On Minimal Entropy Martingale Measures

Similar documents
Information and Credit Risk

When is a Moving Average a Semimartingale?

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Change of Measure formula and the Hellinger Distance of two Lévy Processes

Numerical Methods with Lévy Processes

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition

Multivariate Generalized Ornstein-Uhlenbeck Processes

Harnack Inequalities and Applications for Stochastic Equations

Jump-type Levy Processes

Minimal entropy preserves the Lévy property: How and why

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem

OPTIONAL DECOMPOSITION FOR CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES UNDER ARBITRARY FILTRATIONS. Introduction

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover

Existence and Comparisons for BSDEs in general spaces

On the optimal portfolio for the exponential utility maximization: remarks to the six-author paper

Infinitely divisible distributions and the Lévy-Khintchine formula

Nash equilibrium in a game of calibration

Stochastic Analysis. Prof. Dr. Andreas Eberle

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018

Weak solutions of mean-field stochastic differential equations

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization

CIMPA SCHOOL, 2007 Jump Processes and Applications to Finance Monique Jeanblanc

The Lévy-Itô decomposition and the Lévy-Khintchine formula in31 themarch dual of 2014 a nuclear 1 space. / 20

Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio

Translation Invariant Experiments with Independent Increments

University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics

On some relations between Optimal Transport and Stochastic Geometric Mechanics

Optimal investment strategies for an index-linked insurance payment process with stochastic intensity

A monetary value for initial information in portfolio optimization

Applications of Ito s Formula

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales

Introduction to Malliavin calculus and Applications to Finance

Functional Limit theorems for the quadratic variation of a continuous time random walk and for certain stochastic integrals

Point Process Control

THE ARROW PRATT INDEXES OF RISK AVERSION AND CONVEX RISK MEASURES THEY IMPLY

Supermodular ordering of Poisson arrays

Stochastic Processes

ALEKSANDAR MIJATOVIĆ AND MIKHAIL URUSOV

THIELE CENTRE for applied mathematics in natural science

Conjugate duality in stochastic optimization

STOCHASTIC ANALYSIS, CONTROLLED DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS AN APPLICATIONS

Optional decomposition for continuous semimartingales under arbitrary filtrations *

Polynomial Preserving Jump-Diffusions on the Unit Interval

On semilinear elliptic equations with measure data

Lecture Characterization of Infinitely Divisible Distributions

On the dual problem of utility maximization

An introduction to Lévy processes

EQUITY MARKET STABILITY

Multi-Factor Lévy Models I: Symmetric alpha-stable (SαS) Lévy Processes

Definition: Lévy Process. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 2: Lévy Processes. Theorem

Ambiguity in portfolio optimization

Introduction to Stochastic Optimization Part 4: Multi-stage decision

Robust pricing hedging duality for American options in discrete time financial markets

Generalized Gaussian Bridges of Prediction-Invertible Processes

An essay on the general theory of stochastic processes

Random Fields: Skorohod integral and Malliavin derivative

Max stable processes: representations, ergodic properties and some statistical applications

Outline. A Central Limit Theorem for Truncating Stochastic Algorithms

Perturbative Approaches for Robust Intertemporal Optimal Portfolio Selection

Time-Consistent Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection in Discrete and Continuous Time

Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem

Sample of Ph.D. Advisory Exam For MathFinance

Bernstein-gamma functions and exponential functionals of Lévy processes

Density models for credit risk

Unexpected Default in Information based Model

GLUING LEMMAS AND SKOROHOD REPRESENTATIONS

The strictly 1/2-stable example

Itô isomorphisms for L p -valued Poisson stochastic integrals

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models

LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY

Tools of stochastic calculus

Higher order weak approximations of stochastic differential equations with and without jumps

On Optimal Stopping Problems with Power Function of Lévy Processes

March 1, Florida State University. Concentration Inequalities: Martingale. Approach and Entropy Method. Lizhe Sun and Boning Yang.

Quadratic estimates and perturbations of Dirac type operators on doubling measure metric spaces

Ernesto Mordecki 1. Lecture III. PASI - Guanajuato - June 2010

Stochastic Calculus and Black-Scholes Theory MTH772P Exercises Sheet 1

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

EXPLOSIONS AND ARBITRAGE IOANNIS KARATZAS. Joint work with Daniel FERNHOLZ and Johannes RUF. Talk at the University of Michigan

Robust Utility Maximization for Complete and Incomplete Market Models

TRANSPORT INEQUALITIES FOR STOCHASTIC

Microscopic behavior for β-ensembles: an energy approach

9 Radon-Nikodym theorem and conditioning

Exercises in stochastic analysis

Martingale representation for Poisson processes with applications to minimal variance hedging

Introduction & Random Variables. John Dodson. September 3, 2008

On detection of unit roots generalizing the classic Dickey-Fuller approach

Other properties of M M 1

On Reflecting Brownian Motion with Drift

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations

Backward Stochastic Differential Equations with Infinite Time Horizon

Lévy Processes and Infinitely Divisible Measures in the Dual of afebruary Nuclear2017 Space 1 / 32

Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance

IOANNIS KARATZAS Mathematics and Statistics Departments Columbia University

LIMIT THEOREMS FOR SHIFT SELFSIMILAR ADDITIVE RANDOM SEQUENCES

Short-time expansions for close-to-the-money options under a Lévy jump model with stochastic volatility

Exponential martingales: uniform integrability results and applications to point processes

Generalized Orlicz spaces and Wasserstein distances for convex concave scale functions

Poisson random measure: motivation

Transcription:

On Minimal Entropy Martingale Measures Andrii Andrusiv Friedrich Schiller University of Jena, Germany Marie Curie ITN

Outline 1. One Period Model Definitions and Notations Minimal Entropy Martingale Measure Esscher Transformation Alternative Characterization 2. Exponential Compound Poisson Model Definitions and Notations Some Facts about Lévy Processes and MEM Connection with One Period Model

Definitions and Notations (Ω, F, P) = (R, B(R), µ) probability space ξ(x) = x, x R F 0 := {, R} F 1 := F ξ = B(R) F = (F t ) t=0,1 Then (R, B(R), F, µ) is a filtered probability space. Price Process The price process is defined by X = (X t ) t=0,1 with X 0 = ξ 0 and X 1 = ξ. By definition X should be F-adapted and hence ξ 0 R.

Definitions and Notations The expectation of the random variable η under measure ν is denoted by E ν η := η(x)ν(dx). Let us define the set of all random variables on (R, B(R), ν) by R L 0 (ν) = {η : η is finite}. Similar notation is used for the set of all integrable random variables on (R, B(R), ν): L 1 (ν) = {η : E ν η < }. Finally, let us introduce the linear space generated by the change of price and by the random variables that are equal to 0 µ-a.s.: K = {η : η = k(ξ ξ 0 ) µ-a.s. for some k R}.

Definitions and Notations Definition A probability measure ν on (R, B(R)) is called a martingale measure, if E ν ξ = ξ 0. The set of all absolutely continuous martingale measures is denoted by M = {ν is a martingale measure, ν µ}. The set of all equivalent martingale measures is denoted by M e = {ν is a martingale measure, ν µ}. Assume µ({ξ ξ 0 }) > 0. Then there exists at least one equivalent martingale measure if and only if µ({ξ ξ 0 > 0}) > 0 and µ({ξ ξ 0 < 0}) > 0.

I (M, µ) = inf I (ν, µ). ν M Minimal Entropy Martingale Measure Definition Let ν be a probability measure on (R, B(R)). The relative entropy I (ν, µ) of ν with respect to µ is defined by [ ] dν dν E I (ν, µ) = µ log if ν µ. dµ dµ + otherwise. Definition A probability measure ν 0 M will be called the minimal entropy martingale measure (MEM) if it satisfies [ ] dν I (ν 0, µ) = min I (ν, µ) = min E dν µ log. ν M ν M dµ dµ The distance between µ and M is defined by

Minimal Entropy Martingale Measure The class of all absolutely continuous with respect to µ martingale measures with finite relative entropy is denoted by M 0 = {ν M : I (ν, µ) < + }. Let us define the class of all integrable random variables with respect to all absolutely continuous (with respect to µ) martingale measures with finite entropy L = ν M 0 L 1 (ν), and the set of random variables with non-positive expectation under every absolutely continuous (with respect to µ) martingale measures with finite entropy C 0 = { f L : E ν f 0, ν M 0}. If I (M, µ) < + and if ξ is bounded then there exists a unique MEM.

Characterisation of MEM Assume that I (M e, µ) < +. A probability ν 0 is the MEM if and only if (i) ν 0 M; (ii) dν 0 dµ = c exp( f 0) µ-a.s., where f 0 L 1 (ν 0 ), E ν0 f 0 = 0 and c > 0; (iii) f 0 C 0.

The Esscher Martingale Measure Definition Given a probability space (Ω, F, µ), assume ξ is a r.v. and k R such that E exp[k(ξ ξ 0 ] < +. Then ζ defined by is called an Esscher density. ζ := exp[k(ξ ξ 0)] E exp[k(ξ ξ 0 )] The random variable ζ is positive µ-a.s., integrable and normalized (Eζ = 1), hence ν defined by ζ = dµ dν is a probability measure, ν µ. This probability measure ν is called an Esscher measure. If Eζξ = E ν ξ = ξ 0, then ν is a martingale measure for ξ and is called an Esscher martingale measure.

Alternative Characterisation Let µ be an arbitrary probability measure on R, B(R), ξ is the random variable defined by ξ(x) = x, x R, and ξ 0 R. A probability measure ν 0 on R, B(R) is the MEM if and only if ν 0 is the Esscher martingale measure. Corollary Assume I (M e, µ) < +. Then the following conditions are equivalent: (a) There exists the MEM. (b) There exists the (unique) Esscher martingale measure. (c) There exists k R such that R (x ξ 0) exp[k(x ξ 0 )]µ(dx) = 0.

More Detailed Analysis The set of all c such that ξ exp(cξ) is finite, is denoted by E := {c R : E ξ exp(cξ) < + }. If there exists the MEM, then set E is not empty. The set E could have 4 different structures: (a, b), (a, b], [a, b), [a, b], where a b +. If E = (a, b) there always exists the MEM.

