Granular Comparative Advantage

Similar documents
Granular Comparative Advantage

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

Eaton Kortum Model (2002)

Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large!

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

International Trade. Lecture 4: the extensive margin of trade. Thomas Chaney. Sciences Po. Thomas Chaney (Sciences Po) International Trade 1 / 17

Global Production with Export Platforms

Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation

Import Protection as Export Destruction

Internation1al Trade

THE GAINS FROM INPUT TRADE WITH HETEROGENEOUS IMPORTERS

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation

For Online Publication Online Appendix to: Merger Policy in a Quantitative Model of International Trade

Economic Development and the Spatial Allocation of Labor: Evidence From Indonesia. Gharad Bryan (LSE) Melanie Morten (Stanford) May 19, 2015

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Non-Homothetic Gravity

Consumption-led Growth

Prices and Exchange Rates: A Theory of Disconnect

Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports

The Origins of Firm Heterogeneity: A Production Network Approach

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress

Firm-to-Firm Trade: Imports, Exports, and the Labor Market. IEA: Mexico City. Jonathan Eaton, Samuel Kortum, Francis Kramarz.

External Economies of Scale and Industrial Policy: A View from Trade

The Geography of Development: Evaluating Migration Restrictions and Coastal Flooding

Web Appendix for Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Not for Publication)

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

Quality and Gravity in International Trade

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Trade, Inequality and Costly Redistribution

R&D Investment, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

Competitive Search: A Test of Direction and Efficiency

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) -

Trade and Domestic Policy in Models with Monopolistic Competition

Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1

Gravity Models and the Armington Assumption

Importing Skill-Biased Technology

Quality and Gravity in International Trade

Market Structure and Productivity: A Concrete Example. Chad Syverson

Firm Entry, Trade, and Welfare in Zipf s World

Trade Policies, Firm Heterogeneity, and Variable Markups

The Macro Impact of Micro Shocks: Beyond Hulten s Theorem

Inequality, Costly Redistribution and Welfare in an Open Economy

The Extensive Margin of Exporting Products: The Continuum Case

Endogenous information acquisition

Estimating the Productivity Gains from Importing [Preliminary - Comments welcome]

Technical Appendix. The Steady State

Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2

The Impact of Trade Liberalization on Industrial Productivity

Misallocation Under Trade Liberalization

Innovation, Firm Dynamics, and International Trade

The Elusive Pro-Competitive Effects of Trade

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Globalization, Inequality and Welfare

Wages, Unemployment and Inequality with Heterogeneous Firms and Workers

Imperfect Competition and Misallocations

The Matching and Sorting of Exporting and Importing Firms: Theory and Evidence. Felipe Benguria 1. May Abstract

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

The Gains From Input Trade in Firm-Based Models of Importing

Micro Data for Macro Models Topic 5: Trends in Concentration, Competition, and Markups

Import Protection as Export Destruction

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model

Spatial Misallocation across Chinese Firms PRELIMINARY, DO NOT QUOTE

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Monopolistic Competition when Income Matters

International Trade Lecture 3: Ricardian Theory (II)

Technological Spillovers and Dynamics of Comparative Advantage

Class Notes on New Economic Geography Models

A Theory of Entry into and Exit from Export Markets

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Aggregate Implications of Innovation Policy

CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION

Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Variable Demand Elasticity, Markups, and. Pass-Through

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

ENTRY, EXIT AND MISALLOCATION FRICTIONS JOB MARKET PAPER 1

The Matching and Sorting of Exporting and Importing Firms: Theory and Evidence. Felipe Benguria 1. July Abstract

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note

Productivity Improvements and Falling Trade Costs: Boon or Bane?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NEW TRADE MODELS, SAME OLD GAINS? Costas Arkolakis Arnaud Costinot Andrés Rodríguez-Clare

Lecture 4: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model With Many Goods and Factors

Skilled Factor Abundance and Traded Goods Prices

Nominal Rigidity and the Idiosyncratic Origin of Aggregate. Fluctuations

Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides

14.461: Technological Change, Lectures 7 and 8 Innovation, Reallocation and Growth

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

Consumption-led Growth

Transcription:

Granular Comparative Advantage Cecile Gaubert cecile.gaubert@berkeley.edu Oleg Itskhoki itskhoki@princeton.edu Stanford University March 2018 1 / 26

