MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

Similar documents
MA Macroeconomics 4. Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 8

A Dynamic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT: THE PHILLIPS CURVE. Dongpeng Liu Department of Economics Nanjing University

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

Supplementary Notes on Chapter 6 of D. Romer s Advanced Macroeconomics Textbook (4th Edition)

Source: US. Bureau of Economic Analysis Shaded areas indicate US recessions research.stlouisfed.org

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: Solving Models with Rational Expectations

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 6. Solving Models with Rational Expectations

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor David Romer LECTURE 10

Final Exam. You may not use calculators, notes, or aids of any kind.

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Introduction to Rational Expectations

Two Models of Macroeconomic Equilibrium

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Assignment #5. 1 Keynesian Cross. Econ 302: Intermediate Macroeconomics. December 2, 2009

The Zero Lower Bound

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 4. VARs With Long-Run Restrictions

A Discussion of Arouba, Cuba-Borda and Schorfheide: Macroeconomic Dynamics Near the ZLB: A Tale of Two Countries"

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE

Empirical Project, part 1, ECO 672

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE

Aggregate Supply. A Nonvertical AS Curve. implications for unemployment, rms pricing behavior, the real wage and the markup

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

F11. Lecture 7. Inflation and Unemployment M&I 6. Adaptive vs Rational Expectations. M&B 19, p. 24

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Mankiw Chapter 11. Aggregate Demand I. Building the IS-LM Model

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Conceptual Explanations: Simultaneous Equations Distance, rate, and time

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants,

The transmission mechanism How the monetary-policy instrument affects the economy and the target variables

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Wage and price setting. Slides for 26. August 2003 lecture

Counting Out πr 2. Teacher Lab Discussion. Overview. Picture, Data Table, and Graph. Part I Middle Counting Length/Area Out πrinvestigation

Stabilization policy with rational expectations. IAM ch 21.

Strategic Interactions between Fiscal and Monetary Policies in a Monetary Union

Fresh perspectives on unobservable variables: Data decomposition of the Kalman smoother

PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) (MACROECONOMICS cl. 15)

Relationships between phases of business cycles in two large open economies

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Lecture 9: Stabilization policy with rational expecations; Limits to stabilization policy; closed economy case.

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach

Chapter 9: Roots and Irrational Numbers

Problem Set 2: Sketch of Answers

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

Simple Regression Model. January 24, 2011

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Phillips curve and the Tinbergen and Theil approach to economic policy

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Chapter 14: Finding the Equilibrium Solution and Exploring the Nature of the Equilibration Process

14.05: Section Handout #1 Solow Model

Alex s Guide to Word Problems and Linear Equations Following Glencoe Algebra 1

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Inflation traps, and rules vs. discretion

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

The New-Keynesian Liquidity Trap

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Looking for the stars

MA Advanced Econometrics: Applying Least Squares to Time Series

APPENDIX TO RESERVE REQUIREMENTS AND OPTIMAL CHINESE STABILIZATION POLICY

New Keynesian DSGE Models: Building Blocks

Economics II. Labor Market, Unemployment and the Phillips Curve, Part II

Forward Guidance without Common Knowledge

Title. Description. Remarks and examples. stata.com. stata.com. Introduction to DSGE models. intro 1 Introduction to DSGEs and dsge

MA Advanced Econometrics: Spurious Regressions and Cointegration

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

Ordinary Least Squares Linear Regression

The Solow Growth Model

ECON 4160: Econometrics-Modelling and Systems Estimation Lecture 9: Multiple equation models II

Recession Aversion, Output and the Kydland-Prescott Barro-Gordon Model

Mathematics Review Revised: January 9, 2008

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data

Transcription:

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Autumn 2014 Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 1 / 38

