic Journal, 94, V.5, 78-92. [8] Kalecki M.; A Macrodynamic Theory of Business Cycles, Econometrica, 935, V.3, 327-344. [9] Krawiec A. SzydBlowski M.; The Kaldor-Kalecki Business Cycle Model, Ann. of Operat. Research, 999, V.89, 89-. [] Krawiec A. Szydlowski M.; The Hopf Bifurcation in the Kaldor- Kalecki Model, in Computation in Economics, Finance Engineering: Economic Systems, Editors S Holly S Greenblatt, Elsevier, 2 (forthcoming). [] Krawiec A. Szydlowski M.; The stability problem in the Kaldor- Kalecki business cycle model, Chaos,Solitons Fractals, 25(25):299-35. [2] Torre V.; Existence of limit cycles control in complete Kynesian systems by theory of bifurcations, Econometrica, 45(977), 457-466. [3] Varian HR.; Catastrophe theory the business cycle. Econ Inamiry 979, 7: 4-28. Received: March 9, 28