Exports are Granular Freund and Pierola (2015): Export Superstars Across 32 developing countries, the largest exporting firm accounts on average for 17% of total manufacturing exports Our focus: French manufacturing Average export share of the largest firm Manufacturing 1 industry 7% 2-digit 23 sectors 18% 3-digit 117 sectors 26% 4-digit 316 sectors 37% 1 / 26

Firm-size distribution is: 1 fat-tailed (Zipf s law) 2 discrete } = Granularity Granularity Canonical example: power law (Pareto) with shape θ < 2 Intuitions from Gaussian world fail, even for very large N a single draw can shape N i=1 X illustration i average can differ from expectation (failure of LLN) 2 / 26

Firm-size distribution is: 1 fat-tailed (Zipf s law) 2 discrete } = Granularity Granularity Canonical example: power law (Pareto) with shape θ < 2 Intuitions from Gaussian world fail, even for very large N a single draw can shape N i=1 X illustration i average can differ from expectation (failure of LLN) Most common application: aggregate fluctuations Gabaix (2011), di Giovanni and Levchenko (2012) The role of granularity for comparative advantage of countries is a natural question, yet has not been explored Can a few firms shape country-sector specialization? 2 / 26

Trade Models Trade models acknowledge fat-tailed-ness but not discreteness emphasis on firms, but each firm is infinitesimal (LLN applies) hence, no role of individual firms in shaping sectoral aggregates Exceptions with discrete number of firms 1 One-sector model of Eaton, Kortum and Sotelo (EKS, 2012) 2 Literature on competition/markups (e.g., AB 2008, EMX 2014, AIK 2014, Neary 2015) 3 / 26

Trade Models Trade models acknowledge fat-tailed-ness but not discreteness emphasis on firms, but each firm is infinitesimal (LLN applies) hence, no role of individual firms in shaping sectoral aggregates Exceptions with discrete number of firms 1 One-sector model of Eaton, Kortum and Sotelo (EKS, 2012) 2 Literature on competition/markups (e.g., AB 2008, EMX 2014, AIK 2014, Neary 2015) Our focus: can granularity explain sectoral trade patterns? 1 sector-level comparative advantage (like DFS) 2 firm heterogeneity within sectors (like Melitz) 3 granularity within sectors (like EKS) relax the LLN assumption in a multi-sector Melitz model take seriously that a typical French sector has 350 firms with the largest firm commanding a 20% market share 3 / 26

Granularity Our approach percentiles draws 0 T(z) Productivity draws, ϕ 4 / 26

Granularity Our approach percentiles draws 0 T(z) Productivity draws, ϕ Fundamental vs Granular 4 / 26

Granularity Our approach percentiles draws 0 T(z) Productivity draws, ϕ Fundamental vs Granular: Why do we care? 4 / 26

Roadmap: This paper 1 Basic framework with granular comparative advantage 2 GE Estimation Procedure SMM using French firm-level data 3 Explore implications of the estimated granular model many continuous-world intuitions fail dynamic counterfactuals 5 / 26

Roadmap: This paper 1 Basic framework with granular comparative advantage 2 GE Estimation Procedure SMM using French firm-level data 3 Explore implications of the estimated granular model many continuous-world intuitions fail dynamic counterfactuals Highlights of the results from the estimated model: 1 A parsimonious granular model fits many empirical patterns 2 Granularity accounts for 20% of variation in export shares most export-intensive sectors tend to be granular 3 Moments of firm-size distribution explain trade patterns 4 Granularity can explain much of the mean reversion in CA more granular sectors are more volatile death of a single firm can alter considerably the CA 5 / 26

Modeling Framework 6 / 26

Model Structure 1 Two countries: Home and Foreign inelastically-supplied labor L and L 2 Continuum of sectors z [0, 1]: { 1 } Q = exp α z log Q z dz 0 3 Sectors vary in comparative advantage: T z /T z N (µ T, σ T ) 6 / 26

1 Two countries: Home and Foreign inelastically-supplied labor L and L Model Structure 2 Continuum of sectors z [0, 1]: { 1 } Q = exp α z log Q z dz 0 3 Sectors vary in comparative advantage: T z /T z N (µ T, σ T ) 4 Within a sector, a finite number of firms (varieties) K z : Q z = [ Kz i=1 q σ 1 σ z,i ] σ σ 1 5 Each sector has an EKS market structure 6 / 26