Beyond IS-LM We have reviewed the IS-LM and AS-AD models. We will now revisit some of the ideas from those models and expand on them in a number of ways: 1 More Realistic: Rather than the traditional LM curve, we will describe monetary policy in a way that is more consistent with how it is now implemented, i.e. we will assume the central bank follows a rule that dictates how it sets nominal interest rates. We will focus on how the properties of the monetary policy rule influence the behaviour of the economy. 2 Real Interest Rates: We will have a more careful treatment of the roles played by real interest rates. 3 Expectations: We will focus more on the role of the public s inflation expectations. 4 The Zero Bound: We will model the zero lower bound on interest rates and discuss its implications for policy. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 2 / 38

A Model With Three Elements Our model will have three elements to it. 1 A Phillips Curve describing how inflation depends on output. 2 An IS Curve describing how output depends upon interest rates. 3 A Monetary Policy Rule describing how the central bank sets interest rates depending on inflation and/or output. Putting these three elements together, I will call it the IS-MP-PC model (i.e. The Income-Spending/Monetary Policy/Phillips Curve model). We will describe the model with equations. We will also merge together the second two elements (the IS curve and the monetary policy rule) to give a new IS-MP curve that can be combined with the Phillips curve to use graphs to illustrate the model s properties. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 3 / 38

Part I The Phillips Curve Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 4 / 38

The Phillips Curve What are the tradeoffs facing a central bank? A 1958 study by the LSE s A.W. Phillips seemed to provide the answer. Phillips documented a strong negative relationship between wage inflation and unemployment: Low unemployment was associated with high inflation, presumably because tight labour markets stimulated wage inflation. A 1960 study by MIT economists Solow and Samuelson replicated these findings for the US and emphasised that the relationship also worked for price inflation. The Phillips curve tradeoff quickly became the basis for the discussion of macroeconomic policy. Policy faced a tradeoff: Lower unemployment could be achieved, but only at the cost of higher inflation. However, Milton Friedman s 1968 presidential address to the American Economic Association produced a well-timed and influential critique of the thinking underlying the Phillips Curve. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 5 / 38

A. W. Phillips s Graph Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 6 / 38

Solow and Samuelson s Description of the Phillips Curve Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 7 / 38

The Expectations-Augmented Phillips Curve Friedman pointed out that it was expected real wages that affected wage bargaining. If low unemployment means workers have strong bargaining position, then high nominal wage inflation on its own is not good enough: They want nominal wage inflation greater than price inflation. Friedman argued that if policy-makers tried to exploit an apparent Phillips curve tradeoff, then the public would get used to high inflation and come to expect it. Inflation expectations would move up and the previously-existing tradeoff between inflation and output would disappear. In particular, he put forward the idea that there was a natural rate of unemployment and that attempts to keep unemployment below this level could not work in the long run. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 8 / 38

The Demise of the Basic Phillips Curve Monetary and fiscal policy in the 1960s were very expansionary around the world. At first, the Phillips curve seemed to work: Inflation rose and unemployment fell. However, as the public got used to high inflation, the Phillips tradeoff got worse. By the late 1960s inflation was still rising even though unemployment had moved up. This stagflation combination of high inflation and high unemployment got even worse in the 1970s. This was exactly what Friedman predicted would happen. Today, the data no longer show any sign of a negative relationship between inflation and unemployment. If fact, the correlation is positive: The original formulation of the Phillips curve is widely agreed to be wrong. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 9 / 38

The Evolution of US Inflation and Unemployment 12 US Inflation and Unemployment, 1955-2013 10 8 6 4 2 0 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Inflation Unemployment Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 10 / 38

The Failure of the Phillips Curve 11 US Inflation and Unemployment, 1955-2013 Inflation is the Four-Quarter Percentage Change in GDP Deflator 10 9 Unemployment 8 7 6 5 4 3 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 Inflation Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 11 / 38

How to Read the Equations in this Course We will use both graphs and equations to describe the models in this class. I know many students don t like equations and believe they are best studiously avoided but it isn t as hard is it might look to start with. The equations in this class will often look a bit like this. y t = α + βx t There are two types of objects in this equation. 1 The variables, y t and x t. These will correspond to economic variables that we are interested in (inflation for example). We interpret y t as meaning the value that the variable y takes during the time period t ). 2 There are the parameters or coefficients. In this example, these are given by α and β. These are assumed to stay fixed over time. There are usually two types of coefficients: Intercept terms like α that describe the value that series like y t will take when other variables all equal zero and coefficients like β that describe the impact that one variable has on another. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 12 / 38

