Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides

Similar documents
Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides

Incomplete Contracts and the Product Cycle. Pol Antràs. Harvard University, NBER and CEPR

Topics in Trade: Slides

Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2

Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1

Lecture 8: Incomplete Contracts

Lecture 1: Incomplete Contracts and International Trade

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

Labor Market Structure and Oshoring

Addendum to: New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?

Internation1al Trade

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Internationa1 l Trade

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of Offshoring

Chapter 5. The Engine of Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

Advanced Microeconomics

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Knowledge licensing in a Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth

Internation1al Trade

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note

EconS Cost Structures

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

The challenge of globalization for Finland and its regions: The new economic geography perspective

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

Economic Growth: Lectures 10 and 11, Endogenous Technological Change

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach

Problem Set Suggested Answers

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Modeling firms locational choice

On the dynamics of the Heckscher-Ohlin theory

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 2, Review of Endogenous Growth: Expanding Variety Models

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Expanding Variety Models

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Answers to Spring 2014 Microeconomics Prelim

Advanced Macroeconomics

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Organizing the Global Value Chain: Online Appendix

The Role of Pre-trial Settlement in International Trade Disputes (1)

On the Distributive Effects of Terms of Trade Shocks: The Role of Non-tradable Goods

Productivity Improvements and Falling Trade Costs: Boon or Bane?

Granular Comparative Advantage

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CONTRACTUAL FRICTIONS AND GLOBAL SOURCING. Pol Antràs Elhanan Helpman. Working Paper

Technological Spillovers and Dynamics of Comparative Advantage

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

Modeling Technological Change

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Trade policy III: Export subsidies


Market Structure and Productivity: A Concrete Example. Chad Syverson

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

This process was named creative destruction by Joseph Schumpeter.

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 4. Economic Institutions under Elite Domination

The Heckscher-Ohlin model: Mathematical treatment*

Externalities and PG. MWG- Chapter 11

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

International Trade 31E00500

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Global Production with Export Platforms

Endogenous information acquisition

Microeconomics, Block I Part 2

Imported Intermediate Goods and Product Innovation: Evidence from India

Static and Dynamic Gains from Importing Intermediate Inputs: Theory and Evidence

Advanced Microeconomics Problem Set 1

Research and Development

Trade and Domestic Policy in Models with Monopolistic Competition

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Endogenous Transport Investment, Geography, and Growth Take-offs

Homework 3 - Partial Answers

Discussion Papers in Economics

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

EconS Nash Equilibrium in Games with Continuous Action Spaces.

Two-sided investments and matching with multi-dimensional cost types and attributes

Transcription:

Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides Alexander Tarasov University of Munich Summer 2010 Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 1 / 35

Motivation For the United States, about one-third of exports and over 40% of imports consist of intrarm trade between a U.S. or foreign rm and their afliates. In a cross-section of industries, the share of intrarm imports in total U.S. imports is larger the higher the capital intensity of the exporting industry. PICTURE 1. In a cross-section of countries, the share of intrarm imports in total U.S. imports is larger the higher the capital-labor ratio of the exporting country. PICTURE 2. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 2 / 35

Motivation These observations raise the following questions: Why are capital-intensive goods transacted within rm boundaries while labor-intensive goods are traded mostly at arm's length? Why is the share of intrarm imports higher for capital-abundant countries? Are these facts related? Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 3 / 35

What This Paper Does A property-rights model of the boundaries of the rm in which the endogenous benets of integration outweigh its endogenous costs only in capital-intensive industries! close to PICTURE 1 A general-equilibrium, factor-proportions model of international trade, with imperfect competition and product differentiation: in the general equilibrium, capital-abundant countries capture larger shares of a country's imports of capital-intensive goods PICTURE 2 follows from the interaction of transaction-cost minimization (PICTURE 1) and comparative advantage Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 4 / 35

The Sketch of the Model A nal-good producer needs to obtain a special and distinct intermediate input from a supplier. Production of the input requires certain noncontractible and relationship-specic investments in capital and labor. The nal-good producer contributes to some of these investments but cost-sharing is relatively more important in capital investments. The lack of ex-ante contracts implies that the bargaining over the terms of trade takes place after intermediate input has been produced and manufacturing costs are bygones. A two-sided holdup problem which results in underinvestment in both capital and labor. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 5 / 35

The Sketch of the Model There are two possible organizational forms: vertical integration or outsourcing. Ownership is dened as the entitlement of some residual rights of control. Inefciency in labor investments is shown to be relatively higher under integration than under outsourcing; and conversely for capital. This implies that rms will choose outsourcing only when the investment in labor is relatively important in production! close to PICTURE 1. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 6 / 35

The Sketch of the Model This partial equilibrium is embedded in a general equilibrium setup with imperfect competition and product differentiation. Countries specialize in certain intermediate input varieties and export them worldwide. Capital-abundant countries tend to produce a larger share of capital-intensive varieties than labor-abundant countries. The share of capital-intensive (and thus intrarm) imports in total imports is then shown to be an increasing function of the capital-labor ratio of the exporting country! close to PICTURE 2. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 7 / 35