Productivity draws in a given sector z: Number of (shadow) entrants: Poisson ( M z ) Entrants productivity draws: Pareto ( θ; ϕ z ) EKS Sectors Denote N ϕ number of firms with productivity ϕ N ϕ Poisson ( T z ϕ θ), T z M z ϕ θ z with T z /T z shaping sector-level CA 7 / 26

Productivity draws in a given sector z: Number of (shadow) entrants: Poisson ( M z ) Entrants productivity draws: Pareto ( θ; ϕ z ) EKS Sectors Denote N ϕ number of firms with productivity ϕ N ϕ Poisson ( T z ϕ θ), T z M z ϕ θ z with T z /T z shaping sector-level CA Marginal cost: c = w/ϕ at home and τw/ϕ abroad Fixed cost of production and exports: F in local labor 7 / 26

Productivity draws in a given sector z: Number of (shadow) entrants: Poisson ( M z ) Entrants productivity draws: Pareto ( θ; ϕ z ) EKS Sectors Denote N ϕ number of firms with productivity ϕ N ϕ Poisson ( T z ϕ θ), T z M z ϕ θ z with T z /T z shaping sector-level CA Marginal cost: c = w/ϕ at home and τw/ϕ abroad Fixed cost of production and exports: F in local labor Oligopolistic (Bertrand) competition and variable markups Atkeson-Burstein (2008): {c i } {s i, µ i, p i } Kz i=1 show 7 / 26

Market Entry and GE Assumption: sequential entry in increasing order of unit cost [ w/ϕ c 1 < c 2 <... < c K <..., where c i = i, if Home, τw /ϕ i, if Foreign unique equilibrium Profits: Π i = s i ε(s i ) α zy wf 8 / 26

Market Entry and GE Assumption: sequential entry in increasing order of unit cost [ w/ϕ c 1 < c 2 <... < c K <..., where c i = i, if Home, τw /ϕ i, if Foreign unique equilibrium Profits: Π i = s i ε(s i ) α zy wf Entry: Π K K 0 and ΠK+1 K+1 < 0 determines K z 8 / 26

Market Entry and GE Assumption: sequential entry in increasing order of unit cost [ w/ϕ c 1 < c 2 <... < c K <..., where c i = i, if Home, τw /ϕ i, if Foreign unique equilibrium Profits: Π i = s i ε(s i ) α zy wf Entry: Π K K 0 and ΠK+1 K+1 < 0 determines K z General equilibrium: GE vector X = (Y, Y, w, w ) Within-sector allocations Z = { } K z, {s z,i } Kz i=1 z [0,1] Labor market clearing and trade balance (linear in X) Fast iterative algorithm 8 / 26

Foreign share: Properties of the Granular Model Λ z X z α z Y = K z i=1 (1 ι z,i)s z,i Expected foreign share: { } T Φ z = E Λ z z T = z Granular residual: 1 1 + (τω) θ Tz T z Γ z Λ z Φ z : E T {Γ z } = E T {Λ z Φ z } = 0 Aggregate exports: X = Y 1 0 α z Λ z dz = ΦY, Φ 1 0 α z Φ z dz 9 / 26

Estimation and Model Fit 10 / 26

Estimation procedure Data: French firm-level data (BRN) and Trade data Firm-level domestic sales and export sales Aggregate import data (Comtrade) 119 4-digit manufacturing sectors Parametrize sector-level comparative advantage: T (z)/t (z) log N (µ T, σ T ) Based on empirical distribution shown in Hanson et al. (2015) Stage 1: calibrate Cobb-Douglas shares {α z } and w/w CD shares read from domestic sales + imports, by sector w/w = 1.13, trade-weighted wage of France s trade partners Normalizations: w = 1 and L = 100 Stage 2: SMM procedure to estimate {σ, θ, τ, F, µ T, σ T }, while (Y, Y, L /L) are pinned down by GE 10 / 26

Estimated Parameters Parameter Estimate Std. error Auxiliary variables σ 5 κ = θ θ 4.307 0.246 σ 1 1.077 τ 1.341 0.061 w/w 1.130 F ( 10 5 ) 0.946 0.252 L /L 1.724 µ T 0.137 0.193 Y /Y 1.526 σ T 1.422 0.232 Π/Y 0.211 11 / 26