Squiggly Letters Some of you are probably asking what those squiggly shapes α and β are. They are Greek letters. While it s not strictly necessary to use these shapes to represent model parameters, it s pretty common in economics. So let me introduce them: 1 α is alpha (Al-Fa) 2 β is beta (Bay-ta) 3 γ is gamma 4 δ is delta 5 θ is theta (Thay-ta) 6 π naturally enough is pi. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 13 / 38

Dynamics One of the things we will be interested in is how the variables we are looking at will change over time. For example, we will have equations along the lines of y t = βy t 1 + γx t Reading this equation, it says that the value of y at time t will depend on the value of x at time t and also on the value that y took in the previous period i.e. t 1. By this, we mean that this equation holds in every period. In other words, in period 2, y depends on the value that x takes in period 2 and also on the value that y took in period 1. Similarly, in period 3, y depends on the value that x takes in period 3 and also on the value that y took in period 2. And so on. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 14 / 38

Subscripts and Superscripts When we write y t, we mean the value that the variable y takes at time t. Note that the t here is a subscript it goes at the bottom of the y. Some students don t realise this is a subscript and will just write yt but this is incorrect (it reads as though the value t is multiplying y which is not what s going on). We will also sometimes put indicators above certain variables to indicate that they are special variables. For example, in the model we present now, you will see a variable written as πt e which will represent the public s expectation of inflation. In the model, π t is inflation at time t and the e above the π in πt e is there to signify that this is not inflation itself but rather it is the public s expectation of it. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 15 / 38

Model Element One: The Phillips Curve Our version of the Phillips curve is as follows: π t = π e t + γ (y t y t ) + ɛ π t Here π represents inflation and by π t we mean inflation at time t. The equation states that inflation depends on three factors. 1 Inflation Expectations: This is given by the π e t term which represents the public s inflation expectations at time t. A one point increase in inflation expectations raises inflation by exactly one point. People bargain over real wages and higher expected inflation translates one-for-one into their wage bargaining, which in turn is passed into price inflation. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 16 / 38

Model Element One: The Phillips Curve Our version of the Phillips curve is as follows: π t = π e t + γ (y t y t ) + ɛ π t Here π represents inflation and by π t we mean inflation at time t. The equation states that inflation depends on three factors. 2 The Output Gap: This is yt yt, the gap between y t (GDP at time t) and yt (the natural level of output). The natural level of output is the level consistent with unemployment equalling its natural rate. The coefficient γ describes exactly how much inflation is generated by a 1 percent increase in the gap between output and its natural rate. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 17 / 38

Model Element One: The Phillips Curve Our version of the Phillips curve is as follows: π t = π e t + γ (y t y t ) + ɛ π t Here π represents inflation and by π t we mean inflation at time t. The equation states that inflation depends on three factors. 3 Inflationary Shocks: The ɛ π t term captures all factors beyond inflation expectations and the output gap that drive of inflation. For example, supply shocks like a temporary increase in the price of imported oil can drive up inflation for a while. To capture these kinds of temporary factors, we include an inflationary shock term, ɛ π t. The superscript π indicates that this is an inflationary shock and the t subscript indicates that these shocks change over time. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 18 / 38

The Phillips Curve Graph with ɛ π t = 0 Inflation Output Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 19 / 38

The Phillips Curve as we move from ɛ π t = 0 to ɛ π t > 0 (An Aggregate Supply Shock) Inflation PC ( > 0) PC ( =0) Output Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 20 / 38

The Phillips Curve as we move from π e t = π 1 to π e t = π 2 Inflation PC ( ) PC ( ) Output Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 21 / 38

Part II The IS-MP Curve Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 22 / 38