Consider a two-factor (K, L), two-sector (Y, Z ) closed economy. K and L are inelastically supplied and freely mobile across sectors. In each sector, rms use K and L to produce a continuum of differentiated varieties. Preferences of the representative consumer are of the form: where µ, α 2 (0, 1). Z ny µ Z U = y(i) α α nz di 0 0 z(i) α di 1 µ α, Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 8 / 35

Demand for nal-good varieties is thus y(i) = z(i) = A Y, p Y (i) 1 1 α A Z, p Z (i) 1 1 α where A Y = µep α 1 α Y, A Z = (1 µ) EP α 1 α Z. E is the total expenditure and P Y and P Z are the industry price indexes. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 9 / 35

Sales revenues are given by R Y (i) = p Y (i)y(i) = A 1 α Y y(i) α R Z (i) = p Z (i)z(i) = A 1 α Z z(i) α. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 10 / 35

Technology: Each variety y(i) requires a special and distinct intermediate input x Y (i) (z(i) requires x Z (i)). The input must be of high quality, otherwise output is zero. If the input is of high quality, production of the nal good requires no further costs and y(i) = x Y (i), z(i) = x Z (i). Production of a high-quality intermediate input requires a combination of capital K x and L x : Kx (i) βk Lx (i) x k (i) = β k 1 β k 1 βk for k 2 fy, Z g. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 11 / 35

Technology: Let 1 > β Y > β Z > 0. Low-quality intermediate inputs can be produced at a negligible cost. There are also xed costs of production: fr β k w 1 β k, k 2 fy, Z g. The costs are split between the producer and the supplier (f S and f F ). Firm structure: The nal-good producer (F ) decides whether it wants to enter a given market, and if so, whether to obtain the input from a vertically-integrated supplier (S) or from a stand-alone S. F chooses the mode of organization so as to maximize its ex-ante prots. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 12 / 35

Firm structure: It is assumed that, upon entry, S makes a lump-sum transfer T k (i) to F (it is to simplify the description of equilibrium). The labor investment L x is undertaken by S. The capital investment K x is undertaken by F. These investments are incurred upon entry and are useless outside the relationship. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 13 / 35

Contract Incompleteness: No outside party can distinguish between a high-quality and a low-quality intermediate input x k. This implies that F and S cannot sign enforceable quality-contingent contracts specifying the purchase of a certain type of intermediate input for a certain price. Similarly, it is assumed that K x (i), L x (i) are not veriable and the parties cannot write contracts on R Y (i) and R Z (i). The only contractibles ex-ante are the allocation of residual rights and the ex ante transfer T k (i). Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 14 / 35

Contract Incompleteness: If the supplier incurs all variable costs, the contract incompleteness gives rise to a standard holdup problem: the nal-good producer will want to renegotiate the price after x k (i) has been produced. Foreseeing this renegotiation, the supplier will undertake investments in capital and labor. If the nal-producer shares capital expenditures with the supplier, the holdup problem becomes two-sided. Therefore, its investment in capital are also suboptimal. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 15 / 35

Contract Incompleteness: Because no enforceable contract is signed ex-ante, F and S will bargain over the surplus of the relationship ex-post, when manufacturing costs are bygones. The extent of the underinvestment by each party will be inversely related to the share of surplus the obtain in the bargaining. Assume that Generalized Nash Bargaining leaves the nal-good producer with a fraction φ 2 (0, 1) of the ex-post gains from trade. Bargaining will occur even when the parties are integrated. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 16 / 35

When the supplier is a stand-alone rm, then if the parties fail to agree on a division of surplus, the nal-good producer is left with nothing. Under integration, the nal-good producer can re the manager of the supplying division and seize some amount of input produced. In particular, the nal-good producer obtains the residual rights over only a fraction of δ 2 (0, 1) of the input. If δ = 1, then integration would never be chosen (the nal-good producer just takes the whole amount of input implying zero investment in labor). PICTURE! Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 17 / 35

Integrated pairs: The potential revenues are given by R Y (i) = A 1 Y α y(i) α If there is no agreement, then the revenues are δ α R Y (i). Therefore, the quasi-rent is R Y (i) δ α R Y (i) = (1 δ α )R Y (i). Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 18 / 35

Integrated pairs: The nal-good producer receives δ α R Y (i) + φ(1 δ α )R Y (i) = φr Y (i) The supplier receives 0 + (1 φ)(1 δ α )R Y (i) Note that φ > φ. That is, under integration, the nal-good producer receives a higher fraction of sale revenues. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 19 / 35

Integrated pairs: Given the choice of labor, the nal-good producer solves max f φr Y (i) rk Y (i)g. K Y (i) Given the choice of capital, the supplier solves max f(1 φ) R Y (i) wl Y (i)g. L Y (i) We can solve for the interception of these two best response functions. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 20 / 35

Integrated pairs: The solution implies that p Y,V = β Y r β Y w 1 α φ β. Y (1 φ) 1 β Y The distortionary effect of incomplete contracting takes the form of a markup that is 1 φ β Y (1 φ) 1 β Y times higher than the "traditional" markup. The lump-sum transfer T Y,V is equal to the supplier prots. While the nal-good producer prots are given by π F,V,Y = const V A Y (p Y,V ) 1 α fr β Y w 1 β Y α Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 21 / 35