Moment Fit Moments Data, ˆm Model, M( ˆΘ) Loss (%) 1. Log number of firms, mean log M 5.631 5.624 0.1 2. st. dev. z 1.451 1.222 7.9 3. Top-firm market share, mean 0.197 0.206 3.5 s 4. st. dev. z,1 0.178 0.149 3.8 5. Top-3 market share, mean 3 j=1 s 0.356 0.343 2.0 z,j 6. st. dev. 0.241 0.175 11.5 7. Imports/dom. sales, mean Λ z 0.365 0.351 2.2 8. st. dev. 0.204 0.268 14.8 9. Exports/dom. sales, mean Λ 0.328 0.350 6.0 10. st. dev. z 0.286 0.346 6.5 Fraction of sectors with { } 11. P Xz > exports>dom. sales 0.185 0.092 37.9 Ỹz X z Regression coefficients 12. export share on top-firm share ˆb 1 0.215 0.243 2.6 (0.156) (0.104) 13. export share on top-3 share ˆb 3 0.254 0.232 1.1 (0.108) (0.090) 14. import share on top-firm share ˆb 1 0.016 0.020 0.0 (0.097) (0.079) 15. export share on top-3 share ˆb 3 0.002 0.005 0.1 (0.074) (0.069) 12 / 26

(a) Number of French firms (b) Top market share 0.3 Data Model 4 0.2 3 2 0.1 1 0 1 10 100 1000 10000 0 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 (c) Domestic import share (d) Pareto shape of sales 0.8 3 0.6 2 0.4 0.2 1 0 0.01 0.1 0.5 1 0 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 13 / 26

Non-targeted Moments Correlation between top market share and number of firms: s z,1 = const + γ M log M z + γ Y log Ỹ z + ɛ s z Data: 0.094 0.018 (0.008) (0.008) Model: 0.064 0.025 (0.007) (0.006) Extensive margin of sales: log M z = c d + χ d Data: 0.563 (0.082) Model: 0.861 (0.011) log(ỹ z X z ) + ɛ d z 14 / 26

Equilibrium markups 1.4 1.35 1.3 1.25 Other Top 4 Top 3 Top 2 Top firm 15 / 26

Quantifying Granular Trade 16 / 26

Decomposition of Trade Fflows Variance decomposition of X z = Λ zα z Y with Λ z = Φ z + Γ z: var(λ z) = var(φ z) + var(γ z), var(log X z ) var(log α z ) + var(log Λ z) Table: Variance decomposition of trade flows Granular contribution Export share contribution Common θ Sector-specific θ z (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) var(γ z ) var(λ z ) 17.0% 22.3% 26.0% 28.4% 20.3% var(log Λ z ) var(log X z ) 57.2% 59.2% 62.5% 63.9% 59.0% Pareto shape parameter κ z = θz σ 1 1.08 1.00 1.02 0.96 1.15 Estimated Pareto shape ˆκ z 1.10 1.02 1.07 1.02 1.21 Top-firm market share s z,1 0.21 0.25 0.26 0.29 0.21 16 / 26

Export Intensity and Granularity Granularity does not create additional trade on average Yet, granularity creates skewness across sectors in exports most export-intensive sectors are likely of granular origin 0.25 0.2 (a) Fraction of granular sectors 1/4 Granular 1/3 Granular 1/2 Granular (b) Granular contribution to trade 0.3 Export share Granular exports 0.15 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.05 0 0.02 0.04 0.07 0.1 0.15 0.21 0.29 0.4 0.58 1 Deciles of sectors, by export intensity Λ z 0-0.05 0 0.02 0.04 0.07 0.1 0.15 0.21 0.29 0.4 0.58 1 Deciles of sectors, by export intensity Λ z 17 / 26

Export Intensity and Granularity Granularity does not create additional trade on average Yet, granularity creates skewness across sectors in exports most export-intensive sectors are likely of granular origin (a) Distribution of Λ z Φ z (b) Distribution of Φ z Λ z 1 p50 p75 p90 p95 p99 1 p50 p75 p90 p95 p99 0.8 0.8 0.6 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 17 / 26

Properties of Granular Exports Γ z = Λ z Φ z are orthogonal with Φ z, log(α z Y ) and log M z Best predictor of Γ z is s z,1, the relative size of the largest firm Table: Projections of granular exports Γ z (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) s z,1 0.335 0.373 0.379 0.357 0.354 s z,1 0.254 0.268 log M z 0.008 0.012 0.016 0.011 log(α z Y ) 0.005 0.013 Φ z 0.004 0.073 R 2 0.353 0.013 0.375 0.376 0.520 0.539 18 / 26