Model Element Two: The IS Curve The second element of the model is an IS curve relating output to interest rates. The higher interest rates are, the lower output is. The IS relationship is between output and real interest rates, not nominal rates. Real interest rates adjust the headline (nominal) interest rate by subtracting off inflation. Suppose the interest rate was 10 percent. Is this a high or low? It depends on inflation. Consider a person s decision to save. If the interest rate if 5% but inflation is 2%, then you can buy 3% more stuff next year because you saved. In contrast, if the interest rate if 5% but inflation is 8%, you can buy 3% less stuff next year even though you have saved. Similar for firms considering borrowing. If inflation is 10%, then a firm can expect that its prices will increase by that much over the next year and a 10% interest rate won t seem so high. But if prices are falling, then a 10% interest rate on borrowings will seem very high. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 23 / 38

Our Version of the IS Curve Our version of the IS curve will be the following: y t = y t α (i t π t r ) + ɛ y t Expressed in words, this equation states that the gap between output and its natural rate y t yt depends on two factors: 1 The Real Interest Rate: The nominal interest rate at time t is it, so the real interest rate is i t π t. The real interest rate is the real rate at which output will, on average, equal its natural rate. This is denoted by r. This is known as the natural rate of interest. When ɛ y t = 0, a real interest rate of r will imply y t = yt. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 24 / 38

Our Version of the IS Curve Our version of the IS curve will be the following: y t = y t α (i t π t r ) + ɛ y t Expressed in words, this equation states that the gap between output and its natural rate y t yt depends on two factors: 2 Aggregate Demand Shocks, ɛ y t : Many other factors beyond the real interest rate influence aggregate spending decisions. Fiscal policy, asset prices and consumer and business sentiment. We model these as temporary deviations from zero of an aggregate demand shock this is ɛ y t. This shock has a superscript y to distinguish it from the aggregate supply shock ɛ π t that moves the Phillips curve up and down. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 25 / 38

Monetary Policy: The LM Curve Approach So inflation depends on output and how output depends on interest rates. Complete the model by describing how interest rates are determined. Traditionally, this is where the LM curve is introduced. Links demand for the real money stock with nominal interest rates and output: m t p t = δ µi t + θy t Implies a positive relationship between output and interest rates: y t = 1 ( ) mt δ + µi t θ Combined with the negative relationship between these variables in the IS curve to determine unique values for output and interest rates. p t Illustrated with an upward-sloping LM curve and a downward-sloping IS curve. Central bank adjusts money supply m t to set the position of the LM curve. The determination of prices is then described separately in an AS-AD model. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 26 / 38

Monetary Policy: Our Approach Instead of the LM curve approach, we will model monetary policy by assuming the central bank sets nominal interest rates according to a particular rule. There are three reasons for this appraoch. 1 Realism 1: Modern central banks do not implement monetary policy by setting a specified level of the monetary base. 2 Realism 2: The traditional approach uses a separate AS-AD model to describe the determination of prices (and thus, implicitly, inflation) separate from interest rates. However, rather than being determined independently of inflation, most modern central banks set interest rates with a very close eye on inflationary developments. 3 Simplicity: In simplifying the determination of output, inflation and interest rates down to a single model, this approach is also simpler than one that requires two different sets of graphs. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 27 / 38

Model Element Three: The Monetary Policy Rule We first consider a monetary policy rule of the form: i t = r + π + β π (π t π ) We assume β π > 0. Features of this rule: Central bank adjusts i t up when inflation, π t, goes up and down when inflation goes down. When πt = π real interest rates equal their natural level. Why is a rule like this a good idea? If the public understands the central bank s target inflation rate, then on average we get πt e = π. In this case, the Phillips curve tells us that, on average, inflation will equal π provided we have y t = yt. And IS curve tells us that, on average, we will have y t = yt when i t π t = r. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 28 / 38