Non-Integrated pairs: The potential revenues are given by R Y (i) = A 1 Y α y(i) α If there is no agreement, then the revenues are equal to zero. Therefore, the quasi-rent is R Y (i). The nal-good producer gets φr Y (i) and the supplier (1 φ)r Y (i). Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 22 / 35

Non-Integrated pairs: Given the choice of labor, the nal-good producer solves max fφr Y (i) rk Y (i)g. K Y (i) Given the choice of capital, the supplier solves max f(1 φ) R Y (i) wl Y (i)g. L Y (i) We can solve for the interception of these two best response functions. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 23 / 35

Non-Integrated pairs: We have now that r p Y,O = β Y w 1 β Y αφ β Y (1 φ) 1 β. Y The nal-good producer's prots are π F,O,Y = const O A Y (p Y,O ) 1 α fr β Y w 1 β Y. α Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 24 / 35

Complete contractibility: In the case of complete contracts, when the quality-contigent contracts could be enforced (the quality of the input is veriable), the investments in capital and labor would be set to maximize the total surplus given by: R Y (i) rk Y (i) wl Y (i) fr β Y w 1 β Y. It can be shown that the impossibility of writing contracts lead to underinvestment in capital and labor. PICTURE! Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 25 / 35

Ownership Structure: Let Θ(β k ) be operating prots under integration relative to outsourcing. That is, Then, Θ(β k ) = Θ(β k ) = π F,V,k + fr β k w 1 π F,O,k + fr β k w 1 α(1 φ)δ α (1 2β 1 + k ) 1 α(1 β k ) + αφ(1 2β k ) δ α αβ k 1 α 1 + φ(1 δ α (1 δ α ) α 1 α. ) β k β k Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 26 / 35

Ownership Structure: It can be shown that Θ(β k ) is increasing in β k, Θ(0) < 1, and Θ(1) > 1. Theorem Therefore, there exists a unique threshold capital intensity ˆβ, such that all rms with β k < ˆβ choose to outsource production of the intermediate output, while all rms with β k > ˆβ choose to integrate their suppliers. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 27 / 35

The theorem provides an explanation for the rst picture: vertical integration of suppliers occurs mostly in capital-intensive industries. Hence, one would expect the share of intrarm trade to be relatively higher in those industries. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 28 / 35

Some Important points: Θ(β k ) is independent of factor prices because of the Cobb-Douglas assumption in production. In general, the decision would depend on factor prices. Why is F providing K x? It can be shown that if φ > 1/2 then nal-good producers will always decide to provide capital required for production the supplier is never given full control Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 29 / 35

Industry Equilibrium: Free entry implies that no rm makes positive expected prots. There are two types of equilibria (depends on β k ): integrated and non-integrated. In the integrated equilibrium: the ex-ante transfer T Y,V is equal to the supplier's prots. All prices are the same and given by Then, β Y r p Y,V = β Y w 1 α φ β. Y (1 φ) 1 β Y A Y,V = µe (p Y,V ) α 1 α n Y,V Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 30 / 35

Industry Equilibrium: The free entry implies that In the case of outsourcing, n Y,V = 1 α(1 β Y ) + α φ (1 2β Y ) fr β Y w 1 β µe Y p Y,O = β Y r β Y w 1 αφ β Y (1 φ) 1 β. Y This implies that n Y,O = 1 α(1 β Y ) + αφ (1 2β Y ) fr β Y w 1 β µe Y Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 31 / 35

General Equilibrium We assume that β Y > ˆβ > β Z. That is, in one industry we have the integrated equilibrium, while in the other non-integrated. First, E = rk + wl Equilibrium conditions are such that the capital and labor markets clear. By Walras' law we can focus on the equilibrium in the labor market. The labor market clearing condition is given by: L = n Y L Y + n Z L Z where L Y and L Z are labor demand by each pair in the industries. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 32 / 35

General Equilibrium Therefore, L Y = L x,y,v + L f,f,y + L f,s,y L Z = L x,z,o + L f,f,z + L f,s,z where L x,k,j is labor used by the supplier for production, L f,k,j + L f,k,j is labor used to cover xed costs (k 2 fy, Z g and j 2 fv, Og). It is possible to derive that where σ L is some constant. w r = σ L 1 σ L K L Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 33 / 35

Open Economy Now suppose the world is divided in J 2 countries, with country j receiving an endowment (K j, L j ). Assume that preferences are identical in all J countries. Factors of production are internationally immobile. Factor price equalization is attained (the endowments are not too different) and we can use the general equilibrium above to characterize the aggregate allocations in the world economy. Final goods are not tradable. Trade is in intermediate inputs only. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 34 / 35

Open Economy: Conclusion Capital-abundant countries tend to produce a larger share of capital-intensive varieties than labor-abundant countries. The share of capital-intensive (and thus intrarm) imports in total imports is then shown to be an increasing function of the capital-labor ratio of the exporting country! close to PICTURE 2. Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) and Antras and Helpman (2004) Summer 2010 35 / 35