Identifying Granular Sectors Which sectors are granular? Neither Φ z, nor Γ z are observable P{Γ z ϑλ z Λ Λ z, r z } = z Φ ϑλ g( Φ z, Λ ) z, r z dφ z z 1 0 g( ), Φ z, Λ z, r z dφ z 0.9 1 0.8 0.9 Top home-firm market share, s z,(1) 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.1 0 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Export share, Λ (z) 0 19 / 26

Dynamics of Comparative Advantage 20 / 26

Dynamic Model Use the granular model with firm dynamics to study the implied time-series properties of aggregate trade Shadow pull of firms in each sector with productivities {ϕ it } Productivity of the firms follows a random growth process: log ϕ it = µ + log ϕ i,t 1 + νε it, ε it iidn (0, 1) with reflection from the lower bound ϕ and µ= θν 2 /2 Each period: static entry game and price setting equilibrium Calibrate idiosyncratic firm dynamics (volatility of shocks ν) using the dynamic properties of market shares No aggregate shocks 20 / 26

Firm Dynamics and CA Empirical evidence in Hanson, Lind and Muendler (2015): 1 Hyperspecialization of exports 2 High Turnover of export-intensive sectors Moment Data HLM France Model SR persistence std( s z,i,t+1 ) 0.0018 0.0017 LR persistence corr( s z,i,t+10, s z,i,t ) 0.86 0.83 Top-1% sectors export share 21% 17% 18% Top-3% sectors export share 43% 30% 33% Turnover: remain in top-5% after 20 years 52% 71% Idiosyncratic firm productivity dynamics explains the majority of turnover of top exporting sectors over time 21 / 26

Mean Reversion in CA Idiosyncratic firm dynamics in a granular model predicts mean reversion in comparative advantage In addition, granular sectors are more volatile (a) Mean reversion in Λ z (b) Volatility of Λ z Expected change in export share, Λ z 0.04 0.02 0-0.02-0.04-0.06 50 years 20 years Variation in export share, std( Λ z) 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01-0.08-1 -0.38-0.24-0.14-0.07 0 0.04 0.13 0.24 0.42 1 Deciles of sectors, by granular Γ z 0-1 -0.38-0.24-0.14-0.07 0 0.04 0.13 0.24 0.42 1 Deciles of sectors, by granular Γ z 22 / 26

Death of a Large Firm Death (sequence of negative productivity shocks) of a single firm can substantially affect sectoral comparative advantage In the most granular sectors, death of a single firm can push the sector from top-5% of CA into comparative disadvantage 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0-1 -0.08-0.04-0.01 0.01 0.03 0.06 0.09 0.13 0.21 1 23 / 26

Granularity and reallocation Sectoral labor allocation: L z L α z + θ NX z σκ 1 Y Interaction between trade openness and granularity results in sectoral reallocation and aggregate volatility 24 / 26

Policy Counterfactuals 25 / 26

1 Merger analysis Policy counterfactuals 2 Misallocation and trade policy policies that hinder growth of granular firms why trade barriers often target individual foreign firm? 25 / 26

1 Merger analysis Policy counterfactuals 2 Misallocation and trade policy policies that hinder growth of granular firms why trade barriers often target individual foreign firm? Figure: Welfare effects of Merger 2 1.5 1 0.5 0-0.5-1 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 25 / 26

Conclusion 26 / 26

Conclusion The world is granular! (at least, at the sectoral level) We better develop tools and intuitions to deal with it Applications: 1 Innovation, growth and development 2 Misallocation 3 Industrial policy 4 Cities and agglomeration 26 / 26

APPENDIX 27 / 26

Granularity Illustration The role of top draw, as the number of draws N increases ( corr max i X i, ) X i i max i X i i X i 1 1 0.8 0.8 0.6 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0 1 2 10 100 1000 10000 Number of draws 0 1 2 10 100 1000 10000 Number of draws back to slides 28 / 26

Sectoral equilibrium Sectoral equilibrium system: p i = µ i c i, µ i = ε i ε i 1 where ε i = σ(1 s i ) + s i, s i = ( pi ) ( 1 σ K ) 1/(1 σ) where P = P i=1 p1 σ i. back to slides 29 / 26