The Full Model That s the model. It consists of three equations. 1 The Phillips curve: 2 The IS curve: 3 The monetary policy rule: π t = π e t + γ (y t y t ) + ɛ π t y t = y t α (i t π t r ) + ɛ y t i t = r + π + β π (π t π ) I promised a graphical representation of this model. But this is a system of three variables which makes it hard to express on a graph with two axes. To make the model easier to analyse using graphs, we are going to reduce it down to a system with two main variables (inflation and output). Monetary policy rule makes interest rates are a function of inflation, so we can substitute this rule into the IS curve to get a new relationship between output and inflation that we will call the IS-MP curve. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 29 / 38

The IS-MP Curve If we replace the term i t in the IS curve with the formula from the monetary policy rule, we get y t = y t α [r + π + β π (π t π )] + α (π t + r ) + ɛ y t Now multiply out the terms in this equation to get y t = y t αr απ αβ π (π t π ) + απ t + αr + ɛ y t Canceling terms and re-arranging, this simplifies to y t = y t α (β π 1) (π t π ) + ɛ y t This is the IS-MP curve. It combines the information in the IS curve and the MP curve into one relationship. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 30 / 38

The IS-MP Curve Graph The IS-MP curve is y t = y t α (β π 1) (π t π ) + ɛ y t How this curve looks in a graph depends especially on the value of β π. An extra unit of inflation implies a change of α (β π 1) in output. Is this positive or negative? We are assuming that α > 0 so this combined coefficient will be negative if β π 1 > 0, i.e. the IS-MP curve will slope downwards if β π > 1 and upwards if β π < 1. Explanation: Increase in inflation of x will lead to an increase in nominal interest rates of β π x so real interest rates change by (β π 1) x. If β π > 1 then an increase in inflation leads to higher real interest rates and, via the IS curve relation, to lower output. For now, we will assume that β π > 1 so that we have a downward-sloping IS-MP curve but we will revisit this later. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 31 / 38

The IS-MP Curve with ɛ y t = 0 Inflation Output Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 32 / 38

The IS-MP Curve as we move from ɛ y t = 0 to ɛ y t > 0 Inflation IS-MP ( > 0) Output IS-MP ( =0) Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 33 / 38

Part III Putting the Pieces Together Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 34 / 38

The IS-MP-PC Model Graph We can now illustrate the full model in a single graph. The graph features one curve that slopes upwards (the Phillips curve) and one that slopes downwards (the IS-MP curve provided we assume that β π > 1.) The next figure provides the simplest possible example of the graph. This is the case where both the temporary shocks, ɛ π t and ɛ y t equal zero and the public s expectation of inflation is equal to the central bank s inflation target. PC and IS-MP curves are labelled to indicate the expected and target rates of inflation are. In the next set of notes, we will analyse this model in depth, examining what happens when various types of events occur and focusing carefully on how inflation expectations change over time. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 35 / 38

Expected Inflation Equals the Inflation Target Inflation IS-MP ( PC ( ) Output Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 36 / 38

A More Complicated Monetary Policy Rule In a famous 1993 paper, John Taylor argued for a monetary policy rule in which the central bank adjusted interest rates in response to both inflation and the gap between output and an estimated trend. We can amend our monetary policy rule to be more like this Taylor rule : i t = r + π + β π (π t π ) + β y (y t y t ) Substituting this into the IS curve, we get y t = y t α [r + π + β π (π t π ) + β y (y t y t )] + α (π t + r ) + ɛ y t This can be re-arranged to give y t yt = α (β π 1) (π t π 1 ) + ɛ y t 1 + αβ y 1 + αβ y Broadening the monetary policy rule to incorporate interest rates responding to the output gap doesn t change the essential form of the IS-MP curve. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 37 / 38

Things to Understand From This Topic 1 The evidence on the Phillips curve. 2 The Phillips curve that features in our model and how to draw it. 3 Why real interest rates are what matters for aggregage demand. 4 The IS curve that features in our model. 5 The monetary policy that features in our model. 6 How to derive the IS-MP curve. 7 What determines the slope of the IS-MP curve. 8 How the IS-MP curve changes when the monetary policy rule takes the form of a Taylor rule. Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 38 / 38