Examples Example 1. Let ξ be a Cauchy distributed symmetric random variable: µ(dx) = 1 π(1 + x 2 ) dx In this case there does not exist the MEM. Example 2. Let ξ is shifted one-side Cauchy distributed random variable. µ(dx) = 1 {x [ a,+ )} 2 π(1 + (x + a) 2 ) dx where a > 0. In this case there exists the MEM.

Definitions and Notations (Ω, F, P) probability space X t is compound Poisson process with drift N t X t = µt + ξ i, X 0 = 0 where N is Poisson with λ = ν(r), (ξ i ) iid, independent of N F = F X filtration generated by process X (R, B(R), F, µ) is filtered probability space Price process Let us define the price process S t = exp(x t ) for t [0, T ]. i=1

Stochastic Exponential Let Y be a real-valued semi-martingale and consider the stochastic differential equation dz = Z dy, Z 0 = 1. This equation has a unique (up to indistinguishability) cádlág adapted solution, called the stochastic exponential of Y, which is a semi-martingale and is denoted by E (Y ). Explicitly, E (Y ) t = exp(y t 1 2 Y c t ) s t(1 + Y s ) exp( Y s ). The mapping Y E (Y ) can be inverted. The following theorem shows this fact.

Stochastic Logarithm Let Z be a semimartingale such that Z, Z are strictly positive. Then there exists an up to indistinguishability unique semimartingale Y with Y 0 = 0 and Z = Z 0 E (Y ). It is given by Y t = t 0 1 Z u dz u, t 0. The process Y from the previous theorem is called the stochastic logarithm of Z and is written L (Z) := Y.

Stochastic Logarithm Stochastic logarithm of S is equal L (S) t = = t 0 N t i=1 [exp( X u ) 1]dN u + µt [exp(ξ i ) 1] + µt =: L t, where is Lévy process with drift µ and Lévy measure ν L = ν F 1, F (x) = e x 1 for x R.

Definitions and Notations Let us define the following sets of martingale measures: M a := {Q : (S, F) is a Q-local martingle, Q P on F T }, M e := {Q M a : Q P on bf T }, M f := {Q M a : I (Q, P) < + }, M l := {Q M a : (L, F) is a Q-Lévy process, }. Assumption: M l M f M e

Some facts about MEM Results of Esche and Schweizer(2005): (1) inf Q Ma I (Q, P) = inf Q Ml M f M e I (Q, P). (2) If the MEM Q exists (in M a ) then Q M l ( (L, F) is a Q -Lévy process). (3) If the MEM Q in M l exists. Then Q l = Q and Q P.

Some facts The process Y is a local martingale if and only if E (Y ) is a local martingale. Assume that Q P on F T and (L, F) is a Q-Lévy process. Then X (resp., L) is compound Poisson with drift µ and Lévy measure ν Q ν (resp., ν L Q = ν Q F 1 ).

Density Let (Y, F) be a Lévy process. Then (Y, F) is a local martingale if and only if (Y, F) is a martingale. If (L, F) is compound Poisson w.r.t. Q and Q P on F T. Then ν L Q νl and dq dp (F T ) = exp T (ν L (R) νq(r)) L + 0<u T log ρ( L u ), where ρ := dνl Q dν L.

Entropy Let us assume that there exists a martingale measure Q such that it preserves the Lévy property and has finite entropy: Q M e M f. Then the relative entropy I (Q, P) has the form [ ( )] I (Q, P) = T λ λ Q + λ Q log λq ν L λ + λq I Q λ Q, νl, λ where λ = ν L (R) and λ Q = ν L Q (R). I (Q, P) < + if and only if I ( ν L ) Q, νl λ Q λ < +.

Form of Density (L, F) is a Q-martingale if and only if E Q [exp(ξ 1 )] = µ λ + 1. If there is no drift µ = 0, the martingale condition can be simplified. The optimization ( problem splits into 2 independent problems: minimization of ν L ) Q I, νl λ Q λ and minimization of I (Q, P) with respect to λ Q. Hence, the optimal solution is [ ( )] ν L λ Q = λ exp I Q νl,, λq λ where νl Q λ Q is a solution of one-dimensional problem.

Form of Density And now we can calculate the density: dq dp (F T ) = exp(kl T ) E exp(kl T ) where k is the Esscher coefficient for one-dimensional distribution.

References Esche,F. Two Essays on Incomplete Markets, PhD-thesis(2004). Esche,F., Schweizer, M. Minimal entropy preserves the Lévy property: how and why., Stoch. Proc. Appl. 115, (2005), 299-327. Frittelli, M. The minimal entropy martingale measures and the valuation problem in incomplete markets., Math. Finance 10, (2000) 39-52. Goll,T., Ruschendorf, L. Minimax and minimal distance martingale measures and their relationship to portfolio optimization., Finance Stochast. 5, (2001) 557-581. Kabanov, Y., Stricker, C. On the optimal portfolio for the exponential utility maximization: remarks to the six-author paper., Math. Finance 12, (2002) 